Electricity Derivatives and Bank Guarantees
Geir Høidal Bjønnes and Jo Saakvitne
BI Norwegian Business School
1
. TABLE OF CONTENTS
1
Executive Summary ......................................................................................................................... 3
2
Introduction ..................................................................................................................................... 4
3
The market for energy derivatives .................................................................................................. 5
3.1
The Nordic energy market .......................................................................................................
7
4
Regulation of central clearing in energy derivatives markets ......................................................... 8
5
Central clearing in the nordic market.............................................................................................. 9
5.1
5.2
The use of bank guarantees and introduction of the DS futures ..........................................
12
5.3
Risk profile of bank guarantees ............................................................................................. 15
5.4
Systemic risk and central counterparties .............................................................................. 19
5.5
6
Overview of central clearing in the Nordic Market .................................................................
9
Systemic risk and bank guarantees ....................................................................................... 22
Likely impact of regulatory changes .............................................................................................. 23
6.1
Increased costs of hedging for industrial firms .....................................................................
23
6.2
Reduced hedging activity ...................................................................................................... 25
6.3
Non-financials move to indirect clearing members .............................................................. 25
6.4
Increased use of bilateral and physical contracts .................................................................
28
6.5
Impact on systemic risk ......................................................................................................... 28
7
Conclusions.................................................................................................................................... 31
8
Literature and references ..............................................................................................................
32
2
. 1 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
This report analyzes the use and risk of bank guarantees in the
clearing of energy derivatives. In particular, we examine the
systemic risk component of bank guarantees in central clearing,
and the likely effects of an effective ban on the current use of
bank guarantees.
Our main conclusions are that
ï‚§
It is likely that the use of exchange-traded energy
derivatives will decrease significantly if the current use
of bank guarantees are disallowed.
ï‚§
We expect an increase in bilateral trading and physical
hedging of energy prices. Systemic risk may increase,
since
o Bilateral markets are not subject to the same
regulatory oversight as exchange-traded
markets.
o Bilateral trades are not necessarily cleared.
o Transparency is much lower in bilateral markets.
ï‚§
Central counterparties face risk when accepting bank
guarantees as margin collateral, as they do when
accepting any other financial asset. However, we do not
find that the bank guarantees used in energy markets
today constitute a significant systemic risk factor.
The main message from this report is that disallowing the
current use of bank guarantees in energy markets, however
well intended, may cause adverse consequences.
In addition,
the benefits from imposing the regulation is likely to be small, if
any.
3
. 2 INTRODUCTION
This report is written on behalf of the Working Party on Bank
Guarantees in European Energy Markets1, by associate professor Geir
Høidal Bjønnes2 and Jo Saakvitne3.
The aim and mandate of the report is to analyze whether the current
use of bank guarantees, as they are used in energy markets today,
poses any unacceptable systemic risk; and how any potential risk can
be mitigated. Further, the report aims to examine likely scenarios if
bank guarantees are not allowed as eligible collateral for nonfinancial participants in the power and gas market. The authors take
full responsibility for any errors or omissions in the work.
In this report, we put a special emphasis on the Nordic energy
market. The Nordic energy market has been a success story, and
influences other European markets, while at the same time it is
particularly affected by the pending regulatory changes.
Sections 3-4 in this report provide key background information, while
sections 5-6 contain the bulk of the analysis.
In section 3, we describe
energy markets, with a special emphasis on features separating them
from other financial markets. We highlight why well-functioning
energy derivatives markets yield valuable benefits to society. In
section 4, we describe the key regulatory issues facing the market
participants.
In section 5, we discuss risk from central clearing and
bank guarantees. Section 6 discusses the likely impact of regulatory
changes, while section 7 concludes.
1
The members of the Working Party are Nasdaq Commodities,
Finnish Energy Industries, Confederation of Finnish Industries (EK),
Energy Norway, Swedenenergy, Oberoende Elhandlare, The Nordic
Association of Electricity Traders (NAET), Nord Pool Spot, and Dansk
Energi. Beyond the Working Party, the project steering group also
included the Finnish Ministry of Employment, the Finnish Ministry of
Finance, the Iberian energy derivatives exchange (OMIP), the Iberian
energy clearing house (OMIClear), and the Warsaw Commodity
Clearing House (IRGIT).
2
3
BI Norwegian Business School
BI Norwegian Business School and Fixed Point Consulting
4
.
3 THE MARKET FOR ENERGY DERIVATIVES
In this section, we discuss key features of energy markets, with a
special emphasis on what separates energy markets from other
financial and commodities markets. We argue that well-functioning
markets for energy derivatives ultimately lead to lower electricity
prices and higher investments in the sector.
Electricity production is
capital-intensive and
financial risk management
is important for
investments
The business of producing, delivering and retailing electricity is
complex. It requires capital-intensive investments and long-term
financing, which gives financial risk management a crucial role in the
determination of electricity prices and viability of investment
projects.
Electricity markets have several unique features, which are lacking in
other financial and commodity markets. Firstly, electricity cannot be
stored, and hence suppliers and consumers lack inventories.
Therefore, the dynamics of derivative prices may behave differently
than for instance oil price derivatives, where the underlying asset can
be stored.
Secondly, electricity markets have historically been geographically
distinct.
Even today, moving power between regions may be
economically or even physically unviable due to energy lost to
resistance in the grid. In Europe, lack of cross-border transmission
capacity is a hindrance to energy market integration (Nowak, 2010).
This has led to fragmented and specialized derivative markets, and
substantial price differences across regions.
Figure 1: Large price differences in electricity prices in EU.
Electricity markets are
geographically distinct
Source: Eurostat. Prices for 2500-5000 kWh, excluding taxes.
5
.
Figure 2: The five wide area electricity grids in Europe
Electricity prices feature
extreme variations,
making hedging important
for electricity suppliers and
consumers
Well-functioning financial
derivatives markets lower
the costs of hedging…
… which in turn lowers
electricity prices and
increase investments
Electricity prices also feature large variations. Part of this variation is
due to strong seasonality in supply and demand over days, weeks and
months. In addition, there is also the possibility of unexpected
dramatic price changes over the very short term, caused by supply
disturbances. These price changes manifest themselves in sudden
upward jumps shortly followed by a rapid reversion to normal levels.
These extreme spikes are a major concern for risk management of
utilities, and imply an important role for financial derivatives (Geman,
2002, Carmona and Coulon, 2014).
The large variations in spot prices
do not carry directly over to derivative prices. Due to the well-known
Samuelson effect (Samuelson, 1965), the effects of spot market
volatility on futures prices will decrease with time to delivery on the
futures contract.
The large spot price variations and non-storability of electricity have
always prompted electricity suppliers to hedge their price risk by
selling power with future delivery. Historically, energy markets have
been in line with the classical Keynes-Hicks theory of “normal
backwardation”, meaning that power producers have sold future
power at a discount to spot prices in order to incentivize external
capital to take on the producers’ risk of falling prices.
(Keynes 1930,
Hicks 1939). A gradual reversal of this discount has taken place as
standardized exchange-traded financial derivatives have allowed a
broader investor base to participate in the risk sharing (Carmona and
Coulon 2014, Bouchouev 2012).
In general, reduced forward premiums caused by improved risk
sharing are characteristics of efficient and well-functioning markets.
When electricity producers can hedge their commercial risk, the
uncertainty about returns to investments in the electrical power
utilities sector decreases. This in turn decreases capital costs of
6
.
electricity investment projects, and ultimately leads to lower prices
of electricity and increased investments.
3.1 THE NORDIC ENERGY MARKET
This report has a
special emphasis on
the Nordic energy
market
The energy derivatives
market of other parts of
northern Europe is
gradually moving
towards the same
structure as the Nordic
market
The Nordic market is
exchange-traded and
cleared by central
counterparty (CCP)
Multilateral and cleared
markets have clear
benefits in terms of risk
and efficiency
We will now examine the Nordic energy market in detail. This market
has been a success story, and influences other European markets. At
the same time, the market is particularly affected by the pending
regulatory changes. Furthermore, the energy derivatives markets of
other parts of northern Europe are gradually moving towards the
same structure as the Nordic market.
Nasdaq Commodities lists, in
addition to the Nordic market and Baltic electricity price area
differential products, derivatives on electricity in the Netherlands,
Germany and UK,.
The Nordic market is of particular interest for three reasons. Firstly,
the Nordic electricity power market is often held to be one of the
most efficient, transparent and liquid electricity power markets in the
world (Mork (2001), Bergman (2002, 2003), Amundsen and Bergman
(2006)). Secondly, the Nordic market will be significantly affected by
the regulatory changes at hand.
Thirdly, there is a trend in other
European markets toward a structure similar to the one in the Nordic
market.
The Nordic electricity power market was deregulated in the mid
1990’s. The aim of the reform was to separate the production and
sale of electricity from the transmission of electricity (the network
operation). The reform led to active trading of spot electricity and
derivatives by a large number of participants at the Nordic exchanges
for electricity spot (currently Nord Pool Spot) and financial
derivatives (currently Nasdaq Commodities).
Currently, members
from around 20 countries are trading at the derivatives market at
Nasdaq Commodities.
Worldwide, only 40 per cent of outstanding commodities derivative
contracts are exchange traded (BIS 2013, WFE 2013). Energy
derivatives (not including oil) make up around 35 per cent of
commodities contracts traded worldwide. It is therefore of particular
interest that the Nordic energy market is to a large degree exchange
traded, with trading centered on the Oslo-based Nasdaq
Commodities exchange4.
Exchange traded markets are multilateral,
meaning that multiple buying and selling interests may interact and
contract in accordance with non-discretionary rules. This market
4
NASDAQ OMX Oslo ASA
7
. structure provides a wide range of benefits over an OTC structure,
and it has been a major regulatory effort since the financial crisis to
promote multilateral trading venues for financial derivatives.
Multilateral markets provide transparency of prices and
standardization of terms, and subsequently efficient price discovery,
increased liquidity and decreased trading costs.
4 REGULATION OF CENTRAL CLEARING IN
ENERGY DERIVATIVES MARKETS
A major policy objective has
been to move derivatives
market to multilateral and
cleared venues
In September 2009, the G20 leaders meeting in Pittsburgh agreed
that: “All standardized OTC derivative contracts should be traded on
exchanges or electronic trading platforms, where appropriate, and
cleared through central counterparties by end-2012 at the latest.”
In Europe, the European Market Infrastructure Regulation (EMIR)
dictates the details of central clearing. Article 46 of EMIR allows nonfinancial clearing members to post bank guarantees as collateral for
a) Derivatives relating to electricity or natural gas produced,
traded or delivered in the Union
b) Derivatives relating to the transportation of electricity or
natural gas in the Union
Pending regulatory
changes will affect energy
markets
The European Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA) specifies the
conditions for accepting bank guarantees in their technical standards.
These standards specify, among other requirements, that commercial
bank guarantees must be “fully backed by collateral”, a requirement
that market participants claim, in practice, negates the use of
commercial bank guarantees (European Association of CCP Clearing
Houses, 2014). An exemption period was granted for commodity
markets in 2013. This period will expire in March 2016.
There is an ongoing initiative to make the exemption permanent, by
policymakers, regulators and the energy industry.
During the
legislative procedure in 2012, the four Nordic financial supervisory
authorities (FSAs) requested in a letter to ESMA that the
requirements prohibiting use of non-fully backed commercial bank
guarantees be removed. In 2015, seven governments in the Nordic
and Baltic region (Sweden, Denmark, Finland, Norway, Estonia, Latvia
and Lithuania) urged the European Commission to reconsider the ban
on non-fully backed commercial bank guarantees as collateral.
8
. The Working Party on Bank Guarantees in European Energy Markets,
The Union of the Electricity Industry (Eurelectric), EACH (European
Association of CCP), European Federation of Energy Traders (EFET)
and Eurogas have also sent letters to the European Commission in
which they urge the European Commission to reconsider the ban on
non-fully backed commercial bank guarantees as collateral.
5 CENTRAL
MARKET
CLEARING
IN
THE
NORDIC
In this section, we discuss the details of central clearing with a special
emphasis on the Nordic market. Furthermore, we analyze bank
guarantees in central clearing. In the final subsection, we examine
the important role of central counterparties in tackling systemic risk.
5.1 OVERVIEW OF CENTRAL CLEARING IN THE
NORDIC MARKET
A central counterparty (CCP) is an entity that interposes itself
between counterparties to contracts traded in a financial or physical
market, becoming the buyer to every seller and the seller to every
buyer, thereby guaranteeing the performance of all contracts.
Central counterparties provide significant risk-reducing benefits due
to improved oversight of market participants and the coordinated
management of open positions following the default of a market
participant (Milne 2012, Wendt 2015). Following the financial crisis in
2008, a major regulatory effort has been focused on imposing
mandatory central counterparty clearing in derivative markets.
The participants in the
energy market is primarily
the suppliers and
demanders of electricity
The participants in the market for financial derivatives on Nordic
power are primarily the suppliers and demanders of electricity (i.e.
the producers and wholesale consumers).
In this aspect the energy
markets differ from financial markets in general, as participants in
other financial markets to a large extent are banks, dealers and other
financial institutions. This can be confirmed by a mere glance at
figure 3. The figure show the relative share of financial versus nonfinancial firms, for major OTC derivatives markets and for the Nordic
power market.
9
.
Figure 3: The participants in the Nordic energy market differ markedly
from other major derivative markets
The type of participants
distinguish energy
markets from other
major derivative
markets, where financial
institutions dominate
Source: Bank of International Settlements (BIS) and Nasdaq
Commodities.
The Nordic market traded on Nasdaq Commodities is cleared by the
Stockholm-based CCP Nasdaq Clearing5. A CCP relieves the market
participants from counterparty risk. The CCP handles its own
counterparty risk in part by having members post collateral. Current
regulation makes a distinction between eligible collateral for financial
and non-financial firms, in that financial firms may not post bank
guarantees as collateral.
Financial and nonfinancial firms have
access to different types
of collateral
Financial firms must provide collateral in the form of cash or
securities deemed eligible by the clearing house and compliant with
regulation.
Financial firms typically have a balance sheet consisting of
various types of financial assets, and are actively engaged in hedging
of risks stemming from these assets.
In addition to cash and securities, non-financial firms can currently
post bank guarantees to cover margin requirements relating to
electricity and gas derivatives in the EU (as defined by EMIR)6. Many
of these firms do not hold excess financial assets eligible as collateral.
For this reason, non-financial firms post large parts of their initial and
variation margin7 with bank guarantees. Figure 4 shows that bank
5
NASDAQ OMX Clearing AB
Bank guarantees can cover initial margin, and, in the case of Deferred
Settlement (DS) Futures, accumulated loss over the trading period of the
instrument.
7
Variation margin include accumulated loss/profit on DS Futures.
6
10
.
guarantees currently make up around three quarters of margin
collateral in the Nordic energy market.
Non-financials cover a
significant amount of
their margin collateral
by bank guarantees
Figure 4: Bank guarantees make up 71 per cent of total CCP
commodities collateral (approximately 33% of Nasdaq Clearing’s total
collateral)
Source: Nasdaq Commodities.
CCPs have different
participation
structures, direct
and indirect
Cleared markets are organized in very different architectures. In one
extreme model, all market participants clear directly with the CCP. In
another, only a limited number of institutions (direct members), clear
via the CCP, and they in turn clear for other participants (indirect
participants). Actual cleared markets feature a mix of the two
models.
Table 1 shows the relation between direct members and indirect
clearing participants for a subset of European CCPs.
It is clear that the
Nordic energy derivatives market at Nasdaq Commodities is
characterized by a high ratio of direct members to indirect clearing
participants. One of the few scientific papers comparing different
architectures of central clearing (Galbiati and Soromäki, 2013), finds
that indirect participation (tiering) increases some key risks faced by
a CCP, compared to direct membership. Specifically, tiering increases
exposures toward the average clearing member and increases the
probability of extreme exposures toward individual clearing
members8.
8
The result is developed under the assumption that clearing members pool
the exposures of their clients and does not carry over to the case of
individual segregation of client accounts.
11
.
The Nordic market has a
direct membership
structure
Table 1: Membership structure of major European CCPs
Direct
Indirect
Members participants
Euro CCP
25
>550
LCH EquityClear LSE
37
>530
Eurex
58
235
LCH SwapClear
22
80
LCH RepoClear
42
80
Nasdaq Clearing (Nordic
287
22
and German power)
Indirect/
direct
>22
>14
4.1
3.6
1.9
0.1
Source: Company websites and Galbiati and Soromaki (2013).
5.2 THE USE OF BANK GUARANTEES
INTRODUCTION OF THE DS FUTURES
AND
Investments in electricity production are characterized by a
particularly long payback profile. Also, the time separating the
investment decision and positive cash-flows is long in energy
markets, compared to most other commodities markets.
Furthermore, price volatility and seasonal variations are large, and
may lead to low margins for extended periods of time.
The special characteristics
of electricity production
have led to the use of
instruments unique to
energy markets
The special characteristics of electricity production have led to the
use of a number of unique products in power derivatives markets, in
order to hedge the atypical cash-flow profiles of the hedgers. One
such product is the Deferred Settlement futures (DS futures), the
standard contract in the Nordic market for contracts with more than
a month to delivery. The market participants developed this contract
specifically to match the time structure of the commercial risks that
they are hedging.
The attractiveness of the contract structure hinges
critically on the use of bank guarantees as margin collateral.
DS Futures were introduced at the end of 1997. The introduction led
to a massive increase in the clearing of energy derivatives, as the
structure of the new instrument was tailor-made to fit the cash flow
profile of electricity producers and consumers. The previously listed
ordinary futures contracts were not being widely traded for contracts
with more than 3-4 months to delivery.
A key difference between the
DS futures and the ordinary futures contract is that market
12
. participants can post bank guarantees as variation margin for their DS
futures in the trade period.
A key feature of these
instruments is the
possibility to post bank
guarantees as collateral
The DS futures contract specifies two time frames; the trade period
and the delivery period. The trade-period can last for as long as ten
years. In the trade period the contract is marked-to-market, but no
cash-flows occur. Bank guarantees can be posted as collateral for the
resulting exposure towards the CCP.
In the delivery period, there is a
daily exchange of the net of spot price and the agreed futures price,
as for a regular futures contract. This contract structure implies that
the parties avoid the cash settlement and funding costs associated
with margin requirements and daily settlements in the trade period.
Figure 5 shows megawatts open interest for ordinary futures
contracts and DS futures with more than one year to maturity around
the introduction of DS futures (November 1996 – December 1999).9
One can clearly see that open interest grew significantly during this
period.
Exchange-traded hedging
volumes increased
significantly when these
tailored instruments were
introduced
Figure 6 shows the developments in open interest for ordinary
futures contracts. These are contracts of the same type that is
standard in other commodities markets, for which the variation
margin cannot be collateralized by bank guarantees.
The figure
shows that this contract type never gained any particular traction in
the market, and eventually died out.
The growth in open interest was particularly pronounced for
contracts with more than one year to delivery, but also overall
hedging volumes grew, as shown in figure 7.
We think the evidence provided in figures 5 to 7 suggests that DS
futures have characteristics that the market participants want. In
particular, market participants report that it is the possibility to
collateralize the contract using bank guarantees in the trade period
that makes the contract attractive.
In section 6, we show that the monetary costs of replacing bank
guarantees with cash collateral are significant. The introduction of DS
futures led to significantly more trading on the exchange.
We will
also argue that an effective ban on bank guarantees is likely to revert
the development shown in figures 5 and 7.
9
This is monthly data that is collected on day 15 every month. If the
exchange is closed on day 15, we collect data on day 16, and then day 14 if
the exchange is not open on day 16.
13
. Figure 5 – Long-term hedging volumes increased significantly with
introduction of DS futures
Figure 6 – Ordinary Futures contracts never reached the same levels
of popularity as DS futures
Figure 7 – Overall hedging volumes grew significantly when DS
futures were introduced
14
. 5.3 RISK PROFILE OF BANK GUARANTEES
The bank guarantees used in commodity derivative markets today
are on-demand, continuing, unconditional and irrevocable. Box 1
summarizes some key features of this instrument.
Box 1: On-demand bank guarantees
Bank guarantees eligible as collateral in European energy
derivatives markets are on-demand, unconditional, irrevocable
and continuing.
i.
On-demand - The guarantor must pay upon demand,
without making any objection or invoking any
defence.
ii.
Unconditional and irrevocable - An unconditional
guarantee is a pledge by the guarantor to make
payments, as stated in the guarantee, without any
conditions. An irrevocable guarantee cannot be
cancelled or modified in any way without explicit
consent by the affected parties involved.
iii.
Continuing - A continuing guarantee is a guarantee
where the guarantor assumes liability for any past,
present and future obligations owed by a
debtor to a lender or creditor. Even where the
amount owing has been completely paid, the
guarantor can still be liable under that line of credit if
there is a subsequent indebtedness.
In this report, when we refer to bank guarantees, we mean nonfully backed commercial bank guarantees, unless otherwise
explicitly stated.
The main risk
dimensions of CCP
collateral are credit,
market and
concentration risk
The risk profile of an instrument posted as collateral can be
evaluated along several dimensions.
The most important ones in this
context are credit risk, market risk and concentration risk.
Credit risk is the risk that a debtor fails to meet its financial
obligations. The credit risk the CCP takes on when accepting
collateral for a position consists of two parts – the event that the
15
. debtor defaults (direct credit risk) and the event that the entity
issuing the collateral defaults (indirect credit risk). 10
Credit risk of a bank
guarantee stems from
the event that both the
debtor and the issuing
bank simultaneously
default
Figure 8 sketches a stylized overview of the credit risk to the CCP with
bank guarantees as bank guarantees as collateral, and with asset
collateral. In the case of bank guarantees, if the debtor does not
meet its obligation upon settlement or defaults in the trade period of
the instrument, the CCP directs its claim to the bank issuing the
guarantee. The bank has to pay the debt owed by the original debtor
in accordance with the terms laid out in box 1.
Thus, the relevant
credit risk from a bank guarantee stems from the event that both the
debtor and the issuing bank simultaneously default, at a time when
the market value of the position is negative.
Figure 8: Stylized overview of bank guarantees and other assets as
collateral
10
If the issuer of collateral defaults, the original debtor (to whom the CCP
has the credit risk towards) is liable to provide new collateral or otherwise
fulfill its financial obligation towards the CCP.
16
. Panel A (Bank guarantees): The hedgers secure their trades with a
bank guarantee. If a hedger with debt to the CCP defaults, the CCP
directs the claim to the bank issuing the guarantee. If the bank and
the hedger default simultaneously, the CCP may incur a loss.
Panel B (Asset collateral): The hedgers secure their trades with
assets11. If a hedger with debt defaults, the CCP claims the asset and
sells it.
CCPs mitigates credit
risk with requirements
on the guarantors’ and
members’ credit
worthiness
A CCP will mitigate credit risk by only accepting guarantees from
banks with low credit risk.
In the case of Nasdaq Clearing, only
guarantees from banks with low credit risk and an investment grade
credit rating are eligible as collateral. In case a bank issuing a bank
guarantee no longer fulfills the requirements stipulated by the CCP,
the bank guarantee has to be replaced within a timeframe specified
in the rules. The CCP will continuously monitor the credit risk
associated with both clearing members and issuing banks to ensure
that the risk of simultaneous default is minimized.
Obviously, a
similar risk is present with other forms of collateral. If the issuer of
the collateral and the debtor posting the collateral defaults
simultaneously, the CCP can potentially incur a loss.
Figure 9 illustrates the direct credit risk by showing annual default
rates in selected industry groups. The “utilities” sector includes
traditional electricity producers and grid operators.
One can estimate
the risk of a simultaneous default by examining the probabilistic
dependence between default rates for utilities and the banking
sector. The figure clearly shows that utilities have a very low
probability of default. The correlation coefficient of the default rates
of the two sectors, a standard measure of dependency, is around 0.4
in the series shown in figure 9.
Figure 9: Annual default rates in selected industries
11
This asset may be cash, which the CCP will invest in highly liquid financial
instruments as specified by EMIR.
The asset might also be a highly liquid
financial instrument as specified in the CCP’s eligible collateral list.
17
. Source: Moody’s
The market risk for a CCP
relates to the possibility of
adverse movements in
market prices at the same
time as a clearing member
defaults
Market risk of collateral is
higher for securities
(bonds and stocks) than
for cash and bank
guarantees
Market risk for a CCP mainly relates to the risk of adverse
movements in market prices at the same time as a clearing member
defaults. This risk dimension is particularly relevant for assets apart
from cash and bank guarantees. When the CCP accepts, for example,
bonds as collateral, there is always the possibility of sharp and
adverse movements in the price of the bond. For bank guarantees,
the associated market risk is indirect, as the guarantees are not
traded.
The indirect risk is due to the possibility that clearing members, in
time of market stress, may not be able to increase the amounts of
their guarantees to cover their margin requirements from the CCP.
To mitigate market risk, a CCP will apply haircuts to the collateral it
accepts.
The haircuts for bank guarantees are set in accordance with
the credit ratings of the bank issuing the guarantee.
Concentration risk in relation to collateral refers to the possibility
that the CCP may build up a large direct or indirect exposure towards
individual issuers of collateral. Current regulations (EMIR) pose
concentration limits for collateral, which also apply to bank
guarantees. In addition to exposure towards individual issuers, the
concentration risk can also stem from having large exposures toward
individual clearing members.
The current direct, and hence
diversified, clearing membership structure of the Nordic market
mitigates this aspect of concentration risk.
The economic essence of a bank guarantee is a contingent claim on
a bank. The claim is triggered if the original debtor does not honor its
obligations towards the beneficiary of the guarantee. In case of a
simultaneous default by both debtor and the bank, the beneficiary of
18
.
the bank guarantee will have a claim on the assets of the defaulting
bank, alongside other creditors and depositors.
5.4 SYSTEMIC RISK AND CENTRAL COUNTERPARTIES
By systemic risk we mean the risk that an event will trigger a loss of
confidence in a substantial portion of the financial system that is
serious enough to have adverse effects on the real economy.12
Systemic risk factors
exhibit propagation
mechanisms to the wider
financial system
Systemic risk factors have three identifying characteristics useful for
operational analysis (Taylor, 2009). Firstly, there must be a risk of a
large triggering shock. This may, for instance, be a severe natural
disaster, or it may be the sudden default of a major firm in a sector.
Secondly, there must be a channel or a mechanism for the shock to
propagate to other parts of the financial system. Thirdly, this financial
distribution must affect the real economy.
A major policy initiative in the years since 2007-2008 has been to
identify and handle systemic risk factors.
An important part of this
initiative has been to push OTC derivatives markets onto multilateral
trading venues such as exchanges, and to introduce mandatory
clearing through central counterparties in these markets.
CCPs generally improves
safety and transparency in
financial markets …
… but also introduce new
systemic risk factors
CCPs are considered
systemically important
institutions, and are
subject to regulatory
oversight
A well-functioning CCP can greatly improve safety, efficiency and
transparency in a market. Market participants are no longer exposed
to each other, but to the CCP. If a clearing member defaults, the CCP
may facilitate the transfer of customer positions and collateral of
that failing clearing member to solvent, surviving clearing members,
and coordinate the orderly replacement of defaulted trades through
auctions and hedging of exposures.
The CCP can be characterized as a
firewall, hindering the propagation of an external shock through a
system (Wendt, 2015).
However, since the CCP serves as a hub in the market architecture,
the possibility that the CCP itself may fail constitutes a systemic risk
factor. A potential CCP default may have a severe impact on clearing
members, the affected market, and other linked CCPs. For this
reason, CCPs are considered systemically important institutions, and
are subject to regulatory oversight.
The negative externality to the rest of society, should a CCP
experience financial distress, may rationalize imposing tighter risk
management practices through regulation, than those the CCP itself
would prefer to implement.
However, it is important to keep in mind
that it is not only the CCP capital structure or margin procedures per
12
This is the G-10 definition of systemic risk.
19
. se which reduce systemic risk, but also the transparency and
potential for orderly resolutions these institutions provide. If the
compliance burden on firms for trading on centrally cleared markets
gets too high, there may be a return to bilateral, physical hedging
contracts, in which case the potential benefits of central clearing
disappear.
A second possible systemic risk stemming from CCPs is the potential
for liquidity squeezes imposed by margin calls. If a severe economic
shock affects a market, we will expect to see sharp price movements,
thereby increasing the volatility of the traded assets. The increase in
volatility leads to higher margin requirements from the CCP, which in
turn may lead to a scramble for highly liquid assets by the market
participants.
Since highly liquid, secure assets are in high demand
during times of market stress, this scramble may, in a worst-case
scenario, ultimately lead to a negative feedback loop, with short term
funding markets drying up, liquidity squeezes leading to fire-sales of
assets, and subsequent higher volatility (Brunnermeier and Pedersen,
2009).
This second mechanism of systemic risk from a CCP may be mitigated
by allowing for some heterogeneity in the type of assets that are
eligible as collateral. One could argue that banks are less susceptible
to these feedback loops than, for example non-financial firms, since
banks have access to central bank liquidity facilities and may thereby
transform less liquid assets into base money.
20
. Box 2: CCPs can act as firewalls for the contagion of financial
stress: the cases of Enron, Lehman Brothers and AIG.
The systemic benefits of central clearing can be illustrated by two
of the most severe defaults in the last decade, Enron and Lehman
Brothers.
Enron was a significant participant in the Nordic energy market.
On 29 November 2001, Enron was excluded from all trading and
clearing by the exchange due to its financial distress. On the
afternoon of the same day, the CCP unwound all of Enron’s open
contracts with no substantial losses for any market participants or
the CCP itself (Nordpool Annual Report 2001).
Lehman Brothers had a $9 trillion portfolio of interest rate swaps
when it collapsed in September 2008. The portfolio comprised
66 390 trades across 5 major currencies. On October 8, LCH
Clearnet could report that it had successfully unwound the
portfolio by auctioning the swaps to other clearing members
(Reuters, October 8, 2008).
On the other hand, the lack of central clearing in the Credit Default
Swaps (CDS market) may have significantly contributed to the
financial contagion in 2007-2008 (Brunnermeier, 2008).
The first
CDS were negotiated in the mid-1990s. The instruments act as
insurance against a default, and can be used for hedging credit
risk. In 2001, the total notional amount outstanding in this
derivative was around $920 billion.
By 2007, volumes had reached
around $62 trillion, with collateral comprising 3.42 per cent of
notional amount outstanding (BIS, ISDA Margin Survey 2010). The
instrument was traded over-the-counter and mainly between
dealers. In contrast to interest rate swaps and energy derivatives,
CDS were not subject to central clearing.
Major issuers of CDS, like the American insurer AIG, were selling
CDS on the provision that it would post collateral if either it, or the
referenced subprime debt, were downgraded.
As the major losses
on US subprime mortgages gradually became evident in 2007 and
2008, the market quickly turned its attention to AIG. The provision
combined with the lack of margins initiated a vicious feedback
loop that quickly led AIG to the brink of bankruptcy and a
complete freeze in short-term funding markets. Only the support
of the Federal Reserve prevented the bankruptcy of AIG.
21
.
5.5 SYSTEMIC RISK AND BANK GUARANTEES
Are there any particular systemic risks stemming from the use of
bank guarantees as collateral to the CCP?
Bank guarantees have a
higher risk of loss than
some other forms of
collateral
If the likelihood of the CCP incurring a major loss is higher when it
accepts bank guarantees rather than other forms of eligible
collateral, one could argue that the use of bank guarantees increases
systemic risk. It is not clear that the probability of simultaneous
default is higher when the collateral posted are bank guarantees
rather than some other eligible collateral classes. However, if one for
some reason believes that CCPs insufficiently address the default risk
inherent to bank guarantees (or any other form of collateral) through
the standard risk management tools outlined above, regulators
should ask for adjustments in the risk management practices of these
CCPs.
But one can also argue
that bank guarantees
actually reduce systemic
risk
On the other hand, one can also argue that systemic risk is lower in a
clearing structure with bank guarantees. One reason for this is that
counterparty concentration is lower in direct membership structures
such as the Nordic energy market.
Without bank guarantees, the
market may change into an indirect membership structure, and the
CCPs direct counterparty exposure towards banks will increase.
Higher counterparty concentration for the CCP leads to higher
default risk for the CCP, and thereby higher systemic risk.
The use of bank guarantees may also decrease the risk of a liquidity
squeeze in the financial system. If the universe of eligible collateral is
larger, the probability of a liquidity squeeze is lower, and the system
as a whole is more resilient to shocks.
The most important thing
for handling systemic risk
is making sure that
markets are exchangetraded and centrally
cleared
Finally, the use of bank guarantees may be necessary in order to keep
the power market as an exchange-cleared market. The alternative is
a move to bilateral trading in the OTC market, or direct physical
hedging by electricity suppliers and major industrial firms.
The
exchange-traded market structure guarantees transparency and
central clearing, which is of fundamental importance for a robust
system. Indeed, the current overall market structure of exchangetraded power markets is exactly what the regulation of derivative
markets seeks to accomplish.
22
. 6 LIKELY IMPACT OF REGULATORY CHANGES
We argue that effectively
prohibiting bank
guarantees in energy
markets will likely lead to
changes in firm behavior
and market structure.
These changes induce
welfare costs.
We argue that if the use of bank guarantees in energy markets is
effectively prohibited, hedging costs for non-financial market
participants are likely to increase. One should fully expect these firms
to adapt their behavior in response to the increased costs. Likely
responses are a reduction in the hedging activity of these firms, a
move to an indirect clearing structure, and a substitution by firms of
the current cleared contracts for non-cleared instruments or physical
delivery contracts. There are welfare costs associated with each of
these responses.
In addition, we find the impact of the regulatory
changes on systemic risk to be at best negligible, and at worst
detrimental.
6.1 INCREASED COSTS OF HEDGING FOR
INDUSTRIAL FIRMS
Electricity suppliers report
that their hedging cost will
increase significantly with
the pending regulations
Electricity suppliers report that their hedging cost will increase
significantly if they have to post other types of collateral instead of
the current bank guarantees. In this section, we will illustrate this
cost increase with a general example.
It should be kept in mind that these cost calculations are based on a
partial approach, meaning that they do not reflect changes to the
market structure which are likely to come as a response to regulatory
changes. The most likely structural changes to the market, and their
effects on market functioning, are explored in the next sections of
this chapter.
It should also be kept in mind that the costs calculated
here do not reflect the true economic cost to society. The economic
cost will come from efficiency losses incurred by changes in the
market structure and behavior of market participants. As such, the
effects calculated here comprise the incentives of market
participants to change their behavior in response to the pending
regulations.
Non-financial market participants, for instance electricity suppliers or
producers, can currently choose to post bank guarantees as collateral
instead of securities or cash.
In this example, we calculate the
difference in cost between posting cash collateral and bank
guarantees. The example is stark, but also relevant since many nonfinancial firms will realistically not hold portfolios of liquid securities
that can be used instead of posting cash as collateral The specific
numbers in our example are made-up and for illustration purposes
only, but the structure of the calculation, and the approximate size of
the net cost difference, is realistic.
23
. The cost incurred by a firm when it posts cash as collateral stems
from the funding costs of the firm. For short-term funding, a firm will
typically pay a benchmark interest rate such as 3M EURIBOR plus a
surcharge (which we call the funding spread). Market participants we
have interviewed regard 50 basis points as a reasonable
approximation for a normal funding spread. The firm posts the cash
as collateral with the CCP, and receives a benchmark overnight
deposit rate less a spread (which we call the deposit spread).
A
deposit spread of around 25 basis points in normal times is a fairly
accurate reference point, again based on interviews with market
participants. The net cost of cash collateral is illustrated in table 2.
Table 2: Cost difference between cash collateral and bank guarantees
+
=
+
=
=
Description
Funding base rate (3M EURIBOR )
Funding spread
Funding cost
Deposit base rate (O/N EONIA)
Deposit spread
Net cost of cash collateral
Cost of bank guarantee
Net cost difference
Description
Average position of representative firm
Average collateral posted
Net cost difference (cash vs. guarantees)
Basis points
30
50
80
0
25
105
15
90
Mill.EUR
400
80
0.72
The cost of cash collateral is compared against the cost of a bank
guarantee.
In our example, we have set the cost of a bank guarantee
to 15 basis points, again based on interviews with electricity
suppliers. The cost will naturally differ with the circumstances of the
particular firm. For a representative electricity supplier and normal
market conditions, we find that a net cost difference between cash
collateral and a bank guarantee of around 0.9 percentage points (90
basis points) to be a reasonable estimate.
The final section of the
table shows how this cost difference aggregates into a money
amount. Again, the specific numbers are only illustrative, calibrated
so to match fairly well a representative, medium-size electricity
supplier.
24
. 6.2 REDUCED HEDGING ACTIVITY
Increased hedging costs
will likely lead to reduced
hedging activity
Reduced commercial
hedging activity can
translate into a loss of
market liquidity
In the previous section, we showed how the costs of non-financial
firms are likely to increase if they can no longer post bank guarantees
as collateral. The next sections will elaborate on likely responses to
this cost increase. The perhaps most obvious response of a firm
would be to scale back on hedging activity. Per standard economic
reasoning, firms will hedge their commercial risk until the marginal
gain from hedging equates the marginal costs.
When marginal costs
of hedging increase, one would expect to see, as a first-order effect, a
decrease in hedging activity. When the possibility of using future
contracts collateralized by bank guarantees was introduced in the
Nordic market in 1997, hedging volumes on the power exchange
grew dramatically (see section 3). A ban on bank guarantees may
revert this development.
Reduced commercial hedging activity would imply lower trade
volumes in energy derivatives, which could translate into a loss of
market liquidity.
As liquidity generally begets liquidity, this secondorder effect might, in the worst-case scenario, end up having a
severe negative impact on the functioning of the market.
Reduced hedging activity would entail a real economic cost to
society, as increased capital costs of energy suppliers would
ultimately show up in higher electricity prices and reduced
investments in the sector. Essentially, we would see a partial reversal
of the beneficial effects of energy derivatives markets highlighted
earlier in this report.
6.3 NON-FINANCIALS MOVE TO INDIRECT CLEARING
MEMBERS
Increased hedging costs
may also lead to an
indirect market
structure
It is possible that hedging activity would fall in response to an
effective ban on bank guarantees in clearing. Another possible
scenario is a change in the market structure to mitigate the cost
increases of prohibiting bank guarantees.
One such change in the
structure might be a move by non-financial firms to become indirect
clearing participants. The market may, with this change, take on the
characteristics of a dealer-based market, which in in turn may
adversely affect informational asymmetries, resulting in reduced
liquidity and increased spreads (Ripatti, 2004).
25
. Indirect clearing participants would clear their derivatives
transactions through a clearing member, usually a bank or another
large financial institution. The clearing bank would post collateral on
behalf of the indirect participant.
The move from direct
membership to indirect
participation may have
unwanted
consequences
This indirect structure is a typical feature in many derivatives
markets. However, the move from direct membership to indirect
participation may have unwanted consequences. The clearing banks
will have access to information about the structure and size of
customer positions, which may give rise to informational asymmetry
and adverse selection.
This informational asymmetry may reduce the
popularity of the exchange-traded contracts, leading to reduced
liquidity and a move to bilateral trading.
One can see an example of this mechanism in foreign exchange
markets. There, major banks involved in clearing and dealing have a
significant informational advantage over other participants because
they can monitor FX flows (Bjønnes et al, 2015 and Bjønnes and
Rime, 2005). This advantage makes it difficult for smaller participants
to compete, which again results in less competition.
Seemingly small
changes in market
structure can lead to
major changes in
market functioning
Given that the market for energy derivatives is quite new relative to
other commodities markets, and that the competition from the
bilateral market is strong, small changes to the market
microstructure can be sufficient to cause a significant impact on
market functioning.
For an example of this, see box 3, (“How misstep
over trading fractions wounded ICAP's EBS”).
26
. Box 3: How a misstep over trading fractions wounded ICAP's EBS
(Reuters, September 20, 2012)
“- Who knew a single decimal point could cause so much trouble?
Worried about diminishing market share and increasing
competition, EBS, at one point the world's top foreign exchange
dealing system, took a gamble and decided to let clients trade out
to a fifth decimal point - that's one-thousandth of a cent.
The move backfired. It accelerated a decline in the firm's market
share in the nearly $5 trillion forex market and contributed to a
management shake-up that caused three top executives to leave
earlier this year.”
The example above shows that even small changes to market
structure can have a large impact. The only change by ICAP was to
change the minimum tick size from 0.0001 to 0.00001. This small
change led to a significant drop in EBS market share.
Compared to
the new regulation discussed in this paper, the change made by
ICAP is small.
27
. 6.4 INCREASED USE OF BILATERAL AND PHYSICAL
CONTRACTS
We have seen that the pending regulation would entail increased
costs to non-financial firms, which in turn would likely affect the
behavior of these firms, and consequently the market structure of
the energy derivatives market. This section will describe what we
view to be a highly likely change in the market structure, an increased
use of bilateral hedging contracts based on physical deliveries.
Non-financial firms have
the option to bypass the
financial market, using
non-cleared and physical
contracts
Liquidity and market
efficiency is likely to suffer
Electricity suppliers and wholesale buyers hedge their risk with
financial derivatives because they will buy or sell electricity in the
future. The future spot price of electricity is uncertain, and firms can
eliminate this uncertainty by entering into offsetting derivative
contracts. However, these market participants often also have the
option to enter into bilateral contracts on physical delivery of
electricity at a specified future date.
As such, non-financial firms have
the option to “bypass” the financial market and regulations specific
to the financial marketplace.
An increased use of bilateral and physical hedging instruments is
likely to have a detrimental effect on market efficiency. Firstly,
liquidity in the multilateral marketplace suffers as trade volumes
decrease. Again, as liquidity begets liquidity, reduced trading from
non-financial firms may induce a spiral that ends up having a
significant negative effect on transaction costs and price discovery.
Secondly, as discussed in the previous section, bilateral markets are
more prone to informational asymmetry and related efficiency
losses.
A third detrimental effect of increased bilateral trading is the impact
on systemic risk.
This will be the topic of the concluding section of
this chapter.
6.5 IMPACT ON SYSTEMIC RISK
We have argued that prohibiting the use of bank guarantees will
incur increased costs to non-financial participants in the energy
derivatives market. Likely responses to this cost increase from nonfinancial firms include reducing hedging activity, becoming indirect
clearing participants instead of direct clearing members, or increasing
the use of bilateral and physical contracts. In this section, we discuss
the impact these changes are likely to have on systemic risk.
We will
28
. argue that while the regulation in isolation is likely to give somewhat
reduced credit risk to the CCP, there will likely also be changes to the
market structure that create more systemic risk.
The isolated effect of
regulatory changes is
somewhat lower credit
risk of CCP collateral
The isolated effect of the regulation is that non-financial firms have
to post cash or other high-quality assets as collateral instead of bank
guarantees. In the case of the Nordic energy market, we have seen
that bank guarantees currently make up approximately 70% of
margin collateral. The isolated effect on the CCP of receiving cash or
high-quality financial instruments instead of a guarantee, could mean
lower risk of the simultaneous default of a clearing member and a
collateral issuer. This argument is valid if one assumes that a bank
issuing a guarantee has a higher probability of default than other
collateral issuers.
This might be true for classes of some eligible
collateral, but not necessarily for all.
As for market risk, the risk associated with bank guarantees is lower
than for marketable assets, since these might experience severe price
movements. On the other hand, there might be circumstances in
which it will take some time for a CCP to recover a debt secured by a
bank guarantee, while a liquid financial instrument or cash is
immediately marketable.
If the market adapts to new regulations by changing into an indirect
membership structure, the CCP will likely have higher direct
counterparty exposure towards banks. This could possibly lead to
higher default risk of the CCP, and thereby increase systemic risk.
There is little reason to
believe that prohibiting
bank guarantees will
have any significant
impact on the overall
risk of the CCP
However, central counterparties manage their credit and market risk
using tools such as haircuts and concentration limits, as well as credit
surveillance of clearing members, guarantors and issuers.
These tools
will counteract the risk effect of replacing one type of collateral with
another, less risky type. For instance, if firms replace bank guarantees
with covered bonds, other haircuts and concentration limits will
apply. To the extent that CCPs already internalizes and adequately
manage credit and market risk, there is little reason to believe that
prohibiting bank guarantees will have any significant impact on the
overall risk of the CCP.
The above discussion indicates the important difference between
traditional risk factors such as market or credit risk, and the concept
of systemic risk.
A cornerstone in the regulatory effort to tackle
systemic risk is the introduction of mandatory clearing of derivatives
through central counterparties. As we discussed in chapter 5, CCPs
offer oversight and the potential for ordered resolutions of defaults.
At the same time, it is clear that CCPs have the potential to become
systemic risk factors themselves, as propagation mechanisms for
29
. shocks. Regulation of CCPs should thus aim to maximize the systemic
benefits of central clearing, while minimizing the potential
drawbacks. The systemic impact of bank guarantees should be
understood with this in mind.
The impact on systemic
risk from effectively
prohibiting the use of
bank guarantees will, in
isolation, be small
In isolation, effectively prohibiting the use of bank guarantees will
have little impact on systemic risk. Non-financial firms will replace
posted bank guarantees with financial instruments or cash.
CCPs will
offset the somewhat lower credit risk by haircuts and other risk
management tools. Non-financial firms will experience higher costs
from hedging with cleared derivatives, which in turn are likely to
increase the use of bilateral and physical hedging contracts.
However, the induced
changes in market
structure may have a
detrimental effect on
systemic risk
Bilateral trading of non-cleared derivatives will have a severe and
detrimental effect on the systemic risk stemming from the energy
market. The massive stress contagion coming from the CDS market in
2007 to 2008 provides ample illustration of the perils of opaque and
non-cleared derivatives markets.
On the other hand, Nasdaq’s
orderly resolution of Enron’s Nordic energy derivatives in 2002 and
LCH’s unwinding of Lehman’s interest rate swap portfolio in 2008
(confer box 2) illustrates the benefit of cleared markets.
30
. 7 CONCLUSIONS
Summing up, we find that the direct effect on systemic risk by
effectively prohibiting bank guarantees is small. However, the
regulation may change the market structure in an adverse manner.
The effect on systemic risk is uncertain. Keeping bank guarantees in
their current form will leave the CCP vulnerable to the simultaneous
default of a clearing member and a bank guarantee issuer. However,
this risk is not unique for bank guarantees, but is also present when
participants post other financial instruments as collateral.
The
handling and procedures to mitigate credit risk of different collateral
types do not differ and there is no apparent reason why a CCP should
not be able to handle the risk of bank guarantees as it is handling the
risk of other types of collateral.
Systemic risk may, on the other hand, increase as the market
structure adapts to new regulations. If the market changes into an
indirect membership structure, the CCPs concentration risk would
increase due to larger direct counterparty exposure towards banks,
possibly leading to higher default risk for the CCP, and thereby
increased systemic risk. Moreover, systemic risk will increase if the
energy market moves to a bilateral non-cleared market with little or
no regulatory oversight.
Central counterparties face risk when
accepting bank guarantees as margin collateral, as they do when
accepting any other financial asset. However, we do not find that the
bank guarantees used in energy markets today constitute a
significant systemic risk factor.
31
. 8 LITERATURE AND REFERENCES
Amundsen, Eirik S., and Lars Bergman. "Why has the Nordic
electricity market worked so well?" Utilities Policy 14.3 (2006): 148157.
Bank of International Settlements Seminannual OTC derivatives
statistics.
Bergman, Lars. "European electricity market integration: the Nordic
experiences." Research Symposium European Electricity Markets.
2003.
Bergman, Lars. "The Nordic electricity market-continued success or
emerging problems? " Swedish economic policy review 9.2 (2002): 5188.
Bjønnes, Geir H., Osler, Carol and Dagfinn Rime.
“Sources of
Information Advantage in the Foreign Exchange Market”, Working
Paper, 2015.
Bjønnes, Geir H. and Dagfinn Rime. “Dealer Behavior and Trading
Systems in Foreign Exchange Markets", Journal of Financial
Economics, feb., 2005.
Bouchouev, Ilia.
"Inconvenience yield, or the theory of normal
contango." Quantitative Finance 12.12 (2012): 1773-1777.
Brunnermeier, Markus K., and Lasse Heje Pedersen. "Market liquidity
and funding liquidity." Review of Financial studies 22.6 (2009): 22012238.
Brunnermeier, Markus K. Deciphering the liquidity and credit crunch
2007-08.
No. w14612. National Bureau of Economic Research, 2008.
Carmona, René, and Michael Coulon.
"A survey of commodity
markets and structural models for electricity prices." Quantitative
Energy Finance. Springer New York, 2014. 41-83.
EACH paper - Bank guarantees as collateral for non-financial
participants.
European Association of CCP Clearing Houses. October
2014.
Galbiati, Marco, and Kimmo Soramaki. "Central counterparties and
the topology of clearing networks." Bank of England Working paper.
no.
480. 2013.
Geman, Helyette. "Towards a European market of electricity: spot
and derivatives trading." Universität Paris IX Dauphine, Paris (2002).
32
.
Hicks J. Value and Capital. Oxford University Press. 1939
Keynes J.
A Treatise on Money, Vol II. Macmillan, London. 1930
Ripatti, Kirsi.
"Central counterparty clearing: constructing a
framework for evaluation of risks and benefits." Available at SSRN
787606 (2004).
Samuelson, Paul A. "Proof that properly anticipated prices fluctuate
randomly." Industrial management review 6.2: pages 41-49. 1965.
Milne, Alistair.
"OTC central counterparty clearing: Myths and
reality." Journal of Risk Management in Financial Institutions 5.3 ,
pages 335-346, 2012
Moody’s Investor Service. “Corporate Default and Recovery Rates,
1920-2010”. February 28, 2011.
Mork, Erling.
"Emergence of financial markets for electricity: a
European perspective." Energy policy 29.1 (2001): 7-15.
Nordic FSAs. “The Nordic FSAs request use of bank guarantees as
collateral for non-financial clearing members in line with current
commodity market practice”. Letter from the Nordic Financial
Supervisory Authorities to European Securities and Markets
Authorithy.
21 September 2012.
Nowak, Bartlomiej. "Energy Market of the European Union: Common
or Segmented?" The Electricity Journal 23.10 (2010): 27-37.
Taylor, Charles. “Managing Systemic Risk”.
PEW Briefing paper no.
11, 2009.
Wendt, Froukelien. "Central Counterparties: Addressing their Too
Important to Fail Nature." IMF Working Paper (2015).
World Federation of Exchanges (WFE) / IOMA Derivatives Market
Survey 2013.
33
.