A WINDOW OF OPPORTUNITY
FOR EUROPE
JUNE 2015
DETAILED ANALYSIS
. In the 25 years since its founding, the McKinsey Global Institute (MGI) has
sought to develop a deeper understanding of the evolving global economy.
As the business and economics research arm of McKinsey & Company, MGI
aims to provide leaders in the commercial, public, and social sectors with the
facts and insights on which to base management and policy decisions.
MGI research combines the disciplines of economics and management,
employing the analytical tools of economics with the insights of business
leaders. Our “micro-to-macro” methodology examines microeconomic
industry trends to better understand the broad macroeconomic forces
affecting business strategy and public policy. MGI’s in-depth reports have
covered more than 20 countries and 30 industries. Current research focuses
on six themes: productivity and growth, natural resources, labour markets,
the evolution of global financial markets, the economic impact of technology
and innovation, and urbanisation.
Recent reports have assessed global
flows; the economies of Brazil, Mexico, Nigeria, and Japan; China’s digital
transformation; India’s path from poverty to empowerment; affordable
housing; the economics of tackling obesity; and prospects for global GDP
growth over the next 50 years.
MGI is led by three McKinsey & Company directors: Richard Dobbs,
James Manyika, and Jonathan Woetzel. Michael Chui, Susan Lund, and
Jaana Remes serve as MGI partners. Project teams are led by the MGI
partners and a group of senior fellows, and include consultants from McKinsey
& Company’s offices around the world.
These teams draw on McKinsey
& Company’s global network of partners and industry and management
experts. In addition, leading economists, including Nobel laureates, act as
research advisers.
The partners of McKinsey & Company fund MGI’s research; it is not
commissioned by any business, government, or other institution.
For further information about MGI and to download reports, please visit
www.mckinsey.com/mgi.
McKinsey in Europe
McKinsey & Company is a global management consulting firm, deeply
committed to helping institutions achieve lasting success. McKinsey opened
its first offices in Europe in 1959 as the region’s economy began to recover
from World War II.
The Firm played an active role in that economic rebirth,
working with leading business organisations, as well as governments, nonprofits, and cultural institutions. With offices in 37 cities across Europe, today
we serve clients across a wide range of industries and business areas, as well
as in the social and public sectors.
Copyright © McKinsey & Company 2015
. A WINDOW OF OPPORTUNITY
FOR EUROPE
JUNE 2015
Eric Labaye | Paris
Sven Smit | Amsterdam
Eckart Windhagen | Frankfurt
Richard Dobbs | London
Jan Mischke | Zurich
Matt Stone | London
. PREFACE
Seven years on from the global recession, the European economic recovery remains
sluggish, and talk persists of countries exiting the Eurozone. Yet Europe has fundamental
strengths on which to build. The question is how to use those strengths as a platform for a
return to robust growth.
In this report, the McKinsey Global Institute (MGI), which has studied productivity and
growth in 30 industries in more than 20 countries over the past 25 years, has examined
European growth from three angles. First, the research looked at the supply side and
productivity of the European economy, discussing 11 competitiveness growth drivers that
together would constitute a sweeping programme of structural reform.
Second, MGI has
drawn on previous analysis on debt and deleveraging to examine the current shortage of
aggregate demand in Europe and to highlight various options for stimulating investment and
job creation. Third, MGI conducted a survey and conjoint analysis of 16,000 Europeans in
eight countries during August 2014 to ascertain their aspirations and priorities.
This research was led by Eric Labaye, a director of McKinsey and chairman of MGI based
in Paris; Sven Smit, a McKinsey director based in Amsterdam; Eckart Windhagen, a
McKinsey director based in Frankfurt; Richard Dobbs, a director of McKinsey and MGI
based in London; and Jan Mischke, an MGI senior fellow based in Zurich. Matt Stone
led the project team.
The team comprised Paraic Behan, Josef Ekman, Asher Ellerman,
Sebastian Farquhar, Alec Guzov, Jakob Hensing, Anna Orthofer, Juliane Parys, Björn Saß,
Anne-Marie Schoonbeek, Nigel Smith, Charlotte van Dixhoorn, and Ollie Wilson. We would
like to acknowledge the helpful support and input of MGI colleagues Jonathan Ablett,
Timothy Beacom, Ivo Eman, Lucia Fiorito, Jan Grabowiecki, Karen Jones, Priyanka Kamra,
Krzysztof Kwiatkowski, Arshiya Nagi, Aditi Ramdorai, Vivien Singer, and Amber Yang.
We are grateful to the academic advisers who helped shape this research and provided
challenge and insights and guidance: Martin N. Baily, Bernard L. Schwartz Chair in
Economic Policy Development and senior fellow and director of the Business and Public
Policy Initiative at the Brookings Institution; Richard N. Cooper, Maurits C.
Boas Professor of
International Economics at Harvard University; Howard Davies, chairman of Phoenix Group;
Hans-Helmut Kotz, visiting professor of economics at Harvard University and senior fellow
at the Center for Financial Studies; and Lord Adair Turner, senior fellow at the Institute for
New Economic Thinking.
In addition to MGI’s advisers, we benefitted hugely from insights and feedback provided
by Bruno Bezard, general director, French Treasury; Laurence Boone, special advisor for
International, European Economic and Financial affairs, French Presidency; Michael Bosnjak
of the GESIS – Leibniz Institute for the Social Sciences, associate professor at the Free
University of Bozen-Bolzano; Horace “Woody” Brock, president of Strategic Economic
Decisions; Marco Buti, director-general for economic and financial affairs at the European
Commission; Raffaele della Croce, lead manager, Long-Term Investment Project, at the
OECD; Ian Davis, chairman of Rolls-Royce Group PLC; Klaus Günter Deutsch, head of
the department of research, industrial and economic policy, Bundesverband Deutscher
Industrie e.V.; José Manuel González-Páramo, member of the Board of Directors, BBVA;
Yoram Gutgeld, member of the chamber of deputies and economic advisor to the prime
minister, Italy; Thomas Heilmann, Senator for Justice and Consumer Protection, Berlin;
Kalin Anev Janse, secretary general of the European Stability Mechanism; Ton Kuijlen,
emeritus professor of methodology at Tilburg University; Pascal Lamy, president
emeritus of the Jacques Delors Institute and former director general of the World Trade
. Organisation; Jean Hervé Lorenzi, founder and chairman of the Cercle des économistes;
Catherine L. Mann, OECD chief economist and head of the economics department;
Giles Merritt, founder and secretary-general of Friends of Europe; Rudolf Minsch, chief
economist of Economiesuisse; Peter Mooslechner, executive director, Oesterreichische
Nationalbank; Ewald Nowotny, governor, Oesterreichische Nationalbank; Jean PisanyFerry, commissioner general for Policy Planning, Office of the French Prime Minister;
Baudouin Regout, policy officer, secretariat general, European Commission; André Sapir,
senior fellow at Bruegel; Gerhard Schwarz, director of Avenir Suisse; Jean Tirole, chairman
of the Toulouse School of Economics and a Nobel laureate in economics; Claire Waysand,
chief of staff for the Minister of Finance and Budget, France; Axel Weber, chairman, UBS;
and Thomas Wieser, chair of the Eurogroup Working Group of the European Council.
We also had the great honour of testing and refining our thinking in further confidential
discussions with many policy makers and officials affiliated with governments and central
banks throughout Europe and with European institutions. We thank them all deeply for
their time.
We would like to thank many McKinsey colleagues for their input and industry expertise,
including Konrad Bauer, Cornelius Baur, Alejandro Beltran de Miguel, Kalle Bengtsson,
Kirsten Best-Werbunat, Beril Beten, Marco Bianchini, Daniel Boniecki, Bogdan Buleandra,
Christian Casal, Adam Chrzanowski, Miklos Dietz, Catarina Eklöf-Sohlström,
Nicklas Garemo, Anna Granskog, Philipp Härle, Antony Hawkins, Matthias Heuser,
Vivian Hunt, Alain Imbert, Andrew Jordan, Stijn Kooij, Peter Lambert, Sebastien Leger,
Frank Mattern, Jean-Christophe Mieszala, Jorge Omeñaca, Jakob Österberg,
Occo Roelofsen, Matt Rogers, Jimmy Sarakatsannis, Luuk Speksnijder, Leonardo Totaro,
Thomas Vahlenkamp, Cornelius Walter, Peter de Wit, and Louise Young.
MGI’s operations team provided crucial support for this research. We would like to
thank MGI senior editor Janet Bush; Matt Cooke, Rebeca Robboy, Vanessa Gotthainer,
Rachel Grant, Damaris O’Hanlon, and Vanessa Ratcliffe in external communications and
media relations; Julie Philpot, editorial production manager; Marisa Carder, graphics
specialist; and Deadra Henderson, manager of personnel and administration.
We are grateful for all of the input we have received, but the final report is ours and any
errors are our own. This report contributes to MGI’s mission to help business and policy
leaders understand the forces transforming the global economy, identify strategic locations,
and prepare for the next wave of long-term growth.
As with all MGI research, this work is
independent and has not been commissioned or sponsored in any way by any business,
government, or other institution, although it has benefitted from the input and collaborations
that we have mentioned. We welcome your emailed comments on the research at
MGI@mckinsey.com.
Richard Dobbs
Director, McKinsey Global Institute
London
James Manyika
Director, McKinsey Global Institute
San Francisco
Jonathan Woetzel
Director, McKinsey Global Institute
Shanghai
June 2015
. Chapter photo
Contents: Construction sky
© Getty Images
. CONTENTS
HIGHLIGHTS
In brief
1
1. Europe has a platform for ambitious renewal Page 1
Europe’s recent performance has been lacklustre Page 6
But Europe has a foundation of strength and a window of opportunity for
renewal Page 10
Europeans in eight countries say they would make tough trade-offs to achieve their
high aspirations Page 18
Platform for renewal
29
There is reason to believe that Europe can grow faster with competitiveness reform
and investment and job creation in tandem Page 25
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth Page 29
1. Nurturing ecosystem for innovation Page 38
2.
Effective education to employment Page 51
Boosting competition
143
3. Productive infrastructure investment Page 59
4. Reduced energy burden Page 68
5.
Supporting urban development Page 79
6. Competitive and integrated markets in services and digital Page 89
Stimulating demand
7. Public-sector productivity Page 101
8.
Further openness to trade Page 109
9. Grey and female labour-force participation Page 117
10. Pro-growth immigration Page 125
11.
Enhanced labour-market flexibility Page 132
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation Page 143
Successful reform requires productive investment and demand for jobs—and vice
versa Page 144
A gap in aggregate demand persists in all domestic sectors of the economy, leaving
Europe to rely on net exports Page 145
Europe has several options for igniting investment and job creation Page 161
4. Europe can overcome barriers to action Page 193
Three-quarters of competitiveness growth drivers can happen nationally with
European action to boost investment and job creation Page 195
There are ways to unlock European action on investment and job creation despite
governance, moral hazard, and distributional issues Page 198
Europeans are willing to play their part in their region’s economic
renaissance Page 199
Appendix Page 203
Bibliography Page 229
.
IN BRIEF
A WINDOW OF OPPORTUNITY
FOR EUROPE
Europe’s growth since the start of the financial crisis has been sluggish, and the continent
faces some difficult long-term challenges on demographics and debt levels. But new MGI
research finds that, thanks to a convergence of low oil prices, a favourable exchange rate,
and quantitative easing (QE), Europe has a window of opportunity to undertake ambitious
reforms, stimulate job creation and investment, and unlock new economic dynamism.1
ƒƒ It may be tempting for some observers to write off Europe. That would be a mistake. The
continent has a foundation of strength on which to take action.
It remains a world leader
on key indicators of social and economic progress. And respondents polled in an MGI
survey and conjoint analysis of 16,000 Europeans in eight countries had high aspirations
and expressed willingness to make tough trade-offs to achieve them.
ƒƒ Three areas of reform with 11 growth drivers—many of which policy makers already
implement in some form—can help deliver on European aspirations. They entail
investing for the future (for example, nurturing innovation and reducing the energy
burden), boosting productivity (for example, competitive and integrated markets in
services and digital and more openness to trade), and mobilising the workforce (for
example, increasing grey and female labour-force participation and enhancing labourmarket flexibility).
ƒƒ Three-quarters of the impact of growth drivers can be obtained at the national level.
Best
practice on every key dimension of the economy can be found somewhere in Europe.
The challenge is to emulate that best practice and adopt it more widely.
ƒƒ Scope for structural reform is limited while investment and job creation are weak.
Corporations are piling up cash despite low interest rates, households have cut
investment since the bubble, and governments have adopted austerity policies. While
every sector is acting rationally, collectively they are causing weak demand that means
output is still 15 percent below pre-crisis trends.
ƒƒ Europe has several options for reigniting investment and job creation despite its complex
institutional setup. Measures to unlock financing and quantitative easing can help but
are insufficient on their own.
Fiscal stimulus is not easy to implement at scale in Europe.
New ideas need to be explored, including accounting for public investment as assets
depreciate rather than during capital formation, and carefully adjusting taxation and
wage structures.
ƒƒ By scaling up and speeding up reform mostly at the national level and stimulating
investment and job creation at the European level in lockstep, Europe could close its
output gap, return to a sustained growth rate of 2 to 3 percent over the next ten years,
unleash investment of €250 billion to €550 billion a year, and create more than 20 million
new jobs. This requires trust and the right governance structures that avoid moral
hazard, bundle tight package deals, or lift investment programmes to the European level.
We define Europe in this report as the EU-28 plus Norway and Switzerland.
1
. A window of opportunity
for Europe
€2.2 trillion
a year needed to meet
European aspirations by 2025
Europeans seen willing to make trade-offs—
e.g., more working hours and/or less social
protection—for higher incomes and better
education, health care, security, and living
environment
Pro-growth
immigration
Grey and female
labour-force
participation
M
o
B
an oo
d
11
growth
drivers
In ve
Nurturing
ecosystem for
innovation
he
ng t
lisi
bi rkforce
wo
kets
mar
ing
tivity
st oduc
pr
Enhanced
labour-market
flexibilty
Public-sector
productivity
Competitive
and integrated
markets in
services and
digital
Further
openness
to trade
s ti
g
n
Effective
education to
employment
fo r
t h e f u t u re
Productive
infrastructure
investment
Act within current
governance structure
where possible (e.g., QE)
Test potential for a
post-Maastricht governance
system to enable bolder action
Look at new solutions like
balance sheet accounting and
unleashing household spend
Supporting
urban
development
Increasing
competitiveness
Implementing European best
practice in three key areas
can deliver growth aspirations
75%
can be achieved by
national governments
Reduced
energy burden
Reigniting investment
and job creation
Action needed to kick-start growth
15%
BELOW
Europe’s output is well
below its pre-crisis trend
Growth potential
If Europe undertakes reform on the supply side
AND boosts investment and job creation—moving
beyond crisis management and establishing the
vision, trust, and governance to act at speed and
scale—2–3% sustained GDP growth is possible
2–3
growth
%
. Chapter photo
Chapter 1: Family on steps
© Getty Images
Alamy
. 1. EUROPE HAS A PLATFORM FOR
AMBITIOUS RENEWAL
A number of forces have converged over the past year to provide Europe with a window
of opportunity to accelerate reform and stimulate job creation and investment that has
arguably not been available since the global financial crisis began in 2008. The sudden
and largely unexpected drop in oil prices, a favourable euro exchange rate, the ECB’s
announcement of a QE programme, and an improving business climate all suggest that
2015 is likely to be a strong year for GDP growth (Exhibit 1). This offers a promising backdrop
for an ambitious programme of renewal.
Exhibit 1
Strong 2015 growth projections create a window of opportunity for Europe to commit to
reform, investment, and job creation for the longer term
Estimated drivers of 2015 GDP growth for Europe-30
%
1.7–1.8
0.3
0.3
~0.9
Baseline
growth
0.2
Fiscal impact
of QE
Depreciation
of euro
Decreased
oil prices
Projected
growth, 2015
NOTE: Baseline growth rate obtained when removing buoying factors: implies weak demand/slow reform In line with 2009–
13 average of ~0.9%.
Quantitative easing (QE): assumes primary economic benefit comes from increased accrued
remittances via the European Central Bank, estimated up to a maximum impact of 0.2 percent of GDP. Depreciation:
based on European Commission projections in early 2015; likely to interact with QE. Oil: calculated from shift in net
exports after multiplier impact.
Projected growth: based on early 2015 European Commission projections.
SOURCE: IMF; European Commission; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Europe's GDP
shrank by
0.1%
2007–13
It is important that Europe not interpret these improving conditions as evidence that
no further action is needed to improve the competitiveness of the economy and boost
investment and job creation. Its leaders need to seize the moment because this precious
window may soon close. Many of these trends are temporary or could reverse.
Although
recent trends have led to a cautious return to a degree of optimism about Europe’s
economic prospects, the fact remains that the continent’s recovery thus far has been
sluggish, and considerable challenges clearly lie ahead. Europe has clearly underperformed
on its long-term growth potential since the global financial crisis, with GDP shrinking
marginally by 0.1 percent between 2007 and 2013. Per capita GDP in purchasing power
parity terms has only just returned to its pre-crisis peak for the continent as a whole.
.
Some warn that Europe could be headed towards a deflationary spiral similar to the one
Japan suffered in the 1990s. Longer term, there is apprehension that ageing will further sap
the European economy’s strength and put even more pressure on governments’ finances.
The prime working-age population in Europe is projected to shrink by 4 percent, or 14 million
people, in the period to 2030, and by 12 percent, or 42 million people, to 2050 (there are a
few exceptions to this broad trend, such as the United Kingdom). Furthermore, there are
political challenges. Europeans’ trust in their governments is at very low levels, according to
the Edelman Trust Barometer.1 There are worryingly high debt levels in many countries, and
the stability of the Eurozone is a continuing concern.
MGI’s analysis suggests that action on a broad front to mobilise the continent’s workforce
and boost its productivity—with lagging European economies closing half the gap with the
continent’s top-quartile performers on these two measures—could boost GDP growth
to 2.1 percent a year and per capita GDP growth to 1.8 percent a year on average, with
significant difference among countries.
There is apprehension that ageing will further sap the
European economy’s strength.
Achieving a stronger society and economy will require significant resources and therefore an
improvement from the lacklustre GDP growth of recent years (see Box 1, “Why GDP growth
matters”).
Europe has had a tepid recovery so far. Combined with demographic headwinds
and a slowdown in productivity growth since the 1990s, the European Commission
estimates that annual real GDP growth will be 1.5 percent to 2025. Europe has the potential
to do better than that.
1
2
2015 Edelman trust barometer, Edelman, January 2015.
McKinsey Global Institute
1.
Europe has a platform for ambitious renewal
. Box 1. Why GDP growth matters
The debate on growth today is contentious and wide-ranging, from whether GDP is the right
measure to use, to how growth can be sustainable and inclusive. We agree that GDP has
serious shortcomings as a measure of growth, and we support the search for alternative
measures of economic and social progress. We also acknowledge legitimate questions
about how to make growth sustainable and inclusive.
However, such discussions should
not distract attention from the strong empirical relationship between GDP growth and key
societal goals. Growth is closely linked to employment and therefore has a direct impact
on the economic livelihood of citizens. It also generates resources that can be invested to
improve societal outcomes and deliver on the broader aspirations voiced in the MGI survey
and conjoint analysis.
It helps societies address critical challenges such as managing public
debt or, indeed, combatting environmental degradation.
In fact, the link between real per capita growth and unemployment is almost mechanical.
Unless growth is entirely driven by increasing labour productivity, it necessarily involves
more hours worked and therefore leads to demand for more workers. For example, an
analysis of European unemployment data since the 1980s shows that periods of strong
growth in real per capita GDP have almost uniformly been ones when there have also
been considerable reductions in unemployment. Unemployment across Europe fell
continuously in the late 1980s when the rate of real per capita GDP growth consistently
exceeded 2 percent per year.
As soon as real per capita GDP growth fell below this rate in
the early 1990s, unemployment surged. Similar patterns occurred in subsequent years,
Unemployment fell sharply in the late 1990s and mid-2000s, periods during which real per
capita GDP was growing strongly.
A common charge against GDP growth as a primary aim for economic policy is that
it involves damaging environmental externalities. This is a multifaceted and complex
issue.
An analysis of the evolution of energy consumption in advanced economies since
1970 appears to offer support for the “environmental Kuznets curve” hypothesis, which
suggests that there is an inverse U-shaped relationship between economic development
and environmental degradation.1 This hypothesis posits that the impact of growth on the
environment decreases as economies develop and shift away from manufacturing towards
services. Historically, growth in real per capita GDP in high-income economies increasingly
uncouples from energy consumption. European countries including Germany, France, and
the United Kingdom have reduced energy consumption while increasing real output per
head (Exhibit 2).
Most European countries have reduced per capita carbon emissions since
the early 2000s even while their economies were growing at a significant rate.
1
McKinsey Global Institute
See, for example, Theodore Panayotou, Economic growth and the environment, presented at the spring
seminar of the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe in Geneva, March 3, 2003. One criticism of
the environmental Kuznets curve, which is, however, not contradictory to the argument outlined here, is that
the inverse U-shaped relationship may not hold any longer because countries at earlier stages of development
are increasingly able to mitigate the environmental impact of growth through technology. See David I.
Stern,
“The rise and fall of the environmental Kuznets curve”, World Development, volume 32, issue 8, August 2004.
A window of opportunity for Europe
3
. Box 1. Why GDP growth matters (continued)
Exhibit 2
Beyond a level of around $30,000, per capita GDP is largely decoupled from energy consumption
Per capita energy consumption, 1970–2008
Million British thermal units (BTU) per person
250
United States
200
Australia
150
Germany
France
100
Historical range
for energy
consumption
evolution
United Kingdom
50
China
Japan
South
Korea
India
0
0
5,000
10,000
15,000
20,000
25,000
30,000
35,000
40,000
45,000
Per capita GDP
Real 2005 $ per person at purchasing power parity
SOURCE: International Energy Agency; IHS; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
4
McKinsey Global Institute
1. Europe has a platform for ambitious renewal
. In the immediate aftermath of the global financial crisis in 2008 and 2009, Europe lost
6 percent of real per capita GDP in purchasing power parity terms. Real per capita GDP did
not return to its pre-crisis peak until the beginning of 2015 (Exhibit 3). The path to recovery
has also been uneven. It is evident that Southern European countries such as Greece and
Spain will require several more years to reach their pre-crisis peaks in real per capita GDP.
Surging unemployment levels have been a particularly difficult challenge in Europe.
More
than five million jobs were lost across the continent between 2008 and 2013, especially in
manufacturing, construction, and other industrial sectors.
Exhibit 3
Europe lost 6 percent of output per head during the crisis and has only just recovered
Purchasing power parity–adjusted per capita GDP1
Index: 1.00 = 1Q08
1.06
United States
1.04
1.02
1.00
Europe-302
0.98
-6%
0.96
0.94
0.92
0.90
2005
06
07
08
09
10
11
12
13
14
Expected return
to pre-crisis peak
Gap to pre-crisis peak, 4Q143
%
Europe-30
Southern Europe
2015
~0
~2019
-10.4
Nordics
~2015
-1.5
United Kingdom
and Ireland
2015
~0
2014
2.2
Baltics
2011
2.9
Continental Europe
Central and
Eastern Europe
7.3
3.6
United States
2011
2013
1 Quarterly GDP data from Eurostat converted to 2005 purchasing power parity (PPP) in dollars using 2005 PPP from the IMF; European countries’ per capita
GDP weighted with respective year population.
2 EU-28 countries plus Switzerland and Norway.
3 2014Q4 or Q3 compared with the corresponding quarter with the highest value before the financial crisis
SOURCE: Eurostat; IMF; United Nations Population Division; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
5
. Europe’s recent performance has been lacklustre
Given current primary fiscal balances, interest rates, and projected real GDP growth, the
ratio of government debt to GDP will continue to grow from already high levels in many
European countries, including Belgium, Finland, France, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal,
Spain, and the United Kingdom. This is a source of concern since high debt levels have
historically been a drag on growth and increased the risk of financial crises that can
spark another set of deep economic recessions.2 However, similarly to Japan, most
major European economies will require significant fiscal adjustment before public-sector
deleveraging can begin (Exhibit 4).
Exhibit 4
European economies require significant fiscal adjustment to start public-sector deleveraging
Primary balance—current and required1
%
Primary balance, 2014
Country
Spain
Primary balance to start deleveraging
-2.3
Japan
Fiscal adjustment
required
ï‚¢ –
Percentage points
4.9
2.6
-5.4
4.1
-1.3
Portugal
0.1
France
3.7
-2.3
2.5
0.2
Italy
1.7
United Kingdom
-2.7
Finland
Netherlands
Belgium
1.3
Ireland
1.1
0.1
0.1
-1.0
0.8
0.7
-0.8
0.2
0.4 -0.2
Greece
n/a
1.4
Germany
1.9
1.9
-0.3
-1.0
United States
3.6
-0.8
-1.6
3.6
0.0
2.7
2.1
n/a
n/a
1 Based on consensus GDP forecast, current inflation, 2Q14 government level of debt to GDP, and estimated 2014 effective interest rate.
SOURCE: McKinsey Country Debt database; IMF; IHS; EIU; Oxford Economics; OECD; McKinsey Global Growth Model; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
2
6
Debt and (not much) deleveraging, McKinsey Global Institute, February 2015.
McKinsey Global Institute
1. Europe has a platform for ambitious renewal
. Other major trends appear worrying for Europe’s future, too. Youth unemployment remains
stubbornly high, hovering just under the 20 percent mark across the EU. Unless this
problem is tackled, there is a risk of rising popular unrest. Meanwhile, the risk of populist
parties gaining power and calling for the dissolution of the EU has grown.
Such political
groupings gained significant shares of the vote in the 2014 EU elections. The stability of
the euro and the future of the Eurozone remain subject to concern and conjecture. Greek
deposit outflows reached €500 million a day at some points during early 2015.
At the time
of writing, it is unclear whether Greece will continue to be a member of the Eurozone and
the EU.
On top of all of these factors, Europe is ageing, placing pressure on the pool of available
labour. The European Commission expects that, by 2060, Germany’s population will shrink
by one-fifth, and the number of Germans of working age from 54 million in 2010 to 36 million
in 2060—lower than the total in France.3 Taking all of this together adds up to a dismal
picture of Europe’s future. Without urgent reform, Europe could be on a dangerous path.
Europe's real GDP
grew only
1.1%
per annum
2009–12 and
0.2%
in 2013
Europe’s anaemic recovery was reflected in real GDP-growth rates.
Between 2009 and
2012, real GDP in Europe grew at a rate of only 1.1 percent per year. In 2013, real GDP
growth even decelerated to 0.2 percent. This trajectory was significantly weaker than the
rate observed in past European expansions and has also fallen short of post-crisis growth in
other advanced economies.
Many analysts and commentators even warn that, seven years
on from the onset of the crisis, Europe still risks entering a deflationary spiral and a long
period of stagnation as Japan has experienced since the crisis of the early 1990s.4
Taking a broader view of Europe’s GDP growth beyond the relatively narrow focus on the
2008 global financial crisis and its aftermath, we find that Europe’s growth performance
has been declining since the 1990s (Exhibit 5). This reflects trends in the supply of labour (or
total hours worked) and productivity, the two principal forces behind real GDP growth. From
1995 to 2000, a period when real GDP growth averaged 2.9 percent a year in Europe, 0.9
percentage points came from an increase in the total number of hours worked and the other
two percentage points from increased output per hour worked, or labour productivity.
Between 2000 and 2007, real GDP growth per annum dropped to 2.3 percent.
The hours
worked component continued to contribute one percentage point, but growth in labour
productivity declined to 1.3 percent per annum. Between 2007 and 2013, hours worked
made a slightly negative contribution to growth, and the contribution of productivity growth
also weakened sharply to only 0.2 percent per annum. This collapse partly reflected the
impact of the financial crisis.
Considering only the post-crisis period between 2009 and
2013, annual productivity growth recovered to a rate of 1.2 percent, while the contribution
of hours worked remained negative. However, the fact remains that Europe will need to
improve its performance on both key drivers of GDP growth if that measure is to settle back
into a more robust upward trajectory.
Looking at hours worked, Europe faces a projected decline in the number of 15- to 64-yearolds from 340 million in 2013 to 326 million in 2030. In the period to 2050, Europe’s labour
force is expected to shrink even more dramatically (Exhibit 6).
Our analysis finds that this
trend could dampen real GDP growth by around 0.2 percent a year over the next ten years.
To offset the impact of declining population growth on the labour pool and therefore real
GDP growth, Europe should consider action to boost the participation of women and
older workers and should consider shifts in immigration policy with an explicit view to
boosting growth.
The 2012 ageing report: Underlying assumptions and projection methodologies, European Commission,
April 2011.
4
For an overview of the recent debate on “secular stagnation”, see Coen Teulings and Richard Baldwin, eds.,
Secular stagnation: Facts, causes and cures, Centre for Economic Policy Research, August 2014.
3
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
7
. Exhibit 5
Europe's growth performance has been declining since the 1990s
Decomposition of annual growth performance
%
1995–2000
2000–07
2007–13
Labour
Labour
productivity
Real GDP
Increasing
overall
population
2.0
2.9
-0.2
1.3
Europe-30
2.3
-0.4
-0.1
-0.2
4.3
Real per
capita GDP
-1.2
2.7
0.9
1.9
1.0
-0.3
0.2
2.5
United States
-0.3
3.1
1.8
1.7
2.4
-0.9
1.5
0.7
1.1
1.0
-0.8
0.2
-0.1
0.9
0.8
-0.2
0.6
1.4
1.4
-0.1
1.3
0.1
Japan
0.1
0.2
-0.1
0
-0.4
0.5
SOURCE: Eurostat; World Bank World Development Indicators; McKinsey Global Growth Model; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
8
McKinsey Global Institute
1. Europe has a platform for ambitious renewal
. Exhibit 6
Europe’s prime working-age population is in a steep long-term decline,
dropping by a projected 42 million between 2013 and 2050
Europe-30 prime working-age population (15- to 64-year-olds),
1990, 2013, 2030, and 20501
Million
Baltics
Nordics
United Kingdom
and Ireland
326
15
340
5
17
40
4
44
326
17
4
45
298
18
Compound
annual
growth rate,
2013–50
%
3
-0.7
0.2
68
67
46
0.2
50
Central and
Eastern Europe
-0.8
69
-0.6
-0.3
61
Southern
Europe
79
85
Continental
Europe
120
123
117
111
1990
2013
2030
2050
81
1 Includes immigration.
NOTE: Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
SOURCE: United Nations Population Division; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Given the end of demographic tailwinds in Europe, the onus will be on productivity to
drive growth. Even the recovery in productivity growth to 1.2 percent per annum between
2009 and 2013 leaves the rate of productivity growth relatively weak, suggesting room for
improvement. Our analysis of long-term labour productivity growth in leading economies
since 1800 finds a long-term average rate of productivity growth of 1.4 percent per annum
(with large variations around that average) (Exhibit 7). Historically, every period of weakening
productivity growth has been followed by a rebound to above-trend growth.
This was the
case in the years after the Great Depression in the 1930s and the oil crisis in the 1970s,
for instance.
However, in the recovery from the global financial and economic crisis, this has not been
the case. The rate of annual productivity-growth rate since 2009 has remained significantly
weaker than in the late 1990s, when it was 2 percent a year on average. Europe is not
alone in experiencing weakening productivity growth; a similar trend can be observed in
other advanced economies.
For instance, US productivity growth was 2.5 percent a year
from 1995 to 2000 but only 1.5 percent between 2009 and 2013. Nevertheless, Europe
will have to find ways to reignite productivity growth in order to achieve a more promising
economic outlook.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
9
. Exhibit 7
Productivity per worker has historically grown at 1.4 percent a year with significant variation around that average
Growth of GDP1 per labour force worker,2 ten-year rolling growth3
%
Productivity
Period average
Long-term average
Second Industrial Revolution:
electrical DC motors, telephone,
typewriter, industrial capital formation
3.0
2.5
1.5
Deregulation and
globalisation
Roaring Twenties:
mass production,
especially
automobiles
Railroad,
steam engine
proliferation
2.0
Mass education,
urbanisation
Further
electrification
New
economy
1.9
2.0
1.4
1.4
1.2
1.0
0.5
0.3
Great
Depression
0.2
0
1800 10
20
30
40
50
Pre-railroad
60
70
80
90 1900 10
Rapid industrialisation
20
30
40
World Wars I
and II
50
60
70
Postwar
prosperity
Bretton
Woods
80
Oil
crisis
90
00 2009
Great
Moderation
(deregulation)
1 Highest GDP per worker among group of companies shown; United Kingdom to 1879; United States from 1880.
2 Working-age population is very rough estimate derived from total population and life expectancy. Labour force derived from OECD and International Labour
Organisation data from 1960 and assumed 58% before industrialisation (interpolation in between); 55% assumes 95% male participation and 15% female
participation. We do not consider unemployment.
3 1939–45 and 1914–24 periods linearly interpolated; highest achieved GDP per worker kept constant during recessions/negative growth.
SOURCE: Angus Maddison series; OECD; United Nations; Gapminder; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
But Europe has a foundation of strength and a window of opportunity
for renewal
An ambitious programme of renewal is possible because Europe has fundamental
strengths. It is one of the world’s largest economies, home to a huge, highly integrated
domestic market of 500 million inhabitants.
It also is well connected to global flows and is
home to half of the 20 most competitive economies in the world, according to the World
Economic Forum (WEF). European economies remain world leaders on six dimensions of
social progress and perform well on indicators of economic health.
Indicators of economic health and societal wellbeing correlate strongly (Exhibit 8). While
the causation between societal well-being and economic health is likely to run both ways,
getting Europe’s economic house in order will be necessary to build a healthier society and
meet Europeans’ ambitions.
10
McKinsey Global Institute
1.
Europe has a platform for ambitious renewal
. Exhibit 8
Strong economic performance creates the foundation for improved societal outcomes
Nordics
Continental Europe
United Kingdom
and Ireland
Southern Europe
Baltics
Central and
Eastern Europe
Societal well-being
Z-score composite index, Europe-30 = 0
0.7
0.6
R-squared = 45%
Denmark
0.5
0.4
Malta
0.3
Ireland
0.2
0.1
0
Cyprus
Slovenia
Sweden
Germany
Belgium
Netherlands
Finland
Switzerland
Luxembourg
Austria
France
Spain
Italy
-0.1
United Kingdom
Czech Republic
-0.2
-0.3
Portugal
-0.4
-0.5
-0.6
Norway
Hungary
Greece
-0.7
Estonia
Croatia
Lithuania
-0.8
Latvia
Slovakia
Poland
-0.9
-1.0
Bulgaria
-1.1
Romania
-1.2
-1.3
-1.4 -1.3 -1.2 -1.1 -1.0 -0.9 -0.8 -0.7 -0.6 -0.5 -0.4 -0.3 -0.2 -0.1
0
0.1 0.2
0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6
0.7 0.8
Economic health
Z-score composite index, Europe-30 = 0
SOURCE: Eurostat; OECD; UNESCO; UNODC; World Bank, WEF; WHO; CIA; national statistical offices; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
To measure economic health, we use a composite index comprising five elements:
prosperity, inclusiveness, agility, resilience, and connectedness (see Exhibit 9 for details
on the indicators included in this measure). Countries including Germany, Luxembourg,
the Netherlands, Sweden, and Switzerland that score highly on economic health have
also performed strongly on the six dimensions of societal well-being we have detailed.
Conversely, societal well-being indicators are below the European average in many
countries whose economic performance has been weaker, including Greece, Portugal,
Romania, and Slovakia.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
11
. Exhibit 9
Europe’s economic performance is more varied than its social performance,
but the continent still boasts best practice
Performance on attributes relative to Europe-30 average
Composite indicators; ranges of country-level z-scores1
United States
Europe-30
Countries with top
indicator scores2
Population >1 million
European average
Norway
Prosperity
-1.1
Switzerland
1.2
United States
Norway
Inclusiveness
-1.2
Switzerland
1.3
Japan
Economic
health
United States
-1.3
Agility
1.9
Japan
Sweden
Czech Republic
-1.4
Resilience
1.0
Sweden
Australia
Connect-2.4
edness
Germany
0.7
United States
United Kingdom
1 Measurement of the number of standard deviations away from the mean. The selection of subindicators and metrics, of course, influences country scores;
not all countries have rankings for all metrics.
2 Comparison among Europe-30 countries, Australia, Canada, Japan, South Korea, and the United States.
SOURCE: Eurostat; OECD; UNESCO; UNODC; World Bank; WEF; WHO; CIA; national statistical offices; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
On each of the five elements of economic health, it is only on inclusiveness that Europe, on
average, outperforms the United States. Performance across the continent varies widely.
For example, per capita GDP at purchasing power parity in Switzerland is more than
three times that of Bulgaria. Productivity per hour in Norway is more than 12 times that of
Romania.
Debt-to-GDP ratios in Europe’s public and private sectors range from 109 percent
in Latvia to almost 450 percent in Ireland.
Nevertheless, it is promising that at least one individual European economy represents best
practice on each of the five dimensions. Norway and Switzerland are leaders on prosperity
and inclusiveness, Sweden on agility, the Czech Republic and Sweden on resilience, and
Germany and the United Kingdom on connectedness. If all European countries were to
match the performance of the front-runners on each dimension, a much more robust
continental economy would be created.
Furthermore, some European economies have
made progress in the past few years on crucial structural policies needed to underpin future
growth (Exhibit 10). This gives cause for optimism that such efforts can—as they must—
continue at an accelerated pace.5
5
12
Economic policy reforms 2015: Going for growth, OECD, 2015.
McKinsey Global Institute
1. Europe has a platform for ambitious renewal
.
Exhibit 10
Economic progress indicators
Economic health indicator rankings
Indicator (unit)
Prosperity
Direction of Europe-30
improvement average
Best practice
ï°
147,975
379,550 Switzerland
ï°
47.1
86.6
Norway
ï°
-821
2,611
Poland
Employment to working-age population (ratio of
those employed to overall working-age population)
ï°
0.51
0.66
Norway
Gini, post-tax, post-pensions (distribution of
family income; Gini index – measure of inequality)
ï±
0.31
0.23
Norway
Ratio of highest to lowest income decile
ï±
9.4
5.3
Czech
Republic
Wage share of GDP (adjusted wage share, % of
GDP)
ï°
56
69
Switzerland
Entrepreneurship index (index of development of
entrepreneurship)
ï°
57
74
Sweden
Patents per million capita (per year)
ï°
48
164
Switzerland
R&D expenditure (R&D spending, % of GDP)
ï°
1.8
3.6
Finland
Debt-to-GDP ratio (overall debt as % of GDP;
excluding debt from financial corporations)
ï±
245
109
Latvia
Financial rating (composite financial rating of
multiple economic indexes and credit agency
scores)
ï°
77.8
99.5
Switzerland
Performing loans (non-performing loans, % of
total bank loans)
ï°
92
100
Finland
Dependency ratio increase (percentage point
change in ratio of the size of the over-65
population to 15- to 64-year-old population,
2014–35)
ï±
15
5%
Latvia
Sectoral concentration (Herfindahl index:
methodology to assess sectoral diversification)
ï±
0.06
0.05
Czech
Republic
MGI connectedness index: goods
ï±
18
3
Germany
MGI connectedness index: services
ï±
18
1
Ireland
MGI connectedness index: finances
ï±
33
7
Germany
MGI connectedness index: people
ï±
24
5
Germany
MGI connectedness index: data
Connectedness
(global ranking:
lower absolute
figure is better)
62,858
Per capita GDP growth (change in GDP per
capita, 2008–13, constant 2011 $)
Resilience
33,747
Productivity per hour (real output [measured in
deflated GDP] per hour of labour input, $)
Agility
ï°
Net wealth per capita (net wealth per adult:
assets less liabilities, $)
Inclusiveness
Per capita GDP (constant 2011 $, at purchasing
power parity)
ï±
11
1
Netherlands
Norway
NOTE: Luxembourg and Malta excluded from analysis as outliers, not all countries have rankings for all metrics.
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute European Growth scorecard model; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
13
. Germany
1ST
in world on global
connections
While the current debate on the European economy tends to focus on the negative, it is
important not to gloss over the continent’s genuine economic strengths. Europe is one
the world’s largest economies, accounting for 24 percent of global GDP in 2012, ahead
of the United States at 22 percent.6 The process of European economic integration has
created a single market of more than 500 million inhabitants with a largely free flow of
goods and capital across the European Economic Area. European nations are not only
closely connected with one another, but also more connected into global flows than many
other parts of the world, including emerging and rapidly growing markets such as China,
India, and Brazil. On MGI’s Connectedness Index, Germany is ranked first in the world,
with the United Kingdom, the Netherlands, and France ranked fifth to seventh, respectively
(Exhibit 11).7
Exhibit 11
Europe is one of the world’s largest economies and is more connected to
global cross-border flows than other major economies
Share of nominal world GDP at market exchange rates, 2012
100% = $73.6 trillion
Rest of world
22
26
North
America1
India 3
Russia 3
Brazil 3
Japan
8
24
11
China
Europe-30
MGI Connectedness
Index, 20122
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
…
21
25
27
30
43
Germany
Hong Kong, China
United States
Singapore
United Kingdom
Netherlands
France
Canada
Russia
Italy
Belgium
Spain
Switzerland
Ireland
Sweden
…
Japan
China
Mexico
India
Brazil
1 Canada, Mexico, and the United States.
2 Global flows in a digital age: How trade, finance, people, and data connect the world economy, McKinsey Global
Institute, April 2014.
SOURCE: World Bank; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
North America—Canada, Mexico, and the United States—accounts for 27 percent of global GDP.
Global flows in a digital age: How trade, finance, people, and data connect the world economy, McKinsey
Global Institute, April 2014.
6
7
14
McKinsey Global Institute
1.
Europe has a platform for ambitious renewal
. According to the WEF, ten of the 20 most competitive economies in the world are located
in Europe, with Switzerland topping the global ranking.8 The continent is also home to
many world-class companies, including 142 Fortune 500 companies as of 2014, more
than the 128 based in the United States. Particular strengths can be found in knowledgeintensive industries.9 Twenty-nine of the world’s most innovative companies in 2014 listed
by Forbes magazine are headquartered in Europe.10 Europe retains major trade surpluses
in knowledge-intensive manufacturing and services (2.8 percent and 1.4 percent of GDP,
respectively, for the EU-15 in 2012).
Combined with the right policies and priorities, these achievements can be the bedrock for
a more robust future economic performance. There is scope to improve all five dimensions
of economic health. The key indicator of whether those improvements are made will be GDP
growth.11
Europeans enjoy a high quality of life
The quality of life in European societies is very high.
Out of six widely recognised measures
of social progress—health care, education, the living environment, public safety, social
protection, and work-life balance—Europe scores on average higher than the United States
on four (Exhibit 12).
The views expressed by the Europeans surveyed on what it takes to have a better life
are broadly similar to those of citizens of other advanced economies, according to online
responses received on the website of the OECD’s Better Life Index.12 Like people in
Australia, Canada, Japan, New Zealand, and the United States, Europeans tend to place
emphasis on overall life satisfaction, health, and education. These are dimensions on which
many European countries perform strongly.
<3%
of employees in
Denmark,
Netherlands, and
Norway work
>50 hours a week
However, there is a great deal of variation within Europe on these social metrics (Exhibit 13).
Some countries outperform other nations around the world by a considerable margin;
others underperform. For example, Norway ranks in the top three of a peer group of
advanced economies on education, public safety, and work-life balance.13 Denmark,
the Netherlands, and Norway are the top performers on work-life balance.
In these three
countries, people devote 15.6 to 16.1 hours a week to leisure and personal care, and less
than 3 percent of all employees work more than 50 hours per week. In our set of countries
and chosen set of metrics, Spain is Europe’s leading performer on health care and Germany
is Europe’s leader on education.
The high degree of variation in performance within Europe on these six quality-of-life
indicators and the presence of world-leading examples on each of the six send an important
message. Europe may have experienced several years of difficult economic conditions
since the global financial crisis in 2007 and global recession in 2008, but it still boasts a high
quality of life overall and is home to world leaders on different measures of social progress.
Europe can look within its borders for the solution to the future.
The global competitiveness report 2014–15, World Economic Forum, September 2914.
Knowledge-intensive goods and services are those that have a high R&D component or utilise highly
skilled labor.
10
“The world’s most innovative companies”, Forbes, August 2014.
11
We fully acknowledge the many measurement challenges and conceptual shortcomings associated with GDP
and welcome the many initiatives under way to refine and broaden the measurement of growth.
For further
discussion, see Global growth: Can productivity save the day in an aging world? McKinsey Global Institute,
January 2015.
12
Better Life Index, OECD, 2014.
13
Comparisons include the Europe-30 plus Australia, Canada, Japan, South Korea, and the United States.
8
9
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
15
. Exhibit 12
Despite recent challenges, Europe remains a world leader on various indicators of social progress
Performance on attributes relative to Europe-30 average
Composite indicators; ranges of country-level z-scores1
United States
Europe-30
Countries with top
indicator scores2
Population >1 million
European average
Spain
Health care
1.2
-1.5
Australia
Switzerland
Germany
Education
-1.2
0.8
Finland
Norway
Sweden
Living
environment
-1.7
Finland
1.1
Portugal
Societal
well-being
Norway
Public safety
-1.4
Austria
1.1
Switzerland
Social
protection
Work-life
balance
Ireland
Germany
1.1
-2.0
Austria
Denmark
-1.4
1.6
Netherlands
Norway
1 Measurement of the number of standard deviations away from the mean. The selection of subindicators and metrics, of course, influences country scores;
not all countries have rankings for all metrics.
2 Comparison among Europe-30 countries, Australia, Canada, Japan, South Korea, and the United States.
SOURCE: Eurostat; OECD; UNESCO; UNODC; World Bank; WEF; WHO; CIA; national statistical offices; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
16
McKinsey Global Institute
1. Europe has a platform for ambitious renewal
. Exhibit 13
Social-progress indicators
Societal well-being indicator rankings
Indicator (unit)
Health
Life expectancy at birth (years)
Direction of Europe-30
improvement average
Best practice
ï°
80
83
Italy
Healthy life expectancy at birth (healthy life expectancy
at birth [years] ÷ life expectancy at birth [years], % of
total)
ï°
87.9
90.2
Cyprus
Infant mortality rate (deaths per 1,000 births)
ï±
3.8
1.6
Slovenia
Self-reported good health (self-reported responses
describing good or very good health, %)
ï°
68
82
Switzerland
Mortality from ischaemic heart disease (deaths per
1,000 population, age-adjusted)
ï±
104
48
France
ï°
498
529
Finland
Preschool enrolment rate (% of children aged 3–5
enrolled in preschool/kindergarten)
ï°
88
100
France
Competitiveness of education system (degree to which
the education system meets the needs of a competitive
economy)
ï°
4.30
6.0
Switzerland
Matching of skills (indexed measure of over- or undereducation in workforce)
ï±
0.97
0.63
Norway
Vocational training attainment (25- to 64-year-olds
attained upper-secondary and post-secondary non-tertiary
education, %)
ï°
46
72
Czech
Republic
Carbon dioxide emissions per GDP unit (kilotonnes of
CO2 emissions per € million GDP)
ï±
0.36
0.09
Switzerland
Particulates per cubic metre (PM10, country level
[micrograms per cubic meter])
ï±
27.9
15.8
Finland
Housing quality (composite based on dwelling quality,
housing expenditure, and rooms per person)
ï°
100.4
102.2 Norway
UNESCO cultural heritage sites (sites per 100,000 sq
km land area)
ï°
10.2
32.8
Belgium
Non-congestion rate (ratio of average to free-flow speed,
scores averaged across three speed limit zones)
ï°
0.90
0.93
Czech
Republic
Homicide rate (intentional homicides per 100,000 people)
ï±
1.1
0.6
Austria
Rule of law (index score on perceived quality)
ï°
3.7
4.5
Norway
Political stability (index score on perceived quality)
ï°
3.1
3.9
Switzerland
ï±
12
3
Estonia
ï°
55
91
Austria
Social protection expenditure (total public social
expenditure as % of GDP)
ï°
28
35
Denmark
Redistribution (observed delta between pre-tax/pensions
Gini and post-tax/pensions Gini coefficients)
ï°
0.19
0.27
Ireland
Average time worked (hours worked per year per person
employed)
ï±
1,638
1,380 Netherlands
Employees working long hours (% of employees
working more than 50 hours per week)
ï±
7
1
Netherlands
Time devoted to leisure and personal care (hours per
week)
ï°
15.1
16.1
Denmark
Education Average PISA score (maths, science, reading)
Living
environment
Public
safety
Social
Vulnerable employment (% of total employment)
protection
Unemployment benefits (coverage of contributory and
non-contributory schemes, %)
Work-life
balance
NOTE: Luxembourg and Malta excluded from analysis as outliers; not all countries have rankings for all metrics.
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute European Growth scorecard model; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
17
. Europeans in eight countries say they would make tough trade-offs to achieve
their high aspirations
While Europe is already a world leader on many dimensions of social progress, and
Europeans generally enjoy an enviable quality of life even in comparison with citizens of
other high-income countries and regions, they are not content merely to preserve these
accomplishments. People in eight countries surveyed by MGI express a desire for an even
better deal and are willing to make tough trade-offs to secure one.
This is a key theme that emerges from a conjoint survey of 16,000 respondents in eight
European countries, conducted by the McKinsey Global Institute in August 2014. The survey
asked respondents to reflect on aspirations and priorities for their societies over the next
ten years.14 While we acknowledge that what people say in response to survey questions
may not entirely reflect the way they would vote when presented with actual policy options,
we believe that the results offer an indication of attitudes across eight European countries
that may be useful intelligence for decision makers.
MGI’s survey asked respondents to make tangible trade-offs in order to secure an even
higher quality of life (see Box 2, “Conjoint-survey methodology”, and the appendix for a
detailed description of the survey and the methodology used, as well as the limitations).
The survey found that individuals express broad agreement that even greater effort and
resources should be invested in specific areas.
14
MGI conducted a survey among 2,000 participants each in France, Germany, Italy, Poland, Romania, Spain,
Sweden, and the United Kingdom. Respondents were asked to choose between sets of conjoint scenarios
that trade off a desire to have more or less of different attributes of societal aspirations in a cost- or GDPbalanced way.
The attributes were health care, education, the living environment, social security, public safety,
buying power, working hours, and productivity (here represented by personal factors such as the willingness
to work faster or under more pressure, or training oneself). A model ensures that scenarios economically
balance: improvements in one attribute have to come at the expense of other attributes or willingness to work
longer or more productively. See the appendix for details.
Box 2.
Conjoint-survey methodology
A weakness of many opinion polls is that questions on interdependent issues are often
presented in isolation. This approach can fail to pick up the gap between one preference
and another and how big that gap is, and can lead to unrealistic “wish lists”. Conjoint surveys
are designed to address this problem by requiring respondents to make trade-offs between
different priorities.
The MGI European Aspirations Conjoint Survey on societal priorities over the next ten years
required respondents to choose between GDP-balanced scenarios—that is, combinations
of options that could be feasible economically—as improvements in one priority area
had to be “paid for” through compromises on another.
The eight attributes were health
care, the living environment, buying power, education, public safety, social protection,
working hours, and productivity. The latter two offered respondents the possibility of
increasing overall economic output and then allocating that additional output to the other
six priorities. Respondents were presented with ten sets of two random GDP-balanced
scenarios.
Based on their replies, we modelled optimal or utility-maximising scenarios for
each respondent. These scenarios are the basis of the average scenarios discussed in this
chapter. The underlying GDP model, which is based on current expenditure on the different
social dimensions in the countries surveyed, allows for estimates of the implied change in
spending per attribute as well as an overall GDP-growth rate for these scenarios.
18
McKinsey Global Institute
1.
Europe has a platform for ambitious renewal
. Respondents across countries, age groups, and levels of income and educational
attainment express a common desire for additional investment in health care, the living
environment, education, and public safety in the period to 2025, and at the same time say
they want to increase their disposable income.
The survey suggests that, on average, respondents would prioritise improvements in health
care, the living environment, education, and public safety, and they would be willing to
“pay” for these improvements by deprioritising their work-life balance and social protection
(Exhibit 14). Those surveyed say that, to achieve improvements in these key social measures
and rising incomes, they would be prepared to work longer—in the order of 1.8 hours a
week (0.5 hours to three hours depending on the country)—and more productively, and to
accept a reallocation of spending away from social-protection programmes. Specifically, the
survey shows that 84 percent of respondents say that they would be willing to compromise
on their work-life balance as long as this led to improved societal outcomes and higher
individual incomes—the opposite of the image of a “lazy European”. It is important to note
that, although respondents say they are prepared to invest additional effort to achieve
improvements in their priorities for society as a whole, they also express a wish to see
growth in their individual incomes—captured in the survey by “buying power”.
To realise improvements in health, the living environment, education, public safety, and
buying power, additional resources of €2.2 trillion a year would be required by 2025,
equivalent to 15 percent of Europe’s current GDP.
The survey shows that 84 % of respondents say that
they would be willing to compromise on their worklife balance as long as this led to improved societal
outcomes and higher individual incomes.
96%
of respondents
want improved
health care
93%
of respondents
want improved
living environment
McKinsey Global Institute
Respondents’ aspirations and commitments are broadly shared across Europe
The priority the Europeans we surveyed give to improvements in the different dimensions
of social progress is remarkably consistent.
While our survey does not adjust for cultural
biases, it is notable that people in all eight countries agree on the areas where they would
like to see improvements, namely health care, the living environment, education, and public
safety. They all want their incomes to rise, too (Exhibit 15). There is very little variation in the
ranking of these priorities among different age groups, educational levels, employment
status, and income levels.
In each of these key social areas, more than 80 percent of all
respondents expressed a common desire for improved outcomes, with almost unanimous
agreement that improvements should be made with respect to health care and the living
environment (96 percent and 93 percent agreement, respectively).
A window of opportunity for Europe
19
. Exhibit 14
European survey respondents want improvements to measures of societal well-being and buying power—
and are ready to make trade-offs to achieve them
Results of MGI European Aspirations Conjoint Survey
Aspirations and trade-offs of respondents in eight European countries to 2025 based on
GDP-balanced conjoint analysis1
Conjoint survey responses, n = 16,000
Relative strength of preferences for different social outcomes
Much less
Less
Same
More
Much more
Health care
Living
environment
Buying power
Education
Public safety
Work-life
balance2
Social
protection
Allocation of resources in respondents' preferred scenario
Additional spend and income generation
Living
environment
Public safety
Health care
1.8 hours per week
per worker—a
commitment broadly
shared by those in
full-time, part-time,
or no employment3
Education
Buying
power
Additional spend
and income
Productivity increase
Working longer
(extra hours)
Working more
productively
Spending reallocation
from social protection
to other priorities
91% of respondents would prefer
this scenario over the status quo
1 Averaged GDP- and demographic-weighted optimal levels for each respondent.
2 Calculated as average of working hours and productivity scores from conjoint survey.
3 Calculated based on choices of all respondents irrespective of current employment status; current full-time employees would choose to work 1.6 hours longer
on average. There is a significant spread among countries.
SOURCE: MGI European Aspirations Conjoint Survey, August 2014 (N = 16,000); McKinsey Global Institute analysis
20
McKinsey Global Institute
1. Europe has a platform for ambitious renewal
. Exhibit 15
Countries are aligned on most priorities, although opinion differs on the trade-off between
work-life balance and social protection
Desired change from status quo for country-specific “average” scenarios1
Weighted average deviation from status quo
Germany
Sweden
United
Kingdom
France
Italy
Spain
26
24
Poland
Romania
Health care
Living
environment
Buying power
Education
Public safety
Work-life
balance
Social
protection
Purchasing power
parity–adjusted real
per capita GDP, 2012
€ thousand
34
33
29
29
19
12
1 The “average” scenario takes averaged GDP- and demographic-weighted optimal levels for each respondent.
SOURCE: MGI European Aspirations Conjoint Survey, August 2014; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
The survey also revealed a shared readiness to work longer and more productively
across geographies—and not only among those currently deprived of opportunities to
work because of the economic environment. However, there is some variation among
respondents on how to achieve this shift (Exhibit 16). For example, the survey found that
Polish respondents expressed a preference for generating additional output mainly through
significant productivity improvements but increasing their working hours by only a relatively
modest 1.1 weekly hours per worker. In contrast, French respondents as a group said that
they would be willing to work as much as 2.0 more hours a week while slightly decreasing
productivity.
It is in Spain and Italy that respondents appear most willing to make large
compromises on both aspects of their work-life balance for societal improvements and
their incomes. The survey results show that, on average, Spanish respondents would
accept working an extra 2.7 hours per week and working much more productively. On
average, Italian respondents say that they would be prepared to work 2.5 additional hours
a week and much more productively.
At first glance, these results may appear to reflect
that fact that Spain and Italy have been facing particularly difficult economic conditions.
However, the results also largely hold for Spanish and Italian respondents who are in fulltime employment.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
21
. Exhibit 16
Readiness to work longer and more productively to improve societal
outcomes is common to most countries with some variations
Extra hours worked
Number
Productivity increase
Relative preference
Less
More Much more
2.7
Spain
Italy
2.5
Romania
2.0
1.1
Poland
1.6
Germany
1.3
United Kingdom
France
Same
1.8
Europe
Sweden
AVERAGE
SCENARIO
0.5
2.0
SOURCE: MGI European Aspirations Conjoint Survey, August 2014; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
72%
of respondents
would work longer
In practice, any commitment among Europeans to compromise on their work-life balance
could be achieved in several ways. Reducing holidays, delaying retirement, or bringing
unemployed people into work could have a similar impact to extending the working week
by 1.8 hours. The survey found that, if they were personally required to work more, the top
choice of 54 percent of respondents in full-time employment would be to work more hours
each week; 23 percent of this group would choose to forfeit holidays or delay retirement.
In all eight countries surveyed, working more hours per week was the top choice among
respondents, although that preference was more prevalent in some countries than in
others. For instance, 64 percent of respondents in France indicated that they would prefer
to work more hours per week compared with only 44 percent of respondents in the United
Kingdom, where 35 percent of respondents chose later retirement as their preferred option.
Many respondents expressed willingness to work longer hours not solely as a necessary
trade-off to achieve better social outcomes but also as an intrinsically positive choice if
doing so would increase their disposable income.
The survey asked separate questions
about how long respondents were currently working and how long they would be willing
to work if compensated accordingly. The survey found that 72 percent of respondents
currently employed opted for increased working hours. This was true for workers currently
in part-time employment who would like to find full-time positions and for those who already
work full time and would like to increase their hours moderately in order to earn more
(Exhibit 17).
In contrast, 17 percent of respondents currently employed would like to reduce
their working hours even at the expense of lower earnings, mostly among those in full-time
employment who aspire to part-time work.
22
McKinsey Global Institute
1. Europe has a platform for ambitious renewal
. Exhibit 17
Many survey respondents currently working would be willing to increase their hours moderately
if they were compensated for doing so
Maximum willingness to work1
Hours per week
Weighted group size
>100
90–99
80–89
Readiness to further
increase full-time
working hours
Desire to move into
full-time employment
70–79
60–69
50–59
40–49
30–39
Interest in part-time
employment
20–29
10–19
<10
<10
10–19
20–29
30–39
40–49
50–59
60–69
70–79
Current working hours2
Hours per week
1 Question: On average, how many hours a week do you spend on your work?
2 Question: Imagine you can work as many hours a week as you like and your net income increases accordingly; what is the maximum number of hours you
would work in this case?
SOURCE: MGI European Aspirations Conjoint Survey, August 2014; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
The willingness to work more productively is more difficult to measure precisely than an
increase in hours worked. While many productivity-enhancing measures can be nearly
invisible to a worker, the commitments made in the conjoint survey refer to improvements
that workers could influence directly. These include improved effort, greater ambition
at work, and extra training. One piece of evidence corroborating these commitments
is the considerable support among respondents for performance-based salaries.
The
survey found that 64 percent of respondents believe that salaries in general should reflect
performance “more” or “a lot more” than they currently do. Moreover, more than seven out
of ten respondents would be prepared to make part or even all of their salary performancebased. Only 16 percent of respondents indicated that they already had a performancebased salary, suggesting that there is significant scope to improve the alignment of
incentives with performance in a way that positively resonates with employees.
Although the survey findings on working longer and more productively are broadly
consistent among respondents, there is considerable disagreement on the degree to which
people would want to compromise on social protection.
The survey finds that 84 percent
of respondents said that, in their personal optimal scenario, they would be willing to trim
their work-life balance in exchange for improvements on other priorities. There is modest
variation in the strength of this commitment, according to the survey. However, only
58 percent of respondents expressed a preference for reducing the resources devoted to
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
23
.
social protection. On this aspect of the survey, there are large differences among countries.
For instance, 93 percent of British respondents said that they would accept cuts in social
protection, but only 46 percent of those from Poland, 25 percent from Italy, and 24 percent
from Spain felt the same way. The average Spanish respondent would like to increase social
protection as well as invest more in the other social priorities while making considerable
compromises on the work-life balance. In contrast, on average, respondents from France,
Sweden, and the United Kingdom say they would be prepared to make relatively small
changes to work-life balance and instead opt to cover more than half of the additional
resources required through the reallocation of spending on social protection (Exhibit 18).
Exhibit 18
The degree to which survey respondents are ready to compromise on social protection
varies among countries
Relative magnitude of compromises in country-specific average scenarios1
% of total incremental resources required for preferred outcomes
Working longer and harder
Reallocation away from social protection
Increase in social
protection
spending desired
Spain
100
Italy
100
31
69
Germany
United
Kingdom
France
11
89
Romania
Sweden
4
96
Poland
Decrease in
social protection
spending desired
35
65
Europe
56
44
41
35
59
65
1 Calculated based on conjoint analysis results and country-specific GDP models.
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute analysis
1/5
of survey
respondents would
make large
compromises on
work-life balance
for increased social
protection
24
A cluster analysis gives us more insight into these differences of opinion on social protection
(Exhibit 19).
This analysis reveals five broad groups. Of these, one cluster would like to
increase spending on social protection by making even larger compromises in the worklife balance; this group comprises roughly one-fifth of all respondents, more than half of
whom are from Spain and Italy. A second cluster, with only 12 percent of respondents,
does not favour cuts to social protection but would “pay” for maintaining current protection
by forgoing individual income rather than working longer and harder; respondents from
Sweden are most prominent in this cluster, accounting for one-third of respondents.
The other three clusters all agree that spending on social protection should be reduced
significantly, but they differ on the ambition of their aspirations for the other priorities and
the extent of their readiness to compromise on their work-life balance.
These diverse
McKinsey Global Institute
1. Europe has a platform for ambitious renewal
. attitudes on social protection come from people of all ages, educational attainment, and
employment status.
Exhibit 19
The survey results show some variation in attitudes towards social protection spending
Desired change from status quo in cluster-specific “average” scenarios1
Cluster
I
II
III
IV
V
Cluster size (%)
25.0
12.3
26.8
21.8
14.1
Characteristic
Highest willingness to trade
away social
protection while
preserving worklife balance
Low emphasis on
buying power,
wish to preserve
social protection
Willing to make
moderate
compromises for
moderate
improvements
Highest
willingness to
trade away worklife balance to
improve all other
priorities including
social security
Less aspirational
on societal
priorities, wish to
preserve work-life
balance
Health care
Living
environment
Buying
power
Education
Public
safety
Work-life
balance2
Social
protection
1 For cluster-specific average scenarios.
2 Calculated as average of working hours and productivity scores from conjoint survey.
SOURCE: MGI European Aspirations Conjoint Survey, August 2014; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
There is reason to believe that Europe can grow faster with competitiveness
reform and investment and job creation in tandem
Current forecasts suggest that there is an expectation that Europe will improve on its postcrisis performance. The average of mid-2014 projections from the Economist Intelligence
Unit, IHS, and the Conference Board for real GDP growth between 2013 and 2025 yields
a forecast of 1.7 percent per annum—despite the EIU’s projected decline of 0.4 percent in
the working-age population. The European Commission takes a slightly more pessimistic
view, forecasting growth of 1.5 percent per annum, assuming a slight uptick in annual labour
supply growth by 0.1 percent and a productivity-growth boost of 1.4 percent per annum.
Europe has an opportunity to grow faster by catching up with best practice. To grasp the
potential, consider a scenario in which all countries were to close half of the gap to topquartile European performance on labour productivity and labour-force mobilisation; that
is, the share of the working-age population that is active in the labour force) in the period to
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
25
.
2025. In this scenario, real GDP growth could accelerate to 2.1 percent a year—or more if
Europe adopts the kind of growth-enhancing reforms discussed in this report—and real per
capita GDP growth to 1.7 percent a year (Exhibit 20).
Exhibit 20
Catching up with best practice within Europe could deliver a step change
in GDP growth above post-crisis rates and recent forecasts
Real GDP
Per capita real GDP
Comments/assumptions
GDP growth per annum, %
Catching up with
best practice
Catching up
to top-quartile
performance1
Post-crisis GDPgrowth rate
2009–13
performance1
Baseline forecasts
2013–25
2.1
1.7
0.9
0.6
Average
external forecasts
EU Commission
forecast1
Growth rate achieved if:
â–ª All countries closed 50% of the gap to
top-quartile performance on productivity
and labour-force mobilisation to 2025
â–ª Top-quartile productivity performers in
2012 improved productivity at a rate of
1.4% per annum to 2025
â–ª Top-quartile performers on labour-force
mobilisation maintained constant
mobilisation levels
â–ª
1.7
European real GDP performance
between 2009 and 2013
â–ª
Simple average of forecast 2013–25
from Economist Intelligence Unit, IHS,
and Conference Board for Europe-30
â–ª
European Commission forecast for
EU-27 plus Norway
1.3
1.5
1.2
1 Per capita GDP growth calculated by applying UN population growth forecast.
SOURCE: Eurostat; European Commission; United Nations; EIU; IHS; Conference Board; McKinsey Global Growth Model; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
While the European economy remains so fragile and GDP growth so weak, a growth rate
of 2 percent or above may seem unrealistic. We believe that achieving such a growth rate is
possible, although it will require the right institutional enablers. Other advanced economies
face demographic challenges similar to Europe’s but are expected to achieve real growth
rates of more than 2 percent a year because their productivity is growing strongly.
The US
economy, for instance, is expected to grow in real terms at an annual rate of 2.4 percent
(1.6 percent per capita) despite modest 0.2 percent projected growth in the working-age
population.15 South Korea’s economy is expected to expand by 2.9 percent a year in real
terms (2.5 percent per capita) despite an expected contraction of 0.5 percent in its workingage population.
To deliver on citizens’ aspirations, European leaders need to work together to develop a
comprehensive programme of reform (largely at the national level) and investment and job
creation (enabled by pan-European action). Only this combination will overcome inertia and
get Europe’s growth engine motoring again (Exhibit 21).
GDP growth is based on a simple average of forecasts by the Economist Intelligence Unit, IHS, and
Conference Board; population growth is based on a projection from the UN Population Division.
15
26
McKinsey Global Institute
1. Europe has a platform for ambitious renewal
.
Exhibit 21
Europe will need to work in tandem on reform and support for job creation
and investment
Reform to boost competitiveness,
mostly at national level (75% impact),
supported at European level
Investment and job creation
enabled mostly at the
European level
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute analysis
•••
There is no guarantee that Europe will achieve the rates of GDP growth that we believe are
possible if the region is to embrace reform to boost competitiveness and acts to stimulate
investment and job creation. By the same token, these rates are not the upper limits of
what can be achieved. Europe has fundamental strengths on which to build, and European
citizens express themselves willing to make tough trade-offs to achieve higher growth and
incomes. If they are to meet the high aspirations suggested by the MGI survey, Europe’s
leaders need to set out a programme that delivers a step change in growth compared
with the continent’s recent economic performance and uses the fruits of growth to further
strengthen European society and quality of life.
Europe needs a healthier economic
environment to deliver on what Europeans say they want, and that will require concerted
action on both structural reform and support for investment and job creation. In the next
chapter, we discuss three broad areas of supply-side reform that could become a platform
for a new growth strategy that delivers a better deal for Europe. Then, in Chapter 3, we
examine various options for stimulating investment and job creation within Europe before,
in Chapter 4, sharing some thoughts on whether Europe can—and is likely to—act on
these fronts.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
27
.
Chapter photo
Chapter 2: Class
© Getty Images
. 2. REFORM—MUCH OF IT
NATIONAL—CAN DELIVER GROWTH
Competitiveness is the foundation of any healthy economy. Therefore, an agenda for
sustainable growth must start with measures to deliver a more competitive Europe. A
combination of 11 structural reforms that invest for the future, boost productivity, and
mobilise the workforce could enhance the competitiveness of the European economy and
generate the growth required to meet Europeans’ societal aspirations.
Encouragingly, Europe does not need to look far to find best-practice examples for these
reforms.
The continent can look to its own fundamental strengths and adopt leading
practices found within its own borders. Three-quarters of the positive impact on growth
possible from implementing competitiveness growth drivers can be achieved through
decisions made at the national level, although these will need support at the European
level to boost investment and job creation and foster more promising growth conditions for
reform. Countries will need to prioritise and select which growth drivers are most applicable
to their economies and societies.
In combination, the 11 growth drivers could potentially help GDP growth to reach 2 to
3 percent per annum and sustain it in the longer term—beyond 2015, whose growth rate,
as noted, could be relatively strong because of the confluence of a number of positive
trends (Exhibit 22).
This would be more than enough to meet in full the aspirations voiced
in the survey. These growth drivers could boost Europe’s GDP-growth rate by around 1.5
percentage points a year compared with a scenario in which no reform takes place. That is
the equivalent of adding the current size of the Austrian economy every year.
Cumulatively,
this would have an effect greater than the entire current size of the United Kingdom’s
economy by 2025.
Eleven growth drivers could potentially help GDP
growth to reach 2 to 3 percent per annum.
This estimate does not include any of the interaction effects or overlap among the growth
drivers, although we believe that, implemented in concert, many of the growth drivers would
magnify the effect of others. For example, promoting competitive and integrated markets in
the service and digital sectors will help accelerate the development of a stronger ecosystem
for innovation across Europe by enabling business-friendly policies and standards. Efforts to
increase the competitiveness of European cities could work well in tandem with immigration
policies that are growth-oriented and attract higher-skilled immigrants, and incentivising
new entrepreneurial activity in urban hubs.
.
The 2 to 3 percent that the 11 competitiveness growth drivers could help Europe reach
is more than the 1.5 percent a year that MGI estimates would be needed to meet the
aspirations expressed in the MGI survey (Exhibit 23). Some of the growth drivers may result
in people working longer and more productively, but many others are smarter ways of
achieving growth without necessarily increasing working hours. For example, high-quality
infrastructure provision improves the productivity of workers almost invisibly. Stronger
skills from a well-functioning education-to-employment system allow people to work more
effectively and not necessarily longer or harder.
Exhibit 22
The growth drivers could deliver sustainable growth of 2 to 3 percent even when
oil and currency effects ebb away
Potential GDP growth for Europe-30 (estimates)
%
1.8
2015 EC forecast
0.8
2015 boom factors
Oil
Do nothing
0.3
0.2 0.8–1.5
Euro QE1
0–1.0
European aspirations
1.5
Growth driver impact
>2.0
Potential sustained growth
to 2025
2.0–3..0
1 Projected impact of QE from central bank remittances.
Much of the “Euro” impact also relates to QE; impact of QE
estimated at up to a maximum of 0.2% of GDP; assumes a GDP weighted bond rate of between 1.3 and 2.2%.
NOTE: Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
SOURCE: IMF; European Commission; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
30
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. Exhibit 23
Eleven growth drivers—about three-quarters achievable at the national level—
can deliver on European aspirations
Incremental real GDP growth
% per annum
National-level catching up to leading practice
Leveraging European scale
Enabler
Changing incentive structures and taxation
Investing for the future
Boosting productivity
Nurturing ecosystem for
innovation
0.26
Competitive and integrated
markets in services and
digital
0.43
Effective education to
employment
0.24
Public-sector productivity
0.15
Productive infrastructure
investment
0.14
Further openness to trade
0.08
Reduced energy burden
0.13
Mobilising the workforce
Grey and female labourforce participation
Pro-growth immigration
0.26
Enhanced labour-market
flexibility
Supporting urban
development
0.39
0.15
0.09
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
31
. 3/4
of growth impact at
national level
Three-quarters of the growth potential can be achieved at the level of individual countries—
as long as action is taken to unlock investment and job creation at the European level. The
fact that so much potential for change is in national hands is an encouraging finding given
the complexities of supra-national decision making within the EU. National governments
can play a major role in delivering the growth impact of the drivers, including, for instance,
increasing grey and female participation in the labour force, which will require governments
to adjust labour and child-care policies. Regional and city authorities have a part to play, too.
Each of these can, for instance, contribute to efforts to boost the competitiveness of cities.
National, regional, and city governments have an enormous opportunity to learn from
leading practice found elsewhere in Europe.
Leading practices abound, including
Switzerland’s flexible dual-apprenticeship vocational training system, Denmark’s outcomesbased budgeting in the public sector, Spain’s recent labour-market reforms, Germany’s
support services for exporters in destination countries, Flanders’ pre-commercial
procurement initiative for innovative products and services, and Wroclaw’s efforts to make
the Polish city more attractive to young workers.
1/4
of potential growth
impact needs
involvement of EU
Europe’s supranational institutions need to be involved to coordinate the exchange of
best practice and the delivery of the remaining one-quarter of the potential growth impact
that will rely on leveraging the continental economy’s scale. For instance, the EU can spur
innovation in sectors with significant economies of scale by setting Europe-wide standards
for disruptive technologies or open data, and it can accelerate progress in interconnecting
gas and electricity networks across Europe’s internal borders. The EU is also responsible for
Single Market legislation and external trade agreements, and it can explore European-scale
public procurement to boost efficiency of spending.
It is unlikely that simultaneous implementation of all 11 growth drivers is feasible.
In reality,
countries will need to consider how best to sequence structural reform, and their priorities
will inevitably differ. Drawing on MGI’s assessment of countries’ performance on a range of
subindicators (including, for instance, private spending on R&D, energy intensity in industry,
and the quality of infrastructure relative to income levels), we have identified top performers
on each of the 11 growth drivers and those countries that currently lag behind the European
average on each growth driver by the largest margins (Exhibit 24).
The gaps to that average are quite different for each country. Germany, for instance, has a
gap on mobilising labour.
Poland and Romania have scope to catch up on their innovation
ecosystems and the productivity of infrastructure investment. All European countries
have considerable scope to boost the productivity of their public sectors, but we have not
attempted to quantify this scope due to well-recognised difficulties in measuring productivity
in these sectors. Our scoring system gives us a helpful overview, but we acknowledge that
it is no substitute for a detailed discussion within each country on where its leaders would
place their priorities (Exhibits 25 and 26).
One vital component of enabling the programme of reform that the 11 growth drivers
constitute is ensuring that tax systems are oriented towards economic growth (see Box 3,
“Taxation and incentives”).
32
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. Exhibit 24
European economies need wider adoption of best practice that already exists on the continent
Performance vs. other countries
on each growth driver
Germany
Sweden
United
Kingdom
France
Top third on composite indicator
Top third on at least one subindicator
Italy
Spain
Poland
Romania
Investing for the future
Nurturing ecosystem
for innovation
Effective education
to employment
Productive
infrastructure
investment
Reduced energy
burden
Supporting urban
development
Boosting productivity
Competitive and
integrated markets in
services and digital
Public-sector
productivity
Not quantitatively assessed
Further openness to
trade
Mobilising the workforce
Grey and female
labour-force
participation
Pro-growth
immigration
Enhanced labour
market flexibility
n/a
NOTE: All countries assessed as long as at least two out of three or four subindicators available; limited data availability particularly for Bulgaria, Croatia,
Cyprus, Latvia, Malta, Norway, Romania, Slovakia, and Switzerland.
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
33
. Exhibit 25
Growth driver indicators
Competitiveness growth driver indicator rankings
Direction of Europe-30 Best European
improvement average
country
Indicator (unit)
Nurturing
system for
innovation
Finland
Global innovation index (composite score)
ï°
51.3
64.8
Switzerland
ï±
49.8
18.6
Slovenia
ï°
21
30
Ireland
Youths not in education, employment, or training
(NEETs) (% of the population aged 18–24 with at
most lower secondary education )
ï±
12
4
Slovenia
ï°
37
53
Ireland
Relative length of youth unemployment (time
unemployed for 15–24 age group as a % of time
unemployed for 25–54 age group)
ï±
78
50
Sweden
Competitiveness of education system (degree to
which the education system meets the needs of a
competitive economy)
ï°
4.3
6.0
Switzerland
Quality of infrastructure (WEF composite
infrastructure quality score)
ï°
5.4
6.6
Switzerland
Gap in infrastructure spend (absolute [- or +] gap
between actual and optimal level of infrastructure
spend; % of GDP)
ï±
0.6
0.0
Czech
Republic
Difference between expected and actual quality
(composite score delta, given GDP per capita)
ï°
0.02
1.13
Portugal
Energy intensity in industry (final energy
consumption of industry; tons of oil equivalent/million $
2005 PPP per value added in industry)
ï±
84
29
Ireland
Energy consumption (consumption as a % of value
added, based on inputs from energy intensive sectors)
ï±
5
3
Ireland
Price deviation from European mean (weighted
average of deviation in electricity prices from
European mean; ¢ per kWh)
ï±
2.9
0.6
Denmark
Average electricity price (weighted average for
industry and households, ¢ per kWh, post-tax)
ï±
19.2
9.4
Norway
Urbanisation (% of population living within urban
areas)
ï°
61
83
Belgium
Urban density (people per sq. km. in urban areas)
ï°
875
1,831
Greece
Affordability (% GDP between wages and housing
prices)
Supporting
urban
development
2.4
Tertiary education attainment (% of those aged
30–34 having successfully completed tertiary
education [ISCED levels 5 or 6])
Reduced
energy
burden
1.1
Knowledge-intensive sectors (sector % of GDP)
Productive
infrastructure
investment
ï°
Ease of starting a company (index: lower is better)
(composite score; lower is better)
Effective
education to
employment
Private R&D spending (% of GDP)
ï±
0.5
0.0
Denmark
NOTE: Luxembourg and Malta excluded from analysis as outliers; not all countries have rankings for all metrics.
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute European Growth scorecard model; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
34
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
Exhibit 26
Growth driver indicators (continued)
Competitiveness growth driver indicator rankings
Indicator (unit)
Competitive
and integrated
markets in
services and
digital
Direction of Europe-30 Best European
improvement average
country
30
Ireland
Transposition lag of trade laws (% non-compliance
within national law)
ï±
0.7
0.2
Denmark
Trade law infringements (per $ trillion GDP,
averaged over 3 years)
ï±
90
17
Germany
ï±
0.17
0.10
Netherlands
ï±
1.37
0.92
Netherlands
Extraterritorial trade (extra EU-28 trade; % of GDP)
ï°
10.8%
17.1%
Sweden
Extraterritorial trade to China, United States, India
(% of GDP)
ï°
5.4%
20.0%
Ireland
ICC Open Market Index (index of market openness)
ï°
3.97
4.80
Belgium
Female participation rates (% of male participation
rates, 25–49)
ï°
87%
97%
Lithuania
Female hours worked (% of male weekly hours)
ï°
82%
97%
Hungary
Grey participation rates (55–74 age group as % of
25–54 age group)
ï°
54%
66%
Norway
Non-EU immigrant share (% of total population)
ï°
6.6%
14.0%
Estonia
Education level of immigrants (% of immigrants with
education levels of ISCED 5, 6, or above)
ï°
31%
63%
Ireland
Employment level of immigrants (% of native level)
ï°
92%
116%
Hungary
Net migration from non-Europe-30 countries
(newcomers per 1,000 people)
ï°
1.31
4.53
Sweden
ï±
42%
9%
Norway
ï±
2.52
1.62
United
Kingdom
Employment rates (rate for the 15–64 age group)
ï°
67%
84%
Norway
Unit labour cost increases (2004–13, real
percentage change)
Pro-growth
immigration
6
Product market regulation index
Grey and
female
labour-force
participation
ï°
Services Trade Restrictiveness Index (degree to
which policies restrict trade)
Further
openness
to trade
Intra-European services exports (% of GDP)
ï±
-0.3%
-14.1% Cyprus
Enhanced
% long-term unemployment (% of total
labour-market unemployment)
flexibility
Employment protection index (index of total
collective and individual dismissals)
NOTE: Luxembourg and Malta excluded from analysis as outliers; not all countries have rankings for all metrics.
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute European Growth scorecard model; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
35
. Box 3. Taxation and incentives
A critical part of any discussion on growth is the impact
of tax systems and how they shape incentives. There is
a strong case for tax reform in Europe as a complement
to the competitiveness growth drivers discussed in this
chapter, and to accentuate their impact on growth. Tax
systems that are fair, transparent, and involve minimal
distortions to economic decisions are the most supportive
of economic growth.
On average, European governments take a larger share
of national annual output in the form of taxes than
governments in other countries (Exhibit 27).
France,
Italy, and Sweden, for instance, each collect more than
40 percent of their respective GDP in taxes compared
with less than 30 percent in Australia, South Korea, and
the United States. Of the European countries that are
members of the OECD group of developed economies,
only three—Ireland, Slovakia, and Switzerland—have
a tax take of less than 30 percent of GDP. There is no
strong pattern in the types of taxes collected in Europe.
For instance, 62 percent of Denmark’s tax revenue comes
from levies on income and profits, while in Hungary that
share is only 17 percent.
Effective tax rates on gross
income in many Western European countries are higher
than in other OECD economies. For example, the effective
tax rate on an annual gross income of $300,000 is more
than 50 percent in France and Italy, compared with
around 30 percent in the United States.1 The reason
for this difference is that Denmark, France, Portugal,
and Sweden, among others, have marginal personal
income tax rates of close to or more than 50 percent for
top earners.
1
KPMG’s individual income tax and social security rate survey 2012,
KPMG International, October 2012.
Exhibit 27
European governments typically take a greater share of total output in taxation than those in other
developed economies
Public-sector tax take by type of tax, 2012
%
44
4
Other
Property
43
Social security and payroll
42
1
Goods and services
3
36
1
14
18
Type of tax
Income and profits
33
13
4
32
1
11
12
15
Sweden
11
3
28
3
5
7
Germany United
Poland
Kingdom
5
9
10
Spain
Canada
27
2
1
9
8
8
Japan
South
Korea
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
3
5
12
Australia United
States
Selected non-European countries
SOURCE: OECD; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
24
4
16
9
NOTE: Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
McKinsey Global Institute
7
14
12
11
Selected European countries
36
30
8
12
Italy
3
12
10
14
11
31
12
11
France
2
14
6
10
32
.
How countries design taxation systems is crucial to their success. It is important, for
example, to minimise the degree of distortion on decisions made by different actors in an
economy on labour, capital, and technological advancement. Property and consumption
taxes are generally regarded as involving the fewest distortions, and therefore the lowest
negative impact on growth.16 In contrast, corporate and income taxes are less conducive
to growth because they can potentially discourage entrepreneurial activity and encourage
capital outflow. By avoiding distortions, taxation can increase the overall impact of the 11
competitiveness growth drivers by not creating incentives that work at cross-purposes
to the reforms themselves, such as encouraging capital flight or decreasing the level of
innovation and entrepreneurship in the economy.
Governments inevitably have to balance many competing objectives, some of which may be
inimical to achieving growth.
A comprehensive view of all the relevant trade-offs is important.
For instance, a critical element of making the labour market more flexible—and, indeed,
helping workers realise a better standard of living—is to reduce taxes on labour incomes.
This reform is necessarily considered in isolation in this report. But it is likely to have knockon effects in the broader economy by forcing governments to either raise taxes elsewhere
to maintain the same fiscal balance or to take on additional debt. Both responses will have
social consequences.
Another key ingredient of well-functioning taxation systems is that they are responsive to the
concerns of stakeholders and feature a high degree of cooperation among governmental
bodies to reduce compliance costs.17 There is significant opportunity for some European
economies to improve compliance.
For instance, while it takes only 63 hours on average to
comply with taxes (three major types of taxes: the corporate income tax, the value added
or sales tax, and labour taxes) in Switzerland, it takes 413 hours in the Czech Republic
and 454 hours in Bulgaria.18 Effective tax systems also need to be highly transparent not
only to ensure public trust in the system but also to make it easier to tackle tax evasion and
avoidance and therefore maximise revenue. Effective tax systems reduce complexity as
much as possible. The administrative burden and complexity of a tax system may have
a stronger negative correlation on economic growth than the actual level of business
taxation.19
See Jens Arnold, Do tax structures affect aggregate economic growth? Empirical evidence from a panel of
OECD countries, OECD economics department working paper number 643, October 2008, and Frank Zipfel
and Caroline Heinrichs, The impact of tax systems on economic growth in Europe: An overview, DB Research,
Deutsche Bank, October 2012.
17
Principles of good tax administration—practice note, OECD Committee of Fiscal Affairs Forum on Strategic
Management, Centre for Tax Policy and Administration, OECD, amended May 2001.
18
Paying taxes 2013: The global picture, PricewaterhouseCoopers and the World Bank/International Finance
Corporation, November 2013.
The data cover taxes payable by businesses, measuring all taxes and
contributions that are government-mandated.
19
Ibid.
16
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
37
. We now describe each of the 11 competitiveness growth drivers in detail and briefly discuss
the importance of growth-oriented tax systems as an enabler to these reforms.
1. NURTURING ECOSYSTEM FOR INNOVATION
Innovation—the invention and adoption of new business models, products and processes—
has driven a large share of the astonishing productivity gains the world has experienced
since the first industrial revolution in the mid-18th century.20 For advanced economies
where the potential for further productivity gains from the adoption of existing technologies
is limited, and where companies can compete against lower-wage countries only by
developing new high-value products or processes, innovation is vital for growth.21 For
Europe’s lower-income economies, disseminating innovations is crucial if they are to
continue to close the gap with their wealthier neighbours.
Europe's private
R&D spending is
1.3%
2.7%
of GDP vs.
in South Korea
Comparing Europe as a whole with the world’s most innovative economies reveals a mixed
picture. Europe’s innovation enablers—its education and research systems—are broadly
in line with those of South Korea, Japan, and the United States. Public R&D expenditure is
also in line with that of leading countries.
But some metrics of private-sector innovation lag
behind. Europe’s private sector spends 1.3 percent of GDP on R&D, below South Korea at
2.7 percent, the United States at 1.8 percent, and China at 1.4 percent.
One of the more tangible ways Europe can encourage innovation is by using government
procurement. This approach has a successful track record.
One example is the
way procurement by the US Department of Defense spurred the development of
semiconductors. European governments spend at least 5 percent of GDP on procurement,
compared with only 0.7 percent on public R&D and 0.1 percent on subsidies for privatesector R&D. Other measures that Europe can consider to nurture innovation are deepening
the Single Market in services and digital to enable fast-growing companies to scale up more
effectively, setting Europe-wide standards for transformational technologies, unblocking
barriers to entrepreneurship and accepting “creative destruction” of industries, establishing
standards and platforms for open data that extend to private-sector data sets, and
enhancing digitisation across the public and private sectors.
Action on these fronts could
accelerate Europe’s GDP-growth rate by 0.26 percentage points.22
Where Europe stands
Innovation relates to new technologies, products, and processes or to new ways of
doing business—ranging from radically original ideas to incremental improvements, and
conducted by the public or the private sector. The impact of innovation depends on the
degree to which ideas developed in one company or country spill over to other sectors
and therefore to overall economic growth (see Box 4, “Varieties of capitalism = varieties of
innovation?”).23
Robert J. Gordon, Is US economic growth over? Faltering innovation confronts the six headwinds, NBER
working paper number 18315, August 2012.
21
Global competitiveness report 2014–2015, World Economic Forum, September 2014.
22
This estimate is based on historic correlations between R&D expenditure and growth in total factor
productivity for the richest 15 European countries and assumes that this set of countries increased R&D
expenditure to the same level as the United States.
23
Alvaro Escribano, Andrea Fosfuri, and Josep A.
Tribó, “Managing external knowledge flows: The moderating
role of absorptive capacity”, Research Policy, volume 38, issue 1, February 2009.
20
38
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. Box 4. Varieties of capitalism = varieties of innovation?
The literature on different forms of capitalism illustrates the high degree to which the
structure of a national economy can drive the type of innovation that occurs. According to
the political economists Peter Hall and David Soskice, coordinated market economies such
as Germany and South Korea tend to promote incremental innovation within companies,
while liberal market economies such as the United Kingdom and the United States tend
to be more favourable to disruptive innovation by entrepreneurs. The industrial structure,
financial sector, labour markets, and government policy all have a role to play.1
Coordinated market economies tend to be dominated by private, often family-held,
companies rather than ones that are publicly listed.
Germany’s large Mittelstand sector of
small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) and South Korea’s chaebol conglomerates
are examples. Commercial banks are the principal source of funding for these businesses
and often are closely involved in investment decisions. Companies can take a longer-term
view on R&D and other investments than corporations whose financing tends to hinge on
quarterly results.
Leaders of South Korea’s Hyundai automotive business, for example, set
their long-term strategy over a 30- to 50-year horizon with the aim of becoming the leading
carmaker by 2050.2 Coordinated market economies tend to have a relatively high degree of
labour-market regulation and a strong sense of loyalty among employees to their employers;
long experience and deep expertise in one company can enable incremental innovation.
The success of Germany’s Mittelstand companies is often founded on such incremental but
continuous improvement of existing technologies.
Liberal market economies, in contrast, are more conducive to short-term, radical
innovation than to longer-term incremental investments. These economies tend to use
capital markets as the main source of funding for businesses and to have few restrictions
on mergers and acquisitions (M&A). Pharmaceuticals and biotechnology is one sector in
which companies are increasingly treating strategic M&A activity—the acquisition of smaller
companies with attractive products or technology portfolios—as a substitute for in-house
R&D.
Liberal market economies also tend to have flexible labour markets with low degrees
of employment protection and generally shorter job tenures. A start-up with a breakthrough
idea can easily receive large amounts of venture funding, scale its workforce up and down,
and start afresh when an idea fails. The success of many Silicon Valley start-ups was
enabled by this liberal institutional framework.
Peter A.
Hall and David Soskice, eds., Varieties of capitalism: The institutional foundations of comparative
advantage, Oxford University Press, 2001; OECD reviews of innovation policy: Korea 2009, OECD; German
Federal Ministry of Education and Research.
2
Manufacturing the future: The next era of global growth and innovation, McKinsey Global Institute,
November 2012.
1
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
39
. 5
European
economies in
top 10 most
innovative in world
Despite broad agreement on what innovation looks like and why it is important to an
economy, measuring performance on innovation is notoriously difficult. Two widely used
rankings of innovation come from the WEF and the European Commission. The WEF’s
2014–2015 Global Competitiveness Index ranks five European economies among the ten
most innovative in the world. Finland and Switzerland rank first and second, and Germany,
Sweden and the Netherlands occupy ranks six to eight.
However, many other European
economies score much lower. For instance, Bulgaria ranks 105th out of 144 countries on the
index.24 The European Commission’s Innovation Union scoreboard 2014, which assesses
seven dimensions of innovation, indicates that the EU overall is outperformed by Japan,
South Korea, and the United States on private-sector R&D, and by the United States on
entrepreneurship (Exhibit 28). While China still ranks below the EU today, its performance
has improved markedly over the past five years, narrowing the gap.25
Exhibit 28
Europe is being outperformed most markedly on private-sector innovation efforts including
corporate spending on R&D and entrepreneurship
EU innovation performance competitors
Normalised EU performance relative to the United States, South Korea, and Japan
(EU performance shown as % difference)
United States
Educational attainment1
EU underperforms (>30 p.p.)
EU outperforms (>30 p.p.)
South Korea
Japan
-12
-11
-20
Enablers
Research systems2
Public-sector R&D
Innovation
process
Private-sector R&D3
Entrepreneurship4
Innovation
outcomes
Cluster development5
Economic impact6
58
12
-24
1
-15
1
-51
-53
-29
20
19
-33
-24
-9
-21
33
1
-11
1 Average of the share of new doctorate graduates per 1,000 of the population aged 25–34 plus share aged 30–34 that has completed tertiary education.
2 Average of the share of international scientific co-publications per million of the population and the share of scientific publications among the top 10% of most
cited publications worldwide as a percentage of the country’s total scientific publications.
3 Patent Cooperation Treaty patent applications per billion dollars of GDP.
4 Global Entrepreneurship and Development Institute (GEDI) index on entrepreneurial attitudes, aspirations, and activity.
5 Global Innovation Index survey results on the state of cluster development and collaboration among firms.
6 Average of the contribution of medium and high-tech product exports to the trade balance, knowledge-intensive services exports as percentage of total
services exports, and license and patent revenue from abroad as a percentage of GDP.
SOURCE: Innovation Union scoreboard 2014, European Commission, March 2014; Global Innovation Index; GEDI Index, Global Entrepreneurship and
Development Institute; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Ibid.
The innovation pillar of the WEF’s Global Competitiveness Index focuses on technological innovation.
Non-technological innovation is reflected in the skills, know-how, and working conditions of organisations and
is reflected in different pillars of the index.
25
Innovation Union scoreboard 2014, European Commission, March 2014.
24
40
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. The 2 percent of GDP that Europe spends on R&D is lower than in Australia, Japan, South
Korea, and the United States (Exhibit 29). This share increased by only 0.2 percentage
points between 2003 and 2012, driven by increased R&D spending by Central and Eastern
Europe and the Baltic countries. The EU has a target of spending 3 percent of GDP on
R&D, but only two European countries—Finland and Sweden—have consistently kept
their expenditure above this threshold. On average, Central and Eastern Europe and the
Baltic countries spend only 1.1 percent of GDP on R&D.
It is notable that China already
outperforms most European countries, spending 1.9 percent of its GDP on R&D, and is
on track to overtake the performance of Europe as a whole on this measure of innovation
within a few years. In 2013, China surpassed Germany on the number of international patent
applications filed with 21,000 compared with 17,900 filed by Germany. On this measure,
China now ranks third in the world behind the United States (57,200 filings) and Japan
(43,900).26
Exhibit 29
Europe has a significant R&D gap with South Korea, Japan, and the United States, caused primarily by
a shortfall in private-sector R&D
R&D spending by country and source, 2012
% of GDP
Total
Business sector1
Public sector2
3.6
South Korea
3.3
Japan
United States
0.5
1.4
1.7
1 Including private not-for-profit (0.02% in Europe).
2 Government and higher education.
NOTE: Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
0.7
1.3
1.9
Canada
0.9
1.3
2.0
China
0.7
1.8
2.1
Europe-30
0.7
2.6
2.6
Australia
0.9
2.7
0.8
0.9
-1.6
-1.5
-0.1
SOURCE: Innovation Union scoreboard, European Commission, 2014; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Private companies account for two-thirds of European R&D expenditure, and it is their
relatively low spending that accounts for virtually the whole of Europe’s R&D spending
gap with the world’s top innovators.
Europe’s public-sector R&D spending at 0.7 percent
of GDP is in line with that of other countries. However, the continent’s private-sector R&D
at 1.3 percent of GDP is significantly lower than in South Korea at 2.7 percent, Japan’s
2.6 percent, and 1.8 percent in the United States. Ninety percent of the overall gap in R&D
spending between the Europe-30 and South Korea, the leading performer, is due to lower
private-sector spending.
We draw on filings for patent application under the Patent Cooperation Treaty compiled by the World
Intellectual Property Organization.
26
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
41
.
Within Europe more generally, about 70 percent of private-sector R&D expenditure is
concentrated in large corporations that have more than 500 employees.27 An analysis of
the 2,000 biggest companies in terms of spending on R&D shows that some sectors in
Europe lead the world. In absolute terms, European pharmaceuticals and biotechnology
companies, at €42 billion, spent as much on R&D in 2012 as their counterparts in the United
States and four times as much as Japanese firms. More than half of this spending was by
just five Swiss, French, and British pharmaceuticals companies. German corporations are
the world’s biggest R&D spenders in automobiles and parts.
Overall, European companies
in the automotive sector spend more than three times as much as US companies and
50 percent more than Japanese companies in this sector at €39 billion. Just four German
companies—Volkswagen, Daimler, Robert Bosch, and BMW—spend more on R&D than
automotive companies in any other single country put together, apart from Japan. Indeed,
these four German automotive companies together contributed more than one-third of all
German private-sector R&D spending in 2012.
4
Silicon Valley giants
spend more on
R&D than all
European tech
companies
combined
However, European companies lag behind those of other countries in some sectors.
In technology hardware and equipment, for instance, European companies invest only
€16 billion, one-third of what US companies spend.
In software and computer services,
European firms spend only €6 billion, one-sixth of what their US counterparts spend. In
technology, four Silicon Valley giants—Intel, Cisco, Qualcomm, and Hewlett-Packard—
spend more on R&D than all European tech companies combined. In this sector, the leading
European countries are Finland, the Netherlands, and Sweden, but all of them rank below
China, Japan, Taiwan, and the United States.
In electronics and electrical equipment, the
fifth-most R&D-intensive industry, Japan and South Korea rank ahead of Europe.
Despite its relatively low spending on R&D in several key sectors, Europe still benefits from
a high propensity to adopt innovations from other countries. Google and Amazon are US
companies, but the United Kingdom leads the world in e-commerce, with online retail having
a higher share of total retail than in the United States. The foundation of the success of some
of Europe’s largest technology start-ups, such as Berlin-based Rocket Internet, has been
in bringing US inventions to European markets and then adapting them.
In Sweden and
the United Kingdom, MGI research has found that the contribution of the Internet to GDP is
significantly higher than it is in the United States. In France and Germany, the contribution of
the Internet to GDP is not far behind that in the United States.28
<5%
of Europeans
committed
resources to new
business in 2013
R&D spending is one important part of the innovation story; the other—where Europe lags
behind other economies—is fostering entrepreneurship. The picture is mixed.
On average,
Europe is less inclined towards entrepreneurship than the United States and Canada but
is more entrepreneurial than Japan or South Korea, the world’s leading R&D investors.
According to the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor in 2013, the percentage of European
adults who considered entrepreneurship an interesting career path and who thought about
starting a business in the next three years was broadly similar to the share in Canada and
the United States. However, less than 5 percent of Europeans actually committed resources
to a new business, compared with 8 percent of Canadians and 9 percent of Americans.
Consequently, less than 10 percent of Europeans surveyed currently owned and managed a
business, compared with 13 percent of Canadians and 11 percent of US adults.
Ibid. The estimate of concentration in large companies is based on data for 14 European OECD countries.
Internet matters: The Net’s sweeping impact on growth, jobs, and prosperity, McKinsey Global Institute,
May 2011.
27
28
42
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. One factor that appears to be deterring Europeans from being entrepreneurs is fear that
their business might fail—39 percent of Europeans who perceive good opportunities to start
a business fear that they will fail, compared with 35 percent of Canadians and 31 percent
of US citizens.29 Strict bankruptcy requirements probably contribute to this sentiment.
While US bankruptcy rules discharge the affected party from debts in less than a year and
Canadian rules in a maximum of two years, repayment obligations in Europe range from one
year in the United Kingdom to three years in Belgium, six years in Germany, and more than
nine years in France.30
15–20%
of respondents in
OECD survey cited
finance access
problems as bar to
entrepreneurship
Lack of access to finance is another hurdle deterring more Europeans from owning their
own businesses, and expanding when they do. An OECD survey conducted in 2012 found
that 15 to 20 percent of respondents cited difficulties accessing finance as the main reason
that they could not envisage themselves being self-employed within the next five years.31
Moreover, since the global economic crisis in 2008, it has become more difficult for
young companies to secure later-stage venture-capital funding once they have become
established. In 2013, only around €4 billion of venture capital was raised, compared with
€8.2 billion in 2007. The situation is most difficult for companies after the seed stage.
Only about 40 percent of the companies that received seed or start-up capital in 2013
also received later-stage venture funding, compared with 70 percent before the crisis.32
Government agencies have tried to compensate for the decline of European venture
capital—and today provide one-third of all venture finance—but have not been able to fully
offset it.33
European companies can also do more to embrace the digital technologies that are
increasingly crucial for success in an ever-more-connected world in which more and more
consumers prefer buying and selling and browsing online, which cuts costs and saves time.
Companies need to prioritise which areas to digitise, taking into account the perspective of
their customers (or citizens in the case of governments), underpinned by future-proofed IT
architecture.34
Europe lags behind the United States on private investment, especially in technology-heavy
sectors (Exhibit 30).
This has translated into dramatically different outcomes between the
United States and Europe. The United States has produced far and away more companies
with a market capitalisation of greater than $1 billion over the past 20 years, even accounting
for its relative size. The largest US tech companies are also disproportionally bigger than
those of any other nations.
This may be attributable in part to much higher levels of venturecapital and growth-stage funding, a type of funding that is particularly applicable for tech
start-ups. This type of funding is equivalent to 0.31 percent of GDP in the United States
compared with less than 0.1 percent in most European countries. There are some reasons
for optimism in Europe, however.
Existing entities such as the European Investment Fund
can be leveraged to encourage innovation and entrepreneurship across Europe. This
fund is a major venture capital and innovation investor in Europe, with around €3 billion in
subscribed capital by the end of 2013. In addition, other innovative new financing options
are emerging.
For instance, the Banque publique d'investissement, or BPI, a development
bank in France, aims to finance and stimulate growth in SMEs by providing soft loans for
innovation, guarantees and risk-sharing in support of bank financing, and private equity
José Ernesto Amorós and Niels Bosma, Global Entrepreneurship Monitor 2013 global report: Fifteen years of
assessing entrepreneurship across the globe, Global Entrepreneurship Research Association, 2014.
30
European Commission Judicial Network.
31
Entrepreneurship at a glance 2013, OECD, July 2013.
32
See Enhancing Europe’s competitiveness: Fostering innovation-driven entrepreneurship in Europe, World
Economic Forum, June 2014.
33
European Private Equity Activity Data 2007–2013, European Venture Capital Association.
34
McKinsey & Company Digital Practice. Also see Global flows in a digital age: How trade, finance, people, and
data connect the world economy, McKinsey Global Institute, April 2014.
29
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
43
. investments, along with co-financing loans and partnerships with commercial banks and
other financial institutions. To close the competitiveness gap with the United States in the
technology sector, Europe needs more of this kind of large-scale public co-financing of risk
capital for new ventures.
Exhibit 30
Europe needs to step up procurement and financing of innovation
R&D spending by
type and area1
% of GDP
US R&D spending
2.6
Public gap
0
Private tech gap
-0.7
Private other gap
0.2
Europe R&D spending
2.0
Companies founded in past 20 years
with market capitalisation greater
than $1 billion
Companies per million people
Peak market valuation of largest
Internet company by country
$ billion
United
States
United
States
Germany
1.28
0.06
410
China
200
Israel
United
Kingdom
13
10
Sweden
United
States
Sweden
United
Kingdom
Germany
0.31
0.09
0.06
0.03
7
Germany
Venture capital and growth
investments
% of GDP, 2012
7
Potential initiatives
â–ª Emulate the funding model of the French development bank Banque publique d'investissement, or BPI.
The bank aims to finance and stimulate growth of SMEs
â–ª Deepen the Single Market and set Europe-wide standards and regulations for transformational technologies
â–ª Adopt EU-level procurement of innovative e-government, health care, security, and education solutions on
the order of 1% of GDP
1 Defined as private R&D spend in the pharmaceuticals and biotech, technology hardware and equipment, and software and computer services sectors.
NOTE: Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
SOURCE: The Economist, July 2014; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
44
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. 16
days on average to
start company in
Central and
Eastern Europe vs.
3
in Australia
Regulation plays a part in the disparity between Europe and other regions, too. Take, for
example, how many days it takes to start a business. In Australia, it takes three days; in
the United States, six. But it takes 14 days on average in Continental European countries
and 16 days in Central and Eastern European ones.
The process is quickest in the Baltic
and Nordic countries, but even there, starting a business takes seven days on average.
Moreover, regulatory burdens often increase sharply as microenterprises grow into SMEs.
Once a company in France employs more than 49 people, it needs to comply with six
additional types of social regulation and two additional accounting regulations, including a
requirement to establish work councils with labour union delegates as well as health and
safety committees. In 2005, France had more than 1,600 non-agricultural retailers with 49
employees, but only 680 companies with 50 employees. A similar picture can be found in
manufacturing with 310 companies employing 49 employees vs.
160 companies employing
50.35 In Italy, a large number of businesses do not grow past 14 employees, since Article 18
of the country’s “workers’ statute” places a range of obligations on companies employing 15
people or more.
“Smart” regulation can, however, encourage companies to accelerate the development
of innovative products. Since the early 1990s, many OECD countries have introduced
a combination of voluntary standards and compulsory requirements to promote
improvements in the energy efficiency and environmental performance of products, from
washing machines and refrigerators to lighting and information and communications
technology (ICT) equipment. Sceptics of such reforms claimed that such measures would
impose significant costs on producers and drive prices up for only marginal performance
gains.
On the contrary, by driving innovation through a balanced mix of regulatory measures,
these policies led to efficiency gains of 10 to 60 percent across a range of products,
alongside real price declines of 10 to 45 percent.36
Scaling up new businesses from microenterprises into larger companies is challenging
in Europe. While the continent is home to many microenterprises with fewer than ten
employees, only a fraction of these are successful in building up their size. Europe has four
microcompanies for every 100 people in the population compared with 3.5 in the United
States.
Most of these microenterprises operate in retail, hospitality, and other low-growth
industries. In stark contrast, the United States has 1.1 companies with more than ten
employees per 100 people compared with only 0.4 in Europe.37 Testament to the dominance
of long-established, rather than entrepreneurial, businesses, more than one-third of
Europe’s largest companies today were founded in the 19th century (Exhibit 31).38
Nila Ceci-Renaud and Paul-Antoine Chevalier, “L’impact des seuils de 10, 20 et 50 salariés sur la taille
des entreprises françaises”, Économie et statistique, number 437, March 2011; and Luis Garicano, Claire
LeLarge, and John Van Reenen, Firm size distortions and the productivity distribution: Evidence from France,
NBER working paper number 18841, February 2013.
36
Jacques Pelkmans and Andrea Renda, “Does EU regulation hinder or stimulate innovation?” Regulatory
Policy, Centre for European Policy Studies special report number 96, November 2014; Mark Ellis, Experience
with energy efficiency regulations for electrical equipment, OECD/International Energy Agency, August 2007.
37
Entrepreneurship at a glance 2013, OECD, July 2013.
38
Capital IQ, Breugel, and MGI analysis of the 480 largest European companies by revenue.
35
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
45
. Exhibit 31
Large companies in Europe are, on average, older than those in the United States
Number of large companies by founding date1
Top 1,000 US and European companies by revenue as of August 11, 2014
United States
Before 1800
6
1801–25
6
12
1851–75
1976–2014
-8
-41
52
-39
45
89
1951–75
+27
59
67
84
1926–50
+3
57
93
1901–25
+9
19
30
1876–1900
+6
15
16
1826–50
Europe vs.
United States
Europe
-38
51
189
110
-79
1 Top 1,000 US and European companies by revenue.
SOURCE: Capital IQ; Breugel; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Initiatives to change the game
A set of policies to nurture innovation could accelerate overall European GDP growth
by 0.26 percent a year. This estimate is based on historic correlations between R&D
expenditure and growth in total factor productivity for the richest 15 European countries,
and assumes that this set of countries increase R&D expenditure to the same level as
the United States.39 This estimate of the potential impact on GDP growth is likely to be
somewhat conservative as the returns to innovation grow in today’s less wealthy European
economies where additional R&D spending is vital if they are to attain the per capita GDP
levels of the wealthiest European economies.
Policies to nurture innovation could accelerate overall
European GDP growth by 0.26 percent a year.
39
46
Using a 65-country sample panel for 1965 to 2005, Claudio Bravo-Ortega and Álvaro Garcia estimated that
a 10 percent increase in R&D per capita generates an average increase in total factor productivity (TFP) of
around 1.6 percent. Due to the large gap in per capita R&D expenditure between the United States and most
European countries, these coefficients imply that reaching US R&D levels in the richest 15 European countries
would increase overall European TFP growth by 1.2 percent per year over the next decade. If all Europe-30
economies matched US per capita spending on R&D, their aggregate GDP growth could be as high as
1.7 percent.
If the Europe-30 matched South Korean R&D spending, incremental GDP growth would be
0.3 percent. See Claudio Bravo-Ortega and Álvaro Garcia, “R&D and productivity: A two way avenue?” World
Development, volume 39, issue 7, July 2011.
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
Governments can be effective in stimulating innovation across the innovation value chain
from the initial development of new ideas to their commercialisation and adoption. While
much of the focus has been on incentivising innovation at its source—through R&D
subsidies—there is increasing recognition that interventions further down the value chain
can be at least as effective, if not more so.40 Among the imperatives that we see as most
important are the following:
ƒƒ Deepen the Single Market. European governments can help to spur overall adoption
by widening and deepening the market for innovative products. Many European policy
makers, including the European Commission, have argued that completing the Single
Market is one of the most powerful levers to promote innovation in Europe.
Doing so
would not only expand the customer base for innovative products but also promote
innovation spillovers between companies and entrepreneurs.41
ƒƒ Set Europe-wide standards and regulations for transformational technologies
such as Industry 4.0. Beyond dismantling the barriers to a fully integrated European
Single Market, policy makers could be proactive in their use of pan-European standards
and regulations to make the market for innovative technologies both more predictable
and more integrated. Such standards and regulations will have the most impact in
industries with significant scale economies, including network effects, or where the
production process is capital-intensive as it is in the manufacture of autonomous
vehicles.
Previous MGI research has identified 12 transformational—or disruptive—
technologies that governments could promote more than they do now.42 For example,
the Internet of Things—the embedding of sensors in physical objects—could be
advanced through European technology standards to enable interoperability between
sensors and computers. In the transport sector, for instance, EU countries have already
agreed on common standards for communication between cars and traffic infrastructure
in certain areas. Further standards are needed to increase road efficiency, safety, and
the environmental sustainability of driving.
For instance, European policy makers could
consider putting in place a common legislative and regulatory framework that would
govern autonomous vehicles. Individual countries are already pioneering change in this
area. In the absence of EU legislation or standards, the United Kingdom is contemplating
enacting a legal framework to allow the testing and deployment of autonomous vehicles
on public roads.43
ƒƒ Gear public procurement spending, including defence spending, towards
supporting innovation.
European governments spend at least 5 percent of GDP
on procurement compared with only 0.7 percent on public R&D and 0.1 percent
on subsidies for private-sector R&D. Public procurement can therefore be a potent
tool for incentivising innovation. However, opportunities to use procurement to drive
innovation are not always fully realised for a number of reasons.
Incentives are often
not aligned, with procurers tending to favour low-cost, low-risk solutions even if greater
long-term benefits can be derived by testing and procuring new technologies. The
public authorities responsible for purchasing often lack in-depth knowledge of the
new technologies available, while overly complex procurement procedures can be
discouraging, particularly to SMEs.44
Demand-side innovation policies, OECD, May 2011.
Simon Tilford and Philip Whyte, eds., Innovation: How Europe can take off, Centre for European Reform,
July 2011.
42
Disruptive technologies: Advances that will transform life, business, and the global economy, McKinsey Global
Institute, May 2013.
43
Chandrika Nath, Autonomous road vehicles, Houses of Parliament PostNote number 443, September 2013,
amended April 2014.
44
Jacques Pelkmans and Andrea Renda, “Does EU regulation hinder or stimulate innovation?” Regulatory
Policy, Centre for European Policy Studies special report number 96, November 2014.
40
41
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
47
. Despite these challenges, several European governments have already shown
how public procurement can be used to further innovation in areas where society
faces challenges, including the ageing of the population and the degradation of the
environment, and in public services such as health care and transport.45 In Belgium,
for instance, through the Flemish pre-commercial procurement initiative, public
entities procure R&D services before launching conventional open tenders for the final
procurement of the resulting product or services. Projects that have emerged from
this approach include a digital book platform for public libraries and an eye screener to
detect amblyopia among children.46 Another example is the Nordic Lighthouse Project
on Public Procurement and Health Care, through which the five Nordic countries
hold joint cross-border public tenders with public health-care providers for innovative
solutions in this sector. Projects that have come to fruition as part of this scheme include
PVC-free blood bags and “intelligent” hospital beds.47 The City of Vienna’s online
platform for procurement, “WienWin”, connects local innovators with procurement
officials in the city’s government and public services. The procurement officers act as
pilot customers who can refer successful products to private-sector buyers.
Projects
that have been developed using this approach include resource-efficient street lights and
water-saving drip irrigation for public gardens.48
>€5B
One way to bridge the gap in private-sector investment in R&D is through tax incentives,
increasingly in use in OECD economies. For example, France’s Crédit d’impot recherche
(CIR) offers a tax break amounting to a 30 percent refund of R&D expenses on the
first €100 million invested and a 5 percent refund beyond that. France refunded more
than €5 billion through this mechanism in 2012.
Although the majority flowed to large
corporations, 29 percent of this funding benefited SMEs.
refunded through
French tax
incentives in 2012
In the United States, the most prevalent form of innovation-promoting public
procurement is in the defence sector. Between 1974 and 1995, for instance, the US
Department of Defense invested approximately $10 billion in the Global Positioning
System.49 GPS was first made available for civilian aircraft and quickly found other uses
in consumer and business applications. Thanks to open GPS data, entire new industries
in GPS and mapping services have developed, including surveying, automotive
navigation, and precision agriculture.
In 2013, revenue from Global Navigation Satellite
Systems totalled about €50 billion. Location-based services on smartphones are
beginning to overtake automotive navigation systems as the largest market segment in
terms of revenue.50
Defence spending in Europe is much lower than in the United States. In 2012, the 27
members of the European Defence Agency spent €190 billion, or 1.5 percent of GDP,
on defence; the equivalent number for the United States was €500 billion ($645 billion),
4.4 percent of GDP.
Within this overall defence budget, defence procurement in Europe
is still an important lever for procuring innovation. European countries could increase
their effectiveness in this regard by creating an open and competitive single market in
defence.51
Andrea Petrella, Fostering innovation through public procurement: Rationale, implementation and best
practice in Italy and Europe, Bank of Italy Regional Economic Research Department, 2013; Demand-side
innovation policies, OECD, May 2011.
46
Innovatief Aanbesteden.
47
Norden.org.
48
WienWin.at.
49
Scott Pace et al., The Global Positioning System, Rand Corporation, 1995.
50
GNSS Market Report, October 2013.
51
The 27 members of the European Defence Agency are the 28 EU member states except Denmark. See Ian
Bond, The EU and defence procurement, Centre for European Reform, January 2014.
45
48
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. ƒƒ Unblock the barriers to entrepreneurship and accept “creative disruption”
across sectors. The United Kingdom offers many aspects of best practice on
promoting entrepreneurship in Europe. It is attracting entrepreneurial talent from
overseas by offering a “start-up” visa for immigrants. The personal risks associated with
entrepreneurship are much lower than in other countries; repayment obligations under
bankruptcy last only one year (compared with France’s nine to ten years, as we have
noted).
Moreover, the United Kingdom has facilitated access to seed and growth finance
for entrepreneurs, putting in place a seed enterprise investment scheme that provides
tax breaks to early-stage investors and relaxing the barriers to stock exchange listings.
Similar measures to promote entrepreneurship have been suggested and debated
across the continent. If European policy makers want to promote entrepreneurship,
however, it is essential that an underlying issue be resolved. Joseph Schumpeter
famously argued that the emergence of innovative firms is inseparably intertwined with
the decline of uncompetitive incumbents—a process known as creative destruction.52
Some 65 years later, recent experience suggests that many European policy makers
are still reluctant to accept creative destruction.
An example of this discomfort includes
the attempt to ban Uber travel-sharing services in Germany and many other countries.
Such barriers to entry by new players need to be lowered if entrepreneurship is to flourish
in Europe.
2,500
data sets open in
United Kingdom in
2009 and
10,000
in 2013
ƒƒ Establish standards and platforms for open data in the private as well as the
public sector. Open government data is already providing significant opportunities for
innovation and new business ideas.53 The United States pioneered open data by making
weather and GPS data freely available, spurring the development of navigation systems,
weather newscasts, location-based applications, precision farming tools, and other
applications. An executive order in 2013 required that the new default for government
information is to be open and machine-readable except where this would jeopardise
privacy, confidentiality, or national security.54 The United Kingdom established an Open
Government Data initiative in 2009 and is pioneering the publishing of data on a full
range of maps, land ownership, census, government budget and spending, company
registers, legislation, public transport, international trade, health care, education, crime,
environment, and election results.
In 2009, 2,500 data sets were open; by 2013, this tally
had grown to 10,000.
The next horizon is for governments to establish standards and platforms in collaboration
with the private sector to provide open access to anonymised private-sector data sets.
One idea would be to introduce the concept of “data patents”—the right of companies
to keep proprietary data to themselves for a number of years with a requirement to
subsequently make them publicly available in an anonymised and machine-readable
format. There is already growing interest among companies in publishing their data for
purposes of open innovation. In 2006, for example, the video streaming company Netflix
published more than 100 million anonymised user ratings and launched a competition
for the best predictive algorithm for these ratings, leading to a more than 10 percent
improvement in its predictions.55
Simon Tilford and Philip Whyte, eds., Innovation: How Europe can take off, Centre for European Reform,
July 2011.
53
Open data: Unlocking innovation and performance with liquid information, McKinsey Global Institute,
October 2013.
54
Executive order: Making open and machine readable the new default for government information, US White
House, May 9, 2013.
55
www.netflixprize.com.
52
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
49
.
ƒƒ Embrace digitisation across the public and private sectors. Digitisation is reshaping
the rules of competition in the private sector with many well-established incumbents
at risk of being left behind in the face of competition from digitally savvy and nimble
new entrants. Digital technologies are a powerful tool for lowering barriers to market
entry across sectors and regions. Digitally enabled new players can scale up rapidly
at a lower cost than those companies or organisations with legacy technologies, and
enjoy higher returns as network effects accelerate.56 Digitising on a large scale in both
the public and private sectors will be a crucial part of any efforts to boost European
innovation.
In the private sector, digitisation drives innovation by enabling new business
or operating models such as rapid product design and testing or smarter customer
service. It also enables superior management decisions through the use of algorithms
to crunch big data from social technologies, freeing up resources to focus on more
creative efforts. Companies should take full advantage of the opportunities offered by
digital sales channels to reduce costs, increase efficiency, and offer broader access
to new markets.57 Digitisation in the public sector is very important for similar reasons.
Customers and citizens increasingly demand easy-to-use digital services when they
interact with public agencies.
Embracing digitisation in the public sector can also boost
performance and productivity by minimising inefficient work, and freeing up resources.
Most companies—and governments—recognise the power of digital technologies,
but embedding these fully will require coordination. The first step is to ensure that
businesses, governments, and citizens have reliable access to high-speed Internet.
Second, there will be a need for more training to establish a “digital-first” attitude and
provide the advanced skills required to take advantage of these technologies. In many
European countries (as in other regions) the share of “knowledge” workers is rising—they
need to be fully equipped.
European countries can measure their progress on digitisation
using metrics such as the European Commission’s Digital Economy and Society Index,
which scores countries on various dimensions of digital performance.
Martin Hirt and Paul Wilmott, “Strategic principles for competing in the digital age”, McKinsey Quarterly,
May 2014.
57
European Commission Digital Agenda, Digital Economy and Society Index.
56
50
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. 2. EFFECTIVE EDUCATION TO EMPLOYMENT
Improving
education to
employment
could add
0.24
percentage points
to Europe's annual
GDP growth
Education is a foundation of labour productivity. There are many pockets of excellence in
Europe’s education systems, but there are also parts of the region where the provision and
quality of education is not equipping young people well enough with the skills they need
in the 21st-century economy. Seventy-four percent of educators say they are adequately
preparing graduates for the workforce, but only 35 percent of employers and 38 percent of
students say the same.
Meanwhile, we estimate the supply-demand balance for workers
with tertiary education will move from a rough balance in 2010 to a shortage of 16 million
workers in 2020. Fortunately, many highly effective education systems within Europe—
in Finland and the Netherlands, for instance—can provide inspiration and examples to
other countries. Among the measures European leaders could consider are increasing
transparency about what skills are needed and jobs are available, dual-apprenticeship
models, revamping the selection and training of teachers, measurement and evaluation
of schools, and putting in place forums to facilitate dialogue between employers and
educators.
Such approaches could increase Europe’s annual GDP growth by 0.24
percentage points.
Where Europe stands
Greater educational attainment serves as a shield against unemployment for young people.
Unemployment has hit all segments of young people since the economic downturn,
particularly those with lower educational attainment (Exhibit 32). Unemployment in
Europe among people aged 15 to 24 has historically been higher than in other developed
regions, but it has soared since the global economic crisis of 2008. The average
youth unemployment rate in OECD economies increased from 12.0 percent in 2007 to
16.3 percent in 2012.
In the EU, the rate jumped from 16.5 percent to 25.1 percent over the
same period.
This statistic may convey an overly optimistic view of the situation because it does not reflect
the number of young people who are so-called NEETs—not in employment, education, or
training. In 2011, Europe had 5.2 million unemployed young people and 7.5 million NEETs.
Factoring in underemployment—the percentage of part-time workers who want full-time
opportunities—paints an even more challenging picture. Over the past half-decade, the
share of young underemployed workers has increased from 7 percent to 9 percent.
The
biggest increase was in Southern Europe, where the number of young underemployed
nearly doubled from 11 percent to 21 percent. Underemployment is high, around
12 percent, even in the United Kingdom and Ireland and in the Nordics, two of the betterperforming regions in Europe on youth unemployment.
The importance of education is demonstrated by the fact that individuals with a tertiary
education have fared better than those who are less educated across Europe. Even regions
that suffered the brunt of recent economic stresses, such as Southern Europe and Central
and Eastern Europe, have experienced lower rates of youth unemployment among tertiaryeducated workers.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
51
.
Exhibit 32
Youth unemployment rates are extremely high in some parts of Europe, particularly among
individuals with low educational attainment
Youth unemployment by educational attainment, 2013
Unemployment rates by highest level of education attained, youths aged 15–24 years, %
Primary/lower secondary
Upper secondary/postsecondary
37
Tertiary
27
19
14
12
20
13
19
26
25
Nordics
United Kingdom and Ireland
36
23
13
12
Continental Europe
52
44
Baltics
35
40
Central and Eastern Europe
Southern Europe
SOURCE: Eurostat; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
4M
surplus in Europe's
tertiary-educated
workers in
2010, vs.
16M
shortage in 2020
By 2020, Europe is expected to have a surfeit of people with a secondary education but
a shortage of graduates with a tertiary education (Exhibit 33).58 Based on trends in GDP
and productivity growth, we estimate the supply-demand mismatch for tertiary-educated
workers will deteriorate from a surplus of four million in 2010 to a shortage of 16 million in
2020. Europe’s prime working-age population (conventionally defined as aged 15 to 64) is
projected to fall by 4 percent by 2030 as a result of lower fertility. Current rates of tertiaryeducation attainment are not sufficient to provide the boost to labour productivity needed to
sustain economic growth as populations age. Tertiary-education attainment among 30- to
34-year-olds varies from 22 percent in Italy to 53 percent in Ireland, and the variability in
educational test scores is high across the continent.
This suggests considerable scope for
some parts of Europe to catch up.
However, educational attainment can go only so far to protect people from the vagaries of
a difficult labour market. In Southern Europe and Central and Eastern Europe, graduates
with a tertiary education are experiencing greater rates of unemployment than workers
with only a primary education in Continental Europe and the United Kingdom and Ireland.
Educational attainment has to be twinned with the skills that today’s companies need. In a
recent McKinsey survey, employers specify a lack of skills as the most common reason for
entry-level vacancies.
This sentiment is particularly strong among employers from countries
with high youth unemployment rates. In Greece, 33 percent of employers could not find
We use the same projection methodology as in The world at work: Jobs, pay, and skills for 3.5 billion people,
McKinsey Global Institute, June 2012.
58
52
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
a candidate for an entry-level position because there was nobody with the right skills; in
contrast, the share of employers citing this issue in Sweden was 21 percent.59
Exhibit 33
By 2020, Europe will have too few individuals with a tertiary education to meet
labour-market demand
Labour supply-demand mismatch: Comparison of projected labour demand and supply
Million workers
Tertiary
Upper secondary/post-secondary
2010A
Primary/lower secondary
2020E
Gap
257
Million
workers
Gap
%1
47
+4
+9
170
+30
+17
34
40
+7
+16
Demand
Supply
216
42
140
Million
workers
%1
55
-16
+22
144
173
+29
+17
36
30
-6
-16
Demand
Supply
259
252
71
1 Gaps are percentage of demand for shortages, and percentage of supply for surpluses.
NOTE: Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
SOURCE: United Nations Population Division (2010 revision); International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis; ILO;
IHS; consensus estimates for GDP; national sources for the United States and France; McKinsey Global
Institute analysis
Europe’s high share of small businesses amplifies the importance of effective skills training.
Across the continent, 37 percent of employees work for businesses with fewer than 20
people. It is noteworthy that those European regions with higher shares of small businesses
also have higher levels of youth unemployment. This reflects the fact that most small
businesses do not possess the resources that large companies have to provide training
to smooth the gap between the skills that prospective employees have and the skills they
need. If we group businesses by their satisfaction with the skills of their employees and their
willingness to train new hires, business with fewer than 50 employees are overrepresented
in the least satisfied group, accounting for 61 percent of that group.
Conversely, small
businesses are most under-represented in the group that is proactive in improving the skills
of the workforce, making up 44 percent of companies of that group (despite accounting for
50 percent of all companies) compared with 32 percent of large businesses, which account
for 27 percent of all companies.
McKinsey surveyed 5,300 young people, 2,600 employers, and 700 education providers from eight EU
countries (France, Germany, Greece, Italy, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom). See Education
to employment: Getting Europe’s youth into work, McKinsey Center for Government, January 2014.
59
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
53
. What is driving these trends? Preparedness for work depends on five components of
effective education: childhood preparation, access to education, choice of study, provideremployer communication, and quality of education provided.
ƒƒ Childhood preparation. How well a child is prepared at school for the world of work
has an impact on the child’s employment prospects over the long term and is the
foundation of economy-wide skills and productivity. The evidence shows that additional
preschool early-childhood education has a dramatic effect on performance later in
life.60 The Progress in International Reading Literacy Study of fourth-graders shows that
reading achievement increases significantly with the length of early-childhood care.61
This effect is particularly pronounced for disadvantaged students. Even at the secondary
school level, performance in mathematics, science, and reading of 15-year-old students
measured by the Programme for International Student Assessment (PISA) improves
by the equivalent of almost one full year of formal schooling if a child has participated
in an early-childhood programme.62 Despite the proven benefits of preschool learning,
particularly among children under three years of age, participation in such programmes
in Europe is relatively low.
Participation has risen from 85.9 percent in 2001 to
92.9 percent in 2011, but still only 30 percent of children under three have received
any kind of education. Underpreparedness continues at later stages of education for
European children. In comparison with the OECD average, only countries in Continental
Europe outperform on mathematics, reading, and science measured by PISA.
Most
regions outperform the OECD average on science, but Southern Europe and Central
and Eastern Europe have gaps across the board.
30%
of Europeans not
enrolling in
postsecondary
education cited
costs
ƒƒ Access to education. Perceived and real barriers to access to education are still
present in Europe, especially at the tertiary level. While most European countries offer
many postsecondary programmes at little or no cost, students still identify affordability
as the main barrier to enrolling in these courses.
Of those young people who did not
enrol in postsecondary education, 30 percent claimed that they could not afford it.
While tuition costs are low across Europe, living expenses and the cost of materials
such as books can act as a barrier for students, particularly those from a low-income
background. Perhaps even more importantly, the opportunity costs of tertiary
education can be prohibitive for such students. Of the young people who embark on a
postsecondary education, one-quarter do not complete their programme because they
could not afford to forgo the earnings from working.
ƒƒ Choice of study.
What students choose to study has an impact on the skills mismatches
that are leading to skills shortages in the labour market. Highly educated people whose
skills are not in demand among employers can find themselves unemployed upon
graduation, and those who do find a job in a field that does not match their qualifications
tend to be less productive. In many cases, there is a lack of sufficient advice for students
about the academic disciplines or skills that are most in demand among employers.
Only 24 percent receive sufficient information on what fields to study.
This situation is
compounded by the fact that many educational systems require choosing subjects at an
early age, before students have sufficient information to know which subjects are likely
to be most useful. Broadly, across all levels of educational attainment, unemployment is
lowest in science, engineering, and health-care professions. Vocational students on the
Key data on early childhood education and care in Europe, 2014 edition, Eurydice and Eurostat report,
European Commission, 2004.
61
The Progress in International Reading Literacy Study is an international comparative study of the reading
literacy of young students.
It studies the reading achievement and reading behaviour and attitudes
of fourth-grade students in the United States and students in the equivalent of fourth grade in other
participating countries.
62
The Programme for International Student Assessment is a worldwide study by OECD in member and nonmember nations of the performance of 15-year-old students on mathematics, science, and reading. The first
study was in 2000, and it is repeated every three years.
60
54
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
whole have more success in finding employment, but only 44 percent of students who
would have preferred to study a vocational field in their postsecondary education do
so against 82 percent of students who preferred an academic discipline. Students see
strong benefits in vocational education, but only one-third think that such an education is
most valued by society.
Only
ƒƒ Provider-employer communication. Those who provide education and training
need to communicate more effectively and more often with employers so that students
emerge with the tools they need to find work. Perceptions diverge significantly.
In
a McKinsey Center for Government survey, 74 percent of educators said that they
were adequately preparing graduates for the workforce. However, only 35 percent
of employers and 38 percent of students thought that this was the case (Exhibit 34).
Employers need to tell educators what skills they need, and educators need to give their
graduates the tools that will enable them to meet these requirements.63 Even in Germany
and Sweden, which have some of the lowest rates of youth unemployment in Europe,
only 43 percent and 33 percent of employers, respectively, agree that new hires are
adequately prepared.
33%
of employers in
Sweden say new
hires are
adequately
prepared
Exhibit 34
Education providers typically have a more favourable view of the preparedness of graduates for work than
employers and young people do
Respondents who agree that graduates/new hires are adequately prepared
%
Employers1
Youth2
Education providers3
83
61
36 40
United
Kingdom
79
69
43 40
50
42
39
23 26
Germany
Spain
Greece
74
72
33
Italy
48
42
22
Sweden
80
73
27
33
France
74
33
35 38
Portugal
Europe
1 Overall, the entry-level employees we hired in the past year have been adequately prepared by their pre-hire education and/or training.
2 Overall, I think I was adequately prepared for an entry-level position in my chosen career field.
3 Overall, graduates from my institution are adequately prepared for entry-level positions in their chosen field of study.
SOURCE: Education to employment: Getting Europe’s youth into work, McKinsey Center for Government, January 2014; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
ƒƒ Quality of education. The overall quality of education affects all four other components,
and European countries tend to lag behind other developed economies in this respect.
The 2013 Survey of Adult Skills by the OECD revealed that only the working-age
populations in the Nordic region and the Netherlands match the OECD average in
numeracy, problem solving, and literacy.
Particular weaknesses persist in Southern
Europe, Ireland, and Poland, which underperform on all three. In the case of digital
literacy, Europe performs well with the exception of Central and Eastern Europe, where
Education to employment: Getting Europe’s youth into work, McKinsey Center for Government,
January 2014.
63
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
55
. a survey by the ECDL Foundation showed a lower share of digitally literate respondents
than the survey average.64
Initiatives to change the game
The initiatives on which we have focused are those that can deliver change within the next
ten years that immediately help to address high youth unemployment rates and also set
the foundation for future productivity growth by addressing gaps in education quality. If
Europe improves the education of its workforce on the five dimensions we have discussed,
the region’s annual GDP growth could increase by 0.24 percentage points. Of this, around
0.09 percent would come from reaching Europe 2020 targets for the share of tertiary
graduates.65 A reduction of half of the gap with best practice on the mismatch between
educational attainment and occupations—known as a vertical mismatch—would drive
an additional 0.07 percent of GDP, reflecting productivity gains.66 The final 0.07 percent
could be realised by reducing the share of NEETs from the current level of 12.2 percent to
8.9 percent (an aggregate of national targets).67 Lowering the share of NEETs would raise
output from the incremental earnings, taxes, and social contributions provided by the newly
employed members of the workforce.
Our analysis suggests the following priorities:
ƒƒ Establish dedicated schemes for matching youth to employment, and increase
transparency about the labour market and career choices. For the many young
people looking for work in Europe today, long-term, fundamental reform of education-toemployment systems will take too long to come to fruition.
However, there are examples
within Europe of approaches that can help young people to adjust to the demands of
the labour market in the relative short term. Since 2013, Finland’s Youth Guarantee
has guaranteed all people under 25 years of age and all graduates under 30 years of
age access to a job, training, or education within three months of declaring themselves
unemployed. Public employment services work with participants on three steps: creating
a personal development plan; carrying out a needs assessment; and identifying and
undertaking whichever of the three options—job, training, or education—is deemed
most appropriate.
Organised as a public-private partnership, the programme has
ensured that all stakeholders are involved in a national working group. The success of
this programme proves that well-crafted solutions can be effective even in the very short
term. Of the 37,023 unemployed young people identified, 93 percent created job-seeking
plans, and 72 percent found work or enrolled in training.
The programme has also
proved cost-effective. Total annual costs for the scheme are approximately €114 million,
against an estimated overall cost to society of youth unemployment of €300 million.
Students cannot make optimal career choices without transparency about the labour
market. A central repository of data on labour-market and education outcomes
organised by youth employment integrators would achieve this aim.
The United Kingdom
already provides a successful model of such a system. The National Careers Service
was launched in the United Kingdom in 2011 as a three-channel delivery system to
Digital literacy report—2009, ECDL Foundation, 2009. The ECDL (European Computer Driving Licence)
Foundation survey of 8,000 people in 15 countries determined their self-perceived digital literacy and
confidence level with different IT tasks, and posed actual questions that test IT skill level.
65
The GDP impact is based on the productivity elasticity of tertiary-education attainment and the correlation
between total factor productivity growth and GDP growth.
See Dawn Holland et al., The relationship between
graduates and economic growth across countries, Bank for International Settlements research paper number
110, August 2013.
66
The output elasticity of the short-run, country-specific reduction in vertical mismatch comes from António
Morgado et al., Measuring labour mismatch in Europe, CEFAGE-UE working paper number 2014/13, Center
for Advanced Studies in Management and Economics, Universidade de Évora, 2014.
67
The output impact is based on annual country-specific resource costs calculated in Massimiliano Mascherini
et al., NEETs: Young people not in employment, education or training: Characteristics, costs and policy
responses in Europe, Eurofound, October 2012.
64
56
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. improve the effectiveness of the labour market by giving people information about the
labour market, provide tools to job seekers to assess their preparedness for work, and
develop an action plan. The website had in excess of seven million visitors in its first year
of operation, and the UK government reported that of more than 10,000 people entering
work or learning every month, more than half credited the programme.
70%
of Swiss youth
complete
apprenticeship
ƒƒ Develop a flexible dual-apprenticeship model. Another useful approach would be to
put in place a flexible apprenticeship system to boost the credibility of vocational tracks
and, at the same time, ensure that students acquire the skills that employers value.
Apprenticeship programmes are a powerful tool for addressing youth unemployment
(Exhibit 35). Countries with vocational education training programmes, including
Germany and Austria, weathered the recent downturn relatively well with a youth
unemployment rate of approximately 9 percent in 2010.
Ten other comparable countries
in Western Europe had an average youth unemployment rate of 25 percent in that year.
Switzerland, with its low youth unemployment rate, can provide a model for a strong
apprenticeship programme. Not only is the apprenticeship programme an integral part of
the educational system—70 percent of Swiss youth complete such programmes—but it
also provides rigorous qualifications through more than 400 federal vocational exams. It
also provides flexibility by enabling students to switch between vocational education and
academic pathways.
The Swiss Confederation, cantons, and professional organisations
work together to develop training standards and ensure that students have sufficient
apprenticeship opportunities.
Exhibit 35
Apprenticeship systems are a powerful way to address youth unemployment in Europe
Youth (ages 15–24) unemployment and enrolment in apprenticeship programmes, 2010
%
Nordics
Continental
Europe
United
Kingdom
and Ireland
Southern
Europe
Baltics
Central
and Eastern
Europe
Other
Youth unemployment rate
45
Spain
40
35
Estonia
Ireland
30
25
Poland
20
Belgium
15
Hungary
France
Finland
Luxembourg
Israel
10
Czech Republic
Iceland
Norway
Denmark
Austria
Netherlands
Germany
5
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
Enrolment in apprenticeship programmes1
1 Percentage of age cohort; six countries with zero enrolment not shown.
SOURCE: OECD; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
57
. ƒƒ Revamp the selection and training process for teachers. It will be difficult for Europe
to develop a best-in-class education system without good teachers. The top-performing
educational systems in Europe—in Finland, England, and the Netherlands—make
recruiting the best talent to the teaching profession a top priority. England has raised
starting conditions for teachers through the Training and Development Agency for
Schools, a group that uses lessons from marketing in the private sector to develop
dynamic recruitment strategies that adapt their message to better match top motivating
factors.
The Netherlands has attracted higher-quality candidates by shortening the time
it takes to reach the top of the salary schedule from 26 years to 18 years, and by raising
the starting salary for teachers in line with the private sector (although this move has
been curtailed by temporary salary freezes since 2010). In addition to attracting better
candidates, school systems must make sure that they make the right hiring decisions
since the effects of their choices can persist in the system for decades. Finland ensures
that it brings in the best teachers through an extensive selection process that includes
a multiple-choice national screening test, group work to assess communication and
interpersonal skills, and interviews to see whether applicants are inspired to teach.
The country also sets strict teaching qualifications that require all teachers, including
kindergarten and preschool teachers, to hold a master’s degree.68
ƒƒ Proactively measure school performance on a defined set of metrics and
intervene with targeted programmes where outcome gaps are identified.
Diagnosing and reversing underperformance as quickly as possible requires
comprehensive measurement.
The best school systems in Europe use a two-pronged
monitoring approach of examination and independent school review, complemented
by specialised one-on-one instruction. England has an independent inspectorate that
is directly accountable to Parliament, which reviews schools on process and outcome
indicators. Failure to improve gives the local authorities the right to replace school
leadership.
The separation between driving and measuring outcomes reduces conflict of
interest and boosts the objectivity of assessment. Once gaps in students’ achievement
have been identified through regular and comparable examination, they should be
addressed proactively through individually tailored instruction. In this vein, Finland
has de-stigmatised special education by ensuring that a high proportion (28 percent)
of students make use of some form of educational support, and also by occasionally
sending the best students to participate in special education sessions.69
ƒƒ Stimulate dialogue between employers and educational providers.
Fostering
communication between employers and providers can help to ensure that students
are not the victims of poor communication between the two sides. Such forums could
enable the establishment of agreed educational standards that meet the needs of
employers, and ensure that curricula can be carried out by providers. Existing panEuropean mechanisms such as the Bologna and Copenhagen processes offer an
effective platform through which this initiative can be executed.
These processes
involve a formal set of meetings and agreements among European countries aimed
at harmonising standards of higher education and vocational education, respectively.
Incorporating the proposed forums into these established processes would be an
effective way to get the forums up and running. Additional metrics on the frequency and
effectiveness of this communication, tracked by each country and reported through
these platforms, would help to assess the continent’s progress and adjust course
if necessary.
Michela Braga, Daniele Checchi, and Elena Meschi, Institutional reforms and educational attainment in
Europe: A long run perspective, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) discussion paper number 6190,
December 2011.
69
How the world’s best-performing school systems come out on top, McKinsey on Society survey, September
2007; Special education 2013: Share of students having received special support diminished, Statistics
Finland, June 2014.
68
58
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
3. PRODUCTIVE INFRASTRUCTURE INVESTMENT
Infrastructure is the connective tissue of an economy, and there is strong evidence linking
productive infrastructure spending and economic growth.70 Without adequate spending,
countries whose infrastructure is inadequate risk falling further behind and leading countries
can quickly slip down the rankings. We estimate that European investment in transport,
power, water, and telecoms infrastructure over the past ten years has been between
0.3 percent and 0.9 percent of GDP lower than needed to support the growth rates to which
Europeans aspire. Net public investment has declined since the crisis and turned negative in
several economies including Germany.
However, simply increasing investment in infrastructure is not enough—particularly during a
time of fiscal constraint.
Spending on infrastructure needs to be as productive as possible.
Previous MGI research found that as much as 40 percent could be saved on countries’
infrastructure bills if they applied global best practice on project selection, delivery, asset
management, governance, and finance.71 Even neighbouring European countries score
very differently on these dimensions, suggesting ample opportunity to learn from each
other. Europe should consider conducting a comprehensive infrastructure productivity
assessment, take an integrated view of project selection, streamline the delivery of projects,
improve the utilisation of existing infrastructure through pricing and the use of technology,
and explore funding options outside general taxation. Stepping up European annual
infrastructure delivery by the equivalent of 0.9 percent of GDP additional spending could
boost Europe’s annual GDP growth by 0.14 percentage points, assuming an economic rate
of return on additional infrastructure stock of 20 percent and ignoring demand-side effects.
Only
4
Baltic and Central
and Eastern
European countries
make world top 40
on infrastructure
quality
Where Europe stands
The quality of Europe’s infrastructure quality compares well overall with that of other
developed economies, according to the WEF’s index of infrastructure quality.72 Across all
types of infrastructure, Europe performs in line with Canada and the United States.
Looking
at regions within Europe, Continental Europe performs comparably with Japan despite
that country’s high levels of investment over recent decades. However, although European
countries are disproportionately represented in the top 20 of the WEF index, some countries
have an opportunity to rise up the rankings. The Baltics and Central and Eastern Europe
lag well behind other European regions.
Of the 11 countries in those two regions, only
four—the Czech Republic, Estonia, Latvia, and Slovenia—make the top 40 in the world on
infrastructure quality. While the quality of telecoms and water infrastructure in those regions
is in line with the rest of Europe, transport infrastructure such as roads, rail, and ports has
some way to catch up.
In general, infrastructure quality has a strong positive correlation with per capita income
(and the causation goes both ways). Nevertheless, some countries can outperform given
their level of income while others fail to reach the level of infrastructure quality expected
based on the stage of their economic development.
Within Southern Europe, for instance,
Portugal outperforms Greece, and Spain outperforms Italy—despite similar levels of income
(Exhibit 36). Even regions with generally higher infrastructure quality such as Continental
Europe show significant variation. Switzerland has the highest-quality infrastructure in
Continental Europe with a WEF score of 6.6, compared with a score of 5.8 in Belgium.
Among the Nordics, Norway’s infrastructure quality overall is lower than one might expect
for such a high-income country, largely due to the country’s underperforming transport
infrastructure, particularly roads.
World economic outlook: Legacies, clouds, uncertainties, IMF, October 2014.
Infrastructure productivity: How to save $1 trillion a year, McKinsey Global Institute and the McKinsey
Infrastructure Practice, January 2013.
72
Global competitiveness report 2014–2015, World Economic Forum, September 2014.
70
71
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
59
.
Exhibit 36
The quality of infrastructure varies widely at each income level
Nordics
Continental Europe
United Kingdom
and Ireland
Southern Europe
Baltics
Central and
Eastern Europe
Infrastructure quality, 2014
WEF score
7.0
Switzerland
6.5
Finland
Spain
5.5
5.0
Hungary
Czech
Estonia
Republic
Latvia
Croatia
Lithuania
Malta
4.5
4.0
Poland
Austria
Germany
France
Portugal
6.0
Luxembourg
Denmark
Belgium Sweden
Cyprus United
Kingdom
Slovenia
Greece
Netherlands
Norway
Ireland
Italy
Slovakia
Romania
Bulgaria
3.5
8.4
8.6
8.8
9.0
9.2
9.4
9.6
9.8
10.0
10.2
10.4
10.6
10.8
11.0
11.2
11.4
Income, 2012
Log GDP per capita, purchasing power parity
SOURCE: WEF; Eurostat; World Bank; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
The high overall quality of Europe’s infrastructure masks a worrying trend of considerable
underinvestment. Left unaddressed, this would be likely to constrain the growth potential
of many of the region’s economies. We base our analysis of investment needs on a crosscountry methodology that mostly reflects economic growth but also takes into account
infrastructure stock and depreciation.73 While we recognise that the investment needs of
any specific country depend on a more complex set of conditions including, for example,
geography, demographics, efficiency of spending, or economic development priorities, this
top-down methodology has proven effective in providing an indication of spending gaps
or overinvestment.
Europe would
require
infrastructure
spending of
3.5%
of GDP per year
We find that, with the exception of Central and Eastern Europe, and Southern Europe,
the continent did not spend a sufficient percentage of GDP on infrastructure in the 2000s
(Exhibit 37). Between 2002 and 2011, Europe spent an average 2.6 percent of GDP per
year, a level that would have been appropriate for an economy growing at 1.2 percent per
annum in real terms.
This level of infrastructure spending is clearly insufficient to support
Europe’s aspirations for future growth. The gap between required spending, based on
an IHS forecast of 1.7 percent annual GDP growth in the Europe-30 to 2030, and actual
spending was 0.3 percent of GDP in 2011. If Europe were to achieve a higher growth rate of
73
60
For details, see Infrastructure productivity: How to save $1 trillion a year, McKinsey Global Institute and the
McKinsey Infrastructure Practice, January 2013.
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. 2.5 percent per annum through the implementation of the growth drivers discussed in this
report, this gap would widen further to 0.9 percent. To support higher future growth rates,
Europe would require infrastructure spending of 3.5 percent of GDP per year.
Exhibit 37
In most of Europe, infrastructure spending has fallen below the levels required to keep pace with
expected GDP growth
Historical aggregate infrastructure spending
% of GDP
Continental
Europe
Southern Europe
Central and
Eastern Europe
United Kingdom
and Ireland
Nordics
Europe-30
Expected future spending requirement vs.
historical spending
% of GDP, regionally weighted by GDP
Historical average, 2002–11
Projected need (1.7% p.a. real GDP growth to 2030)
Projected need (2.5% p.a. real GDP growth scenario)
4.5
Europe-30
2.6
2.9
3.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
United Kingdom
and Ireland
2.5
Nordics
2.0
Continental
Europe
3.7
Central and
Eastern Europe
1.5
2002 03
04
05
06
07
08
09
10 2011
Southern Europe
3.7
2.3
3.4
2.3
3.0
2.3
2.8
3.1
2.6
NOTE: IHS forecast of 1.7% real GDP growth per annum for the Europe-30 to 2030; 2.5% figure based on assumption of implementing growth drivers.
SOURCE: Eurostat; World Bank; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Beyond the general shortfall of spending levels in much of the continent, we discern
variation in patterns of infrastructure investment within Europe.
We have grouped the
economies into a number of archetypes determined by a country’s infrastructure quality
relative to its per capita GDP, as well as its average annual infrastructure investment relative
to its need (Exhibit 38).74 Three countries—Austria, the Czech Republic, and Denmark—fall
into a zone where spending and quality have been about as expected given the countries’
degree of development and historical speed of growth. Eight countries—including Poland,
Sweden, and the United Kingdom—have infrastructure that is below the expected quality
and have not invested sufficiently to make up the gap. This suggests that these countries
should assess carefully whether they need to take measures to avoid falling behind.
Four
countries—Belgium, Finland, France, and Germany—have infrastructure that exceeds the
quality expected for their per capita income but have recently invested less than expected.
This may put their advantageous position at risk in future years. Another four countries—
Hungary, Portugal, Spain, and Switzerland—have above-average infrastructure quality for
With respect to the latter dimension, we compare each country’s average spending in 2002 to 2011 with its
historical GDP-growth rate in the same period, rather than with a projected future growth rate.
74
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
61
. their income levels and high levels of infrastructure investment for their growth rates. Finally,
Greece and Italy combine high recent infrastructure spending with quality that lags behind
the level that would be expected given their incomes. This raises questions about why their
high spending has not translated into improving infrastructure quality.
Exhibit 38
MGI has analysed countries by their infrastructure spending characteristics
Nordics
Continental Europe
United Kingdom
and Ireland
Southern Europe
Baltics
Central and
Eastern Europe
Infrastructure quality gap, 2014
Delta between actual WEF index and predicted value1
1.2
Portugal
1.0
â–ª Quality exceeds
wealth-expected levels
â–ª Recently investing
below levels expected
to support growth
0.8
â–ª Quality exceeds
Finland
0.6
France
Belgium
Czech
Republic
wealth-expected levels
â–ª Recently investing
below levels expected
to support growth
Hungary
Denmark
â–ª Quality lags behind
Romania
wealth-expected levels
â–ª Recently investing
Slovakia
Poland
Ireland
-0.8
above levels needed
to support growth
Greece
Bulgaria
-0.6
â–ª Recently investing
United Kingdom
-0.2 Sweden
-0.4
Austria
Germany
0
â–ª Quality lags behind
Switzerland
0.4
0.2
wealth-expected levels
Spain
above levels needed
to support growth
Italy
-1.0
-1.2
Norway
-1.4
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4 -0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.6
1.8
Spending gap, 2002–11
Delta between average spend (public and private)
and estimated need in the same period2,3
1 Calculated as difference between actual WEF index and predicted value given per capita GDP on a purchasing power parity basis.
2 Spending requirement to maintain average infrastructure stock of 70 percent of GDP given 2.5 percent per annum depreciation and GDP growth 2002–11.
3 Several countries excluded from analysis due to incomplete data.
SOURCE: WEF; Eurostat; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Differences in the quality of infrastructure within Europe are caused by different practices
and conditions that affect all stages of a typical project development life cycle. Productive
infrastructure investments are typically underpinned by fact-based project selection,
streamlined delivery, effective management and utilisation of existing infrastructure, strong
governance and capabilities, and a robust funding and finance framework.
It is evident that high spending alone does not guarantee good infrastructure.
Where
spending doesn’t lead to quality infrastructure, there tend to be shortcomings in the
efficiency of procurement and delivery. Even among countries at a similar stage of economic
development, differences in the cost of building infrastructure can be large (Exhibit 39). For
example, the cost of building a road in the United Kingdom is about €10 million per kilometre
62
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. but in Germany is around 20 percent less. On the cost of materials, the United Kingdom
consistently pays less than either France or Germany. In most advanced economies, labour
productivity in the construction industry has stagnated or even fallen over the past two
decades. There are many circumstantial explanations for such differences, but overall there
is a large opportunity to optimise.
Exhibit 39
Vast infrastructure cost differences within Europe demonstrate a significant opportunity to
learn from best practice
Cost
benchmark
Relative cost of
road building
Unit cost
€ million per kilometre
Material costs
United Kingdom
9.8
8.4
-21%
7.7
France
Germany
€ per tonne (€ per m3 concrete)
Steel rebar—
high yield
Structural
steel
759
Ordinary
cement
817
1,230
Concrete
(20N/mm)
Aggregate—
all grades
93
105
1,314
1,425
1,101
65
202
1,121
58
140
190
n/a
12
19
99
166
30
System productivity
Productivity changes, 1992–2009
Growth in construction labour
productivity
%
Productivity, 2012
GDP per hour worked
(all labour groups)
€
45.2
26.0
36.9
44.3
Building labour costs
(skilled labour)
€ per hour
16.9
42
12.2
19.2
16
6
2.3
-9.0
NOTE: Not to scale.
SOURCE: Infrastructure UK, 2010; Gardiner and Theobald, 2011; OECD; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
The five groups of countries that we have identified share characteristics that lead to lower
or higher project delivery costs.
In 2012, on average, the group comprising Italy and Greece
spent a median of 43 person-days per process in procurement compared with roughly
17 days for the central group of Austria, the Czech Republic, and Denmark. There is also
significant variation in the composition of the construction sector. Less than 5 percent of
construction employees in Italy and Greece work in firms with 250 or more employees; this
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
63
.
share in the central group was 15 percent. While consolidated construction sectors are not
uniformly associated with productive and high-quality infrastructure spending, a high degree
of fragmentation in the sector is likely to obstruct economies of scale and to make it more
difficult to coordinate complex projects, leading to lower productivity.75
There is scope to
increase the
productivity of
capital investment
by up to
40%
Effective delivery systems are essential. However, in addition, countries need to be able
to obtain adequate funding for projects, especially as the financial sector continues to
adapt to a post-crisis regulatory environment. Countries in all five groups face further fiscal
retrenchment by their public sectors, and in this difficult climate it will be easier for some to
access finance than others.
The countries that have been systematically spending more
in the past than expected to support growth could arguably reduce their spending in this
area and focus their scarce fiscal capacity on more pressing priorities. The situation is more
severe for those countries that have invested substantially but not achieved high-quality
infrastructure. Their simultaneous challenge is to retrench on spending while designing a
framework for infrastructure provision that ensures that the spending that is left is more
productive.
Countries that have underinvested could be putting their competitiveness
and growth potential at risk. For all countries, fiscal austerity and attempted publicsector deleveraging points to a need for governments to design a policy and governance
framework that attracts additional private capital to help meet the infrastructure funding gap.
Initiatives to change the game
For Europe to deliver the societal and growth aspiration of its citizens would require
an annual growth rate in excess of 2 percent, as we have discussed. A growth rate of
2.5 percent per annum to 2025 would require infrastructure spending to rise to 3.5 percent
of GDP, an increase of 0.9 percent of GDP over current levels.
Such an increase would
boost GDP growth by 0.14 percent annually. This assumes an economic rate of return
on additional infrastructure stock of 20 percent. The impact of infrastructure investment
may be greater due to short-term stimulus effects and may be enhanced by productivity
improvements that stretch the value of each euro spent at all stages of project delivery.
There is scope to increase the productivity of capital investment by up to 40 percent.76
Governments may choose to use those savings elsewhere rather than on additional
infrastructure projects, and therefore we do not quantify this effect.
Our analysis suggests
that the following measures would help Europe to meet its infrastructure imperative:
ƒƒ Increase spending in countries currently underinvesting, and increase
productivity of spend where overinvestment occurred. Our top-down methodology
offers a first approximation of the gap between European infrastructure spending and
the required level to support aspirational growth. All European countries could benefit
from a detailed analysis of their current infrastructure situation to determine appropriate
spending levels for the next ten years.
Many countries in the region, particularly those
we have characterised as underinvesting, will likely find that they need to increase
investment in infrastructure. Through such analysis, countries identified as having
overspent should turn their attention to better prioritising projects and developing
more efficient delivery systems. Although there are fiscal constraints in many European
countries, in many respects this is a propitious moment to invest in infrastructure.
Most European countries have historically low borrowing costs, and many have a
long-overdue need for upgrades and improvements in transport infrastructure due to
high traffic volumes.
Even Germany, which has high-quality transport infrastructure, is
experiencing heavy congestion on 20 percent of its road network.77
In practice, these challenges can also be addressed through collaborative partnerships. See R. Beach, M.
Webster, and K.
M. Campbell, “An evaluation of partnership development in the construction industry”,
International Journal of Project Management, volume 23, issue 8, November 2005.
76
Infrastructure productivity: How to save $1 trillion a year, McKinsey Global Institute and the McKinsey
Infrastructure Practice, January 2013.
77
Ibid.
75
64
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
ƒƒ Explore funding options outside the general tax budget. Fiscal constraints faced
by many European countries require them to seek sources of funding outside of general
taxation. Charging user fees for using infrastructure, as in congestion pricing on roads,
can help pay for a project and optimise its use. Once user charges are in place, the
private sector could be brought in to increase competition and as a source of additional
finance.
Property-value capture, in which the public sector acquires land surrounding
a project and then sells it at a profit when the project is completed, offers another
promising avenue.78 Barcelona’s experience with property-value capture demonstrates
its effectiveness. In 2001, the city re-designated four million square metres of land from
industrial use for use by the services sector. This re-designation increased the value of
the land, thereby giving local government increased leverage with private developers to
help transform the area while also capturing value for the public.
The city exchanged a
planning permit for 30 percent of land rights and a development fee of €80 per square
metre of the land developed. This arrangement enabled the city to finance the project
despite fiscal constraints at the national level. All the value captured was fed into the
publicly owned 22@BCN company, which then allocated funds across social housing,
green spaces, and advanced infrastructure such as transport, ICT networks, and heating
and cooling systems.
This reinvestment approach created a virtuous cycle of value. The
project’s success partly reflected up-front planning that ensured that the infrastructure
built was attractive to businesses, including a central location and good transport links.
The city has built 4,000 affordable housing units on the site and developed 114,000
square metres of green space and 145,000 square metres of public facilities, as well
as installing fibre-optic cables, Wi-Fi networks, and modern waste-collection systems.
The return to the developers is an estimated 6 to 7 percent per year, and the public
value of the development is estimated at more than €1 billion for an initial outlay of only
€180 million.79
ƒƒ Conduct comprehensive infrastructure productivity assessments. Countries can
vary hugely on the money they spend on comparable infrastructure projects—even
countries that have similar per capita incomes such as France, Germany, and the United
Kingdom.
A McKinsey diagnostic of infrastructure productivity in two neighbouring
European countries reveals not only that both countries have some way to go before
achieving global leading practice but also that they can learn and improve significantly
by looking at other countries in the region (Exhibit 40). A granular 360-degree diagnostic
can show policy makers where the major gaps are that need rectifying, helping to boost
the productivity of government infrastructure spending.
€3.4B
annual savings in
UK infrastructure
cost review
ƒƒ Take an integrated view of project selection. One of the most powerful ways to
reduce the overall cost of infrastructure is to avoid investing in projects that neither
address clearly defined needs nor deliver sufficient benefits.
The United Kingdom has
made impressive progress in improving its selection of infrastructure projects. In 2010,
Infrastructure UK, a newly established entity within HM Treasury, published a National
Infrastructure Plan that outlined priorities for allocating public spending in this area
in a bid to increase transparency. It established an annual infrastructure cost review
to encourage efficiency.
As a result of this framework, the government prioritised 40
projects out of a pipeline of around 250 that were deemed to encourage economic
growth, enable a transition to a low-carbon economy, and be capable of attracting
investment from the private sector. Across roads, rail, water, energy, and flood defences,
in 2014 the United Kingdom achieved annual cost savings of £3.4 billion, 15 percent of a
baseline of £22.3 billion.80
George E. Peterson, Unlocking land values to finance urban infrastructure, World Bank, 2009.
Joe Huxley, Value capture finance: Making urban development pay its way, Urban Land Institute, 2009.
80
Infrastructure cost review, Infrastructure UK, July 2014.
78
79
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
65
.
Exhibit 40
An infrastructure diagnostic can enable more efficient spending
Country A
Robust funding and finance framework
Country B
Fact-based project selection
Infrastructure strategy linked to socioeconomic objectives
Effective approach to public-private partnerships
Suitable regulation, pricing, and
value capture investment
Strong framework for long-term public funding
Clear strategy for market competition
and ownership
Suitable conditions for private
infrastructure finance
Master planning coordinated across asset classes/
jurisdictions
Prioritised optimisation of infrastructure before
new build
Fact-based and consistent project evaluation
System-wide portfolio prioritisation
Effective construction and supply market
Strong value-assurance process
Sufficient financial capacity
Attractive overall investment climate
Adequate owner team
Concept, design, and engineering
optimisation
Robust infrastructure data
Strong capabilities
Seamless permitting and land acquisition
Strong governance and collaboration
Robust institutions and processes for
combatting corruption
Strong infrastructure governance
and capabilities
Effective procurement, tendering,
and contracting
Advanced procurement with synergies
captured across projects
Rigorous execution and contract management
Total cost of ownership-oriented maintenance
Increased asset utilisation and loss reduction
Well-planned commissioning and ramp-up
Well-defined approach to projects in distress
Demand managed
Making the most of existing infrastructure
Streamlined delivery
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute analysis
ƒƒ Streamline delivery of infrastructure projects. Cost and time overruns can be
avoided with smart planning. Tight management of contractors, cost-focused
contracts, and the use of advanced construction techniques such as prefabrication
can lead to potential savings of up to 15 percent.81 Sweden’s national transportation
agency was able to use lean-manufacturing techniques and ways of optimising capital
spending that helped to rationalise the costs of implementing infrastructure projects.
Clearly defined ownership, flexible timelines, active management of planning reserves,
optimised requirement and exemption management, and efficient production have led to
reduction of both cost and timelines for almost all ongoing megaprojects. One example
is the North Link, a 9.3 billion Swedish kroner road tunnel in Stockholm.
The tunnel
opened in December 2014, a full year before schedule, and 2.6 billion Swedish kroner,
or 22 percent, under budget. Applying similar approaches elsewhere led to a further
cost reduction of around 20 percent that freed up funds for investment in road and
rail projects.
81
66
Infrastructure productivity: How to save $1 trillion a year, McKinsey Global Institute and the McKinsey
Infrastructure Practice, January 2013.
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
ƒƒ Improve utilisation of existing infrastructure through pricing and technology use.
Rather than invest in costly new projects, governments can often improve the quality
of infrastructure and meet demand more cost-effectively by upgrading existing assets.
Finland has done a great deal to improve use of existing infrastructure and reduce
maintenance costs by deploying intelligent transport systems. Its aim is to use electronic
operating models to improve the efficiency of transporting goods, targeting a 10 percent
improvement in the productivity of the logistics sector. Finland is also developing a smart
transport corridor across different modes of transport and using intelligent systems,
including an information service on traffic incidents, to facilitate travel between Finland
and Russia. These efforts have already yielded significant efficiency improvements.82
For example, systems offering weather information on roads and more efficient use of
maintenance workers have saved an average of 23 minutes on each de-icing job.
In the
capital, Helsinki, the installation of transit signal priority systems reduced the average
journey time by 11 percent. Such improvements not only boost infrastructure productivity
but are also cost-effective: benefit-to-cost ratios from improved traffic conditions range
between 2 to 1 and 5 to 1. Although Finland’s implementation of these systems is not
complete, they can serve as a model for other countries with heavy road use.
“Smoother passenger traffic across the Finnish-Russian border”, press release, VTT Technical Research
Centre of Finland, April 15, 2014.
82
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
67
.
4. REDUCED ENERGY BURDEN
Energy—whether petroleum fuels, electricity, or the calories embodied in food—is one
of the base ingredients of all economic activity.83 A divergence in energy prices with the
United States in recent years has risked putting Europe at a competitive disadvantage
in energy-intensive industries; the chemicals industry has already shifted a significant
volume of investment abroad. At the same time, such industries generate a relatively small
share of European output and can often be traded only regionally, mitigating global cost
pressure. Higher energy prices may even aid a shift towards higher-value-added industries
that are less energy-intensive.
Nevertheless—and despite the sharp fall in energy prices in
late 2014—reducing Europe’s energy burden remains an important long-term economic
issue. New sources of domestic supply should be explored, but the potential over the next
ten years appears limited.
Given this context, there is a broad imperative to use energy more productively—through
efforts to boost efficiency, structural change in the composition of economies, and
technological innovation.84 On this score, best practice already exists in Europe. Denmark,
for instance, has successfully fostered energy efficiency through a concrete and coherent
regulatory framework of energy-intensity standards.
Governments can also play an
important role in accelerating progress towards a single European energy market and laying
the foundation for long-term energy supply with a pan-European framework for new energy
sources including renewables and, provided environmental concerns can be addressed,
unconventional hydrocarbons. Progress on energy productivity and the single market alone
could result in an annual uptick in GDP growth of 0.13 percent.
70%
rise in household
post-tax electricity
prices 2004–13
Where Europe stands
Between 2004 and 2013, European post-tax electricity prices for industry approximately
doubled, while those for households rose by about 70 percent. In the same period,
European natural gas prices increased by 160 percent.
This was a far greater increase than
that observed in the United States, where large-scale exploitation of shale gas has helped
to curtail price pressures (Exhibit 41).85 Both natural gas and electricity prices in the United
States are now about half of European prices.
The rising prices in Europe put pressure on the competitiveness of energy-intensive
industries. Executives at the chemical giant BASF, for example, were widely cited in the
media in 2014 saying that high electricity and feedstock prices were important factors
behind the company’s decision to focus more of its €20 billion capital expenditure budget on
Asia and the United States over the next five years, cutting investment in Europe from twothirds of its budget to just under half.86 Almost three times as many European households
worry about rising energy prices as the number concerned about keeping up with mortgage
or rent payments. This has resulted in 31 percent of respondents in 2014 planning energyefficiency changes compared with only 4 percent in 2012.87
Robert U.
Ayres and Benjamin Warr, “Accounting for growth: The role of physical work”, Structural Change
and Economic Dynamics, volume 16, issue 2, June 2005.
84
For example, see Better growth, better climate: The new climate economy synthesis report, Global
Commission on the Economy and Climate, September 2014, and Georg Zachmann and Valeria Cipollone,
“Energy competitiveness”, in Manufacturing Europe’s future, Reinhilde Veugelers, ed., Bruegel Blueprint
Series, volume XXI, 2013.
85
Despite some infrastructural bottlenecks and regulatory obstacles, crude oil and refined products have
traded at generally similar price points in the United States and Europe due to the integrated global nature of
these markets.
86
Chris Bryant, “BASF to focus investments outside Europe”, The Financial Times, February 25, 2014.
87
European home report 2014, Kingfisher, August 2014.
83
68
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. Exhibit 41
European gas and electricity prices have diverged from those in the United States,
putting pressure on industry and households
US industry1
US households2
Europe industry1
Europe households2
Industry natural gas prices and US shale production
14
Natural gas
prices
$ per million
BTU
12
10
8
-49
6
4
2
0
2004
US dry shale
gas production
Billion cubic feet
per day
05
06
07
08
09
3
3
4
5
7
10
2004
05
06
07
08
09
10
15
11
22
12
13
28
31
10
11
12
13
10
11
12
2014
36
2014
2013
Household and industry electricity prices after tax
$ per kilowatt-hour
0.30
0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0
2004
05
Average US
61
prices as % of
European prices
06
07
08
09
49
44
1 US gas prices are Henry Hub; Europe gas prices are German border.
2 Weighted average of Europe-30 excluding Cyprus, Malta, and Norway in natural gas price due to data availability.
SOURCE: German Federal Office for Economic Affairs and Export Control; Bloomberg; FACTS; US Energy Information
Administration; Enerdata; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Energy supply
The gas and power price differential between Europe and the United States partly reflects a
regional supply-demand mismatch that has developed in recent years.88 Therefore, one way
to reduce the economic burden of high energy costs would be through increased supply
from domestic production or imports. However, expanding domestic energy production
Howard Rogers, The impact of a globalising market on future European gas supply and pricing: The
importance of Asian demand and North American supply, Oxford Institute for Energy Studies, January 2012.
88
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
69
. on a large enough scale to produce meaningful reductions in energy prices appears
very difficult.
United
States drilled
~14X
as many shale
wells as Europe in
2002
Take shale gas, for example. Although shale resources are abundant in Europe, McKinsey
experts expect domestically produced shale gas to meet only a small percentage of
European gas demand by 2030—and at a higher price than in the United States. This
reflects a combination of difficult geology, stringent regulations, an underdeveloped pipeline
infrastructure, public opposition, and a rudimentary support-services sector. Even if Europe
decided to intensify shale gas production, its current level of activity implies a very long
ramp-up period.
By 2003, years before the “shale revolution” became a topic of household
conversation, the United States had already drilled 127 shale wells per 1,000 square
kilometres—approximately 14 times as many as Europe had in 2012 (Exhibit 42). What’s
more, rather than growing at a rapid rate, shale exploration since 2011 has actually fallen by
approximately 20 percent per year in critical European countries such as Poland and the
United Kingdom.
Exhibit 42
In shale gas exploration, Europe currently lags significantly behind the United States
ten years before peak production
Shale gas production
Shale drilling activity
Number of wells
Estimated well density
Wells drilled per 1,000 sq km
25–30x
14x
8.4 billion m3
United States
(Barnett), 20031
Europe, 2013 = 0
30–40
Europe,
2013
973
United States
(Barnett), 2003
9
Europe,
1983–2012
127
United States,
1973–2002
1 Gas production from the Barnett Shale basin peaked at 57 billion cubic metres per annum in 2011; therefore, 2003 data give an indication of the level of
activity Europe would need to achieve to significantly expand production within ten years.
SOURCE: Baker Hughes; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Other domestic energy sources also face significant headwinds. Germany, for example, has
accelerated its phasing out of nuclear power.
Meanwhile, renewables are less subsidised
than before as many European governments and consumers bristle at the legacy costs of
past investments. In recent years, the Czech Republic and Spain have ended their feed-in
tariffs for renewables.
As an alternative to attempting to boost domestic supply, energy imports can help to reduce
energy prices provided the transmission of resources is considered stable and predictable.
Europe already imports a large share of its energy needs. In 2012, the EU procured
53 percent of its gross inland energy consumption from abroad, including 88 percent of
its demand for crude oil and natural gas liquids, 66 percent of its natural gas demand, and
70
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. 62 percent of its hard coal demand.89 Even treating energy from Norway (not a member of
the EU) as domestic supply, Europe remains highly reliant on imports, with dependency
rates of 78 percent for crude oil and natural gas liquids and 45 percent for natural gas.
Russia is the major supplier of all three types of energy and is a particularly critical partner for
natural gas, accounting for 47 percent of extra-Europe-30 imports to the EU (Exhibit 43).
Exhibit 43
The European Union relies heavily on energy imports
EU-28, 2012
%
Extra-Europe-30 origins of primary energy imports1
Final energy consumption by fuel
Renewables
11
Nuclear
Others
20
Nonrenewable
waste
Petroleum
and
34 products
14
Qatar
12
United States
23
Nigeria
9
Algeria
20
Libya
9
Colombia
24
Solid
fuels
Others
34
Australia
7
1
Others
21
Saudi Arabia
10
17
23
Russia
26
Gas
Hard coal
Russia
47
Russia
38
Crude oil
and NGLs2
Natural gas
Dependency on extra-Europe-30 imports3
%
62
78
45
1 Intra-Europe-28 imports and imports from Norway not included.
2 Natural gas liquids.
3 Net imports (gross inland consumption plus bunkers); intra-Europe-28 imports and imports from Norway not included.
SOURCE: European Commission; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
In the face of many concerns about the security of Europe’s energy supplies, the
European Commission has recommended supporting the development and expansion of
infrastructure to allow for further increases in gas import volumes from Norway as well as
from Central Asia, the Middle East, and North Africa. Complex geopolitics aside, any importbased strategy will be constrained by the situation in the global gas market. For instance,
89
McKinsey Global Institute
Figures for EU-28. See European energy security strategy, European Commission, May 2014.
A window of opportunity for Europe
71
.
in 2013 more than 80 percent of incremental liquefied natural gas (LNG) capacity under
development around the world was already contracted to specific buyers, mostly in nonEuropean destinations.90 US LNG is often held up as a promising new opportunity. However,
even if all US LNG exports expected in 2025 were directed to Europe, they would meet only
10 to 20 percent of European gas demand.91 In the case of coal, US exports to Europe more
than doubled between 2000 and 2012. This had only a marginal impact on power prices but
significant consequences for the EU’s 2020 carbon emissions targets.
Energy transmission
One way in which Europe could still significantly reduce its energy burden is by enhancing
the efficiency and connectivity of its domestic energy market, which remains rather
fragmented—a collection of national islands with only a few bridges between them. Spain’s
LNG import terminals ran at around one-quarter capacity in 2013, partly due to depressed
domestic demand and to a lack of interconnections with the rest of the continent.
By
enhancing market efficiency and heightening competition, a single European energy
market could reduce prices. For example, in the case of power, building and upgrading
interconnectors such as those between France and Italy and between the Netherlands
and Norway would yield the greatest gains due to large differences in price, supply, and
demand.92 Some neighbouring European countries have significant variations in electricity
prices. For example, in 2011, the average cost of electricity (excluding taxes) for industry
in Italy was 20.73 US cents per kilowatt-hour compared with only 12.91 cents in Austria.
Similarly, the cost for industry in Spain was 14.33 US cents per kilowatt-hour compared with
9.79 cents in France.
The significant variation in pre-tax electricity prices (when considering
weighted household and industrial prices) between European countries that are close or
even next to each other underlines the potential gains from closer integration (Exhibit 44).
Capturing the full benefits of integration would require not only new infrastructural links
across Europe but also more harmonisation of energy policies and regulation. Today, for
instance, there are surcharges and taxes that contribute to the strong variation in prices paid
by final energy consumers. For example, household- and industry-weighted average aftertax electricity prices in countries developing renewables such as Denmark and Germany
are more than 50 percent greater than in France, which relies predominantly on nuclear
power.
A more deeply integrated European energy market could also make efforts to foster
renewable energy in Europe much more effective. Utility-scale photovoltaic (PV) solar is
most efficient in parts of Southern Europe.93 However, in Germany, where solar PV is half
as efficient, demand is stimulated through subsidies. A study for the European Parliament
shows that, had German solar PV capacity been located in Spain, additional electricity
worth €740 million would have been generated in 2011 alone.94
Medium-term gas market report 2013: Market trends and projections to 2018, International Energy Agency,
June 2013.
91
“Figure MT-46: U.S.
exports of liquefied natural gas in five cases, 2005–40”, in Annual Energy Outlook 2014,
US Energy Information Administration, April 2014.
92
ACER/CEER annual report on the results of monitoring the internal electricity and natural gas markets in
2011, Agency for the Cooperation of Energy Regulators and Council of European Energy Regulators,
November 2012.
93
Photovoltaic Geographical Information System, European Commission, 2012.
94
Veit Böckers, Justus Haucap, and Ulrich Heimeshoff, Benefits of an integrated European electricity market,
Düsseldorfer Institut für Wettberwerbsökonomie discussion paper number 109, September 2013.
90
72
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. Exhibit 44
Variations in electricity prices within Europe demonstrate the potential gains possible
from an integrated energy market
Weighted average pre-tax electricity price of households and industry, 20111
Cents per kilowatt-hour
>20¢
15–20¢
10–15¢
<10¢
1 Malta excluded from analysis due to unavailability of data.
SOURCE: Enerdata; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Europe's energy
intensity is
129
tonnes of oil
equivalent per
$1 million in
2013, vs.
158
tonnes in
United States
Energy demand
High energy prices—and constraints on the expansion of supply—need not necessarily
impede European growth and competitiveness. High energy prices are primarily a concern
for chemicals, steel, and other energy-intensive industries that are likely to have limited
scope to reduce that intensity. However, energy-intensive industries, which we define as
industries in which the share of energy in total value added exceeds 10 percent, generate
only 7 percent of European total output. The comparable figure in the United States is
8 percent.
Many of the affected energy-intensive industries also tend to be regionally
based for logistical reasons; this means that there is a limited threat that they will move their
operations to other continents.
There is scope to further reduce energy intensity in the European economy as a whole,
and thereby reduce the burden of energy prices. A number of studies have demonstrated
positive direct and indirect effects of energy efficiency on economic activity.95 Europe is
already a global leader on energy efficiency. It has an energy intensity of 129 tonnes of
oil equivalent per million US dollars of GDP in 2013.
This is a lower intensity than that of
Australia and the United States, for instance, whose oil equivalents per million US dollars
of GDP are 147 tonnes and 158 tonnes, respectively. Europe’s energy intensity is less than
one-quarter that of China. Only Japan’s energy intensity, at 94 tonnes of oil equivalent
per million US dollars of GDP, is lower.
Europe’s relatively low energy intensity means that the
continent has been able to retain a share of energy costs in total output similar to that of the
United States, despite gas and electricity prices that are nearly twice as high (Exhibit 45).
Capturing the multiple benefits of energy efficiency, International Energy Agency, September 2014.
95
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
73
. Exhibit 45
Despite different energy costs, the share of energy input in economy-wide output is
roughly the same across Europe and the United States
Energy input share of total output, 20111
EU
United States
Share of energy in total output
%
70
70
60
60
50
50
40
40
30
30
20
Share of energy input
in total output = 4.96%
10
0
20
Share of energy input
in total output = 4.63%
10
0
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Output (value added)
%
1 Includes the following inputs: coke, refined petroleum and nuclear fuel, mining and quarrying, and electricity, gas and
water supply; excludes sales, maintenance, and repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles, and retail sales of fuel. Data
are for 2011 for the Europe-30 excluding Croatia, Norway, and Switzerland.
SOURCE: The World Input-Output database; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Industries in which energy plays a less important role in the generation of output can thrive
and be internationally competitive even in an environment of high energy costs. A recent
study found that countries facing high energy prices were successful at exporting products
that required less energy to make, while creating more jobs and higher value added, than
the goods exported by countries with lower energy prices.96 In a similar vein, a European
Commission analysis of real unit energy costs found that the European manufacturing
sector was maintaining its cost competitiveness by improving on energy intensity.97
There is an opportunity to leverage best practice across the continent in order to expand
Europe’s leading position on energy intensity to all of its regions. The energy intensity of
the Baltics and Central and Eastern Europe together stood at 267 tonnes of oil equivalent
per million US dollars of GDP—1.4 times that of Continental Europe and 2.4 times that of the
United Kingdom and Ireland, for instance.
The largest potential savings lie in the industry
and household sectors, which consume about half of total energy and have the largest
variations in energy intensity among countries (Exhibit 46).
Georg Zachmann and Valeria Cipollone, “Energy competitiveness”, in Manufacturing Europe’s future,
Reinhilde Veugelers, ed., Bruegel Blueprint Series, volume XXI, 2013.
97
Energy economic developments in Europe, European Commission, January 2014.
96
74
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. Exhibit 46
Energy intensity can be reduced through improved energy efficiency, particularly in industry and
among households
Variation in energy intensity1 in Europe,2 2013
Tonnes of oil equivalent per million $ 2005
Nordics
Continental Europe
United Kingdom
and Ireland
Leaders3
Europe-30
Southern Europe
Baltics
Share in
final energy
consumption
%
Followers3
Transport
75
14
14
Switzerland United
Kingdom
15
22
Denmark
42
Romania
Croatia
Bulgaria
136
23
23
26
Spain
Portugal
27%
42
Households4
91
Central and
Eastern Europe
25%
102
44
Switzerland
Romania
Poland
Industry
Bulgaria
315
167
24%
183
90
35
35
Switzerland United
Kingdom
40
Denmark
Romania
Services4
52
10
United
Kingdom
11
12
Switzerland Denmark
Finland
60
Bulgaria
61
13%
20
Czech
Republic
Slovakia
Bulgaria
1 Energy intensity of transport = transport energy use divided by GDP; energy intensity of households = climate-corrected household energy use divided by
private consumption; energy intensity of industry (services) = industry (services) energy use divided by value added of industry (services).
2 Europe-30 except for households; Croatia, where energy-intensity data are not available, is not included. Data for Switzerland are for 2012.
3 Leaders and followers are the top and bottom three countries in terms of energy intensity in Europe-30 with populations of >5 million.
4 Climate-adjusted.
SOURCE: Enerdata; Eurostat; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
75
. Energy intensity within sectors in Europe varies widely. Laggards can be five times as
energy-intensive as leaders. Of the four key sectors, the variation is greatest in industry.
Denmark, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom have the most energy-efficient industrial
sectors with energy intensities that are between four and nine times lower than in Bulgaria,
Finland, and Romania, the most energy-intensive countries. This gap is due partly to the
sector mix of these different economies.
In Bulgaria, Finland, and Romania, industries
with high energy intensity, including steel, chemicals, non-metallic minerals, and paper,
account for 70 to 80 percent of their total value added compared with 30 to 45 percent in
best-practice countries. Yet improvements to energy intensity have often varied significantly
across industries in these countries.
Service sectors are far less energy-intensive than many industrial sectors. As Baltic and
Central and Eastern European countries move along the usual development curve away
from industry and towards services, energy intensity should naturally fall.
But this shift will
take time. Today, industry (including construction) in these European regions accounts for
almost 50 percent of their economies compared with only around 30 percent in the United
Kingdom, for example.98 This means that, for now, energy prices are of greater concern for
them. The share of energy input in economy-wide output is about 7 percent in the Baltics
and Central and Eastern Europe compared with approximately 4 percent in the United
Kingdom and Ireland.
Even within services, energy intensity can vary considerably. For
example, the United Kingdom consumes ten tonnes of oil equivalent per million US dollars of
value added in its services sectors—one-sixth the level in Slovakia.
The transportation sector’s energy intensity is driven by a number of factors, including the
share of road transport (accounting for 82 percent of total transport energy consumption
in the EU), the efficiency of vehicles, and distances between hubs of economic activity.
Continental Europe, the Nordics, and the United Kingdom and Ireland have the lowest
transport energy intensity in Europe. In the Netherlands, strong tax incentives encouraging
the adoption of efficient vehicles have been in place since 2006.
These include a bonuspenalty scheme that links the level of passenger car and motorcycle tax to carbon dioxide
emissions per kilometre, as well as income tax incentives for efficient company cars. These
measures have arguably contributed to the highest penetration of hybrid electric vehicles in
Europe at 4.5 percent of car sales compared with 1 percent on average in the EU.99
The energy intensity of households in Europe is 44 tonnes of oil equivalent per million US
dollars of private consumption largely due to high energy use in buildings in some European
economies. Portugal, Spain, and Switzerland are Europe’s leaders in household energy
efficiency (adjusted for differences in climate) with an energy intensity that is between 3.5
times and six times lower than that of households in Bulgaria, Poland, and Romania.
A key
driver of energy efficiency among households is awareness of the costs of poor energy
efficiency in the form of higher bills and of ways to tackle this. In economies in Central and
Eastern Europe, policies aimed at increasing awareness and fostering energy efficiency in
households have made progress, albeit only relatively recently. For instance, in 2009, the
Czech Republic launched a scheme providing subsidies and grants for measures aimed
at improving household energy efficiency.
Projects supported by the scheme included
investments in home insulation, new construction that meets passive-energy house
standards, and investments in heating equipment that relies on renewable sources of
energy. In 2011, Poland required energy utilities to provide customers with comparisons
of their electricity consumption with previous years, as well as with information on energyefficiency measures.100
Sector composition based on data from the CIA World Factbook.
European vehicle market statistics 2013, International Council on Clean Transportation, October 2013.
100
Sara Pasquier and Aurelien Saussay, Progress implementing the IEA 25 energy efficiency policy
recommendations: 2011 evaluation, International Energy Agency, March 2012.
98
99
76
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
Initiatives to change the game
Between 2003 and 2013, the energy intensity in 30 European countries declined at an
annual rate of 1.9 percent, and we believe progress on this front can continue. Further
European progress on improving energy productivity and liberalising the gas and energy
markets could result in an annual uptick in GDP growth of 0.13 percent.
Among the imperatives that we see as most important are:
7.6%
cut in energy
consumption
targeted by
Denmark 2010–20
ƒƒ Use targets, standards, and fiscal policy to incentivise investment in energy
productivity. While high energy prices are a major motivator for improving energy
efficiency, government action is still necessary to address the many market failures and
behavioural biases that undermine progress in this area.101 For example, investments
in weatherised rental or leased properties don’t tend to happen because tenants, who
pay the utility bills, would derive the benefit rather than the building owners. Similarly,
consumers tend to buy cheaper but less energy-efficient appliances because it takes
a relatively long time to reap the savings from the more energy-efficient choice.
In many
cases, too, consumers don’t have the information they need to make the most sensible
choice.102 Governments can address such issues in a variety of ways. Progressively
higher energy-efficiency standards are a proven way to accelerate investments in energy
efficiency. In Denmark, the government has set a target of reducing energy consumption
by 7.6 percent between 2010 and 2020 through energy-efficiency measures.
From
that overall target, regulations cascade down into each sector. Another way to promote
energy efficiency is through fiscal policy. The EU’s Emissions Trading Scheme, which
sets a price for carbon emissions, is, in effect, a tax on carbon-intensive energy use.
In
the United States in 1977, then-President Jimmy Carter put forward a proposal known
as the standby gas tax under which higher petrol taxes would be imposed every year
that the United States failed to meet lower targets for petrol consumption, but with the
income earned through the tax returned to citizens via income tax credits. The proposal
was defeated in congressional committee.
ƒƒ Accelerate progress towards a single European energy market. A Europe-wide
energy market would promote competition and enable suppliers to achieve scale,
thereby enhancing efficiency and reducing energy costs over the medium term.
The
EU’s Third Energy Package recognised that initiatives were needed in a number of
areas to make this happen. They include building numerous interconnectors between
national energy markets, establishing a level playing field for domestic and international
suppliers within individual countries, ensuring non-discriminatory access to transmission
infrastructure, and allowing the resale of surplus energy purchases. While some
progress has been made in this area, it has been largely incremental.
One step forward
was the coupling of the electricity markets of the Czech Republic, Hungary, and Slovakia
in 2012, which drove a convergence in power prices in these three economies. The fact
that energy markets within Europe are designed differently is a constraint on market
participants meeting demand from customers across the continent’s internal borders.
Design differences within Europe include variations in price formation mechanisms such
as gas-trading hubs and forward markets for electricity, and contractual structures like
destination clauses that limit the trading of energy.103 A lack of infrastructure such as gas
and power interconnectors among European economies makes trading across borders
nearly impossible. In this regard, the EU’s Connecting Europe Facility—a €5.85 billion
programme to build cross-border energy infrastructure—is an important start.
Energy market report 2013: Market trends and medium-term prospects, International Energy Agency, 2013.
Resource revolution: Meeting the world’s energy, materials, food, and water needs, McKinsey Global Institute,
November 2011.
103
ACER/CEER annual report on the results of monitoring the internal electricity and natural gas markets in 2013,
Agency for the Cooperation of Energy Regulators, October 2014.
101
102
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
77
.
Almost
30%
of German
electricity in 2014
from renewables
ƒƒ Launch a cost-effective pan-European renewables and, provided environmental
concerns can be addressed, unconventional oil and gas strategy. To enhance the
security of supply and to foster industrial development, in recent years many European
countries have provided incentives like feed-in tariffs to encourage the development of
domestic production of renewable energy. Germany has taken this the furthest. In 2014,
renewables accounted for almost 30 percent of German electricity production.104 The
benefit of these schemes could be multiplied if they were to be rolled out Europe-wide
and across many still-maturing technologies.
For example, subsidies for solar make
more sense if they are directed towards the sunniest parts of Europe. Other frontier
energy technologies could also be a target of assistance, including unconventional
fossil fuels like shale gas and energy storage technologies. Shifting away from energy
based on fossil fuels also reduces a country’s risk to future carbon regulations, or a rapid
increase in the price of carbon dioxide, in the context of carbon markets.
Bruno Burger, Electricity production from solar and wind in Germany in 2014, Fraunhofer ISE (Institute für
Solare Energiesysteme), December 2014.
104
78
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. 5. SUPPORTING URBAN DEVELOPMENT
Cities are the most dynamic centres of economic activity today. They create network
effects, accentuate economies of scale in the provision of goods and services, enable more
dynamic and flexible labour markets, and facilitate the transmission of knowledge and ideas.
All of these boost productivity growth.105 Urbanisation and per capita GDP have moved in
tandem for decades (Exhibit 47).106
Exhibit 47
Per capita GDP has risen in tandem with increases in the urbanisation rate
Per capita GDP and urbanisation1
Per capita GDP2
1990 purchasing power parity $ (log scale)
30,000
Japan
2005
Germany
2005
Italy
2005
United States
2005
South
Korea
2005
10,000
India
2005
3,000
China
2005
1950
1950
Brazil
2005
1820
1,000
1891
1930
1950
1920
1950
300
Increasing urbanisation rate
%
1 Definition of urbanisation varies by country.
2 Historical per capita GDP series expressed in 1990 Geary-Khamis dollars, which reflect purchasing power parity.
SOURCE: United Nations Population Division; Angus Maddison via Timetrics; IHS; census reports of England and Wales; Honda in Steckel and Floud,1997;
Bairoch, 1975; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
There is a large body of literature on urban economics focused on assessing the nature and size of urban
economies of scale. See, for example, Edward L.
Glaeser and Joshua D. Gottlieb, The wealth of cities:
Agglomeration economies and spatial equilibrium in the United States, NBER working paper number 14806,
March 2009; World development report 2009: Reshaping economic geography, World Bank, December
2008; and Indermit S. Gill and Chor-Ching Goh, “Scale economies and cities”, World Bank Research
Observer, volume 25, number 2, August 2010.
106
MGI has published extensively on urbanisation.
See Preparing for China’s urban billion, March 2009; India’s
urban awakening: Building inclusive cities, sustaining economic growth, April 2010; Urban world: Mapping the
economic power of cities, March 2011; Building globally competitive cities: The key to Latin American growth,
August 2011; Urban America: US cities in the world economy, April 2012; Urban world: Cities and the rise of
the consuming class, June 2012; and Urban world: The shifting global business landscape, October 2013.
105
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
79
. Europe is far less urbanised than either the United States or South Korea, for instance,
and the share of people within Europe living in cities varies enormously. This suggests a
considerable opportunity for some European economies to capture more of the economic
benefits that urban living offers. While citizens should be free to choose where they want
to live, and megacities (with populations of ten million or more) face particular challenges,
there are barriers to rural-to-urban migration that should be removed, including high levels
of support per capita in rural areas through the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP), high
price-to-income ratios for housing, and low satisfaction with urban infrastructure. Europe
can more broadly apply funding approaches such as property-value capture to support
urban redevelopment, including affordable housing and the expansion of infrastructure,
as Spain has done, and focus more on citizen-friendly provision of public services.
Cities
that are experiencing significant emigration need to up their game in competing for talent
at a European and even global level. Accelerating its rate of urbanisation to that of the
Netherlands, the fastest urbanising country between 2000 and 2012, could generate an
additional 0.09 percent of real GDP growth for Europe per annum.
30
percentage point
difference between
Europe's most and
least urbanised
regions
Where Europe stands
European cities started to grow and proliferate rapidly in the 18th century, but Europe’s
urbanisation rate today still lags behind that of many other developed regions, and it
varies enormously within the continent. According to recent data from the MGI Cityscope
database, which uses a definition of urban areas derived from population density and travelto-work flows, only about 60 percent of Europe’s population can be classified as urban.107
This is well below the urbanisation rates in other developed economies, including South
Korea at 87 percent, Japan at 82 percent, the United States at 81 percent, and Canada at
65 percent.
Within Europe, there is a difference of 30 percentage points between the most
urbanised region (the United Kingdom and Ireland) and the least urbanised one (Central and
Eastern Europe). These disparities clearly point to considerable scope for Europe to boost
economic growth by stepping up the development of towns and cities, especially in regions
that are still comparatively rural (Exhibit 48).
Cityscope is a McKinsey Global Institute global database of more than 2,500 cities that brings together
MGI research on cities. For a detailed explanation of the methodology used to define cities and map
socioeconomic factors across regions, see Urban world: Cities and the rise of the consuming class, McKinsey
Global Institute, June 2012.
107
80
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. Exhibit 48
There is significant scope to increase the urbanisation rate across Europe,
particularly in Central and Eastern Europe and the Baltics
Degree of urbanisation, 20121
% of population
South
Korea
87.1
81.7
Japan
United
States
Canada
81.2
65.3
Absolute
growth,
2000–122
%
United Kingdom
and Ireland
69.1
+2.7
Continental
Europe
69.0
+2.5
Southern
Europe
Nordics
Mexico
Turkey
53.4
+2.2
+1.3
62.0
Baltics
Europe-30
62.1
60.6
49.0
Central and
Eastern Europe
44.4
39.0
-0.4
+0.3
1 Harmonised definition of urban areas on basis of population density and travel-to-work flows.
2 Absolute urbanisation growth calculated on the basis of UN urbanisation data (administrative definition of urban areas)
and scaled to 2012 urbanisation rates based on MGI Cityscope database.
SOURCE: MGI Cityscope database; Eurostat; United Nations Population Division; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
81
. Over the past 15 years, however, Europe’s least urban countries, which are mostly located
in Central and Eastern Europe and the Baltics, have not become significantly more urban;
indeed, their rates of urbanisation have been static at best (Exhibit 49). Despite these
countries’ low starting position on urbanisation, and even though some of their cities have
experienced significant rises in per capita incomes, their urban areas have not managed
to attract citizens in greater numbers. For example, Bulgaria’s capital city of Sofia and
Romania’s capital city of Bucharest posted per capita GDP growth of more than 13
percentage points a year between 2000 and 2011, but their populations did not grow.
Exhibit 49
Urbanisation in Central and Eastern Europe and the Baltics has been sluggish despite a low starting point in 2000
Size =
Population, 2013
Nordics
Continental
Europe
Urbanisation
Compound annual growth rate, 2000–12, %
United
Kingdom
and Ireland
Southern
Europe
Baltics
Central
and Eastern
Europe
1.3
1.2
Netherlands
1.1
Portugal
1.0
0.9
0.8
0.7
Hungary
0.6
United Kingdom
Bulgaria
0.5
Ireland
0.4
Luxembourg
Croatia Norway
0.3
0.2
Greece
France
Denmark
Romania
0.1
0
Slovenia
-0.1
Italy
Lithuania
Switzerland
Czech Republic
Belgium
Austria
Cyprus
Estonia
-0.3
Malta
Germany
Sweden
Poland
Latvia
-0.2
Finland
Spain
Slovakia
-0.4
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
55
60
65
70
Average urbanisation level, 2000
75
80
85
90
82
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
100
Urbanisation rate, 20001
%
1 2000 urbanisation rates obtained by applying historic UN urbanisation growth rates to MGI Cityscope database urbanisation rate from 2012.
SOURCE: United Nations; MGI Cityscope database; Eurostat; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
95
.
Rather than catching up with their more urbanised European peers, regions with relatively
low urbanisation rates have experienced further declines in their city populations. For
example, urbanisation rates decreased in seven countries in the Baltics and Central and
Eastern Europe between 2000 and 2012. In some cases, including the Baltic countries
and Poland, the decline in the urban population has outpaced the decline in their overall
populations (Exhibit 50).
Exhibit 50
Among countries whose populations have shrunk, only Hungary, Croatia, and Germany increased flows to cities
Urbanisation trend decomposed by urban and total population growth
Compound annual growth rate, 2000–12, %
Population
change
-0.2
Hungary
Growing
urban
population
Positive
urbanisation
rate
0.4
-0.2
Croatia
0.1
-0.1
Germany
Urban
population
shrinking at
slower rate
0.1
-0.4
Romania
-0.2
-0.7
Bulgaria
-0.2
-0.1
Poland
Negative
urbanisation
rate
Urban
population
shrinking at
faster pace
-0.2
-0.3
Estonia
-0.5
-0.9
Latvia
Lithuania
Urban population
change
-0.9
-1.0
-1.1
SOURCE: United Nations; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
83
. Why are cities, especially in the Baltics and Central and Eastern Europe, not growing faster
despite rising incomes that should, theoretically, attract workers looking for better jobs and
a higher quality of life? Broadly speaking, there are “push” and “pull” factors that persuade
migrants to move from rural to urban areas. An example of a push factor is a paucity of wellpaid jobs in the countryside; a pull factor is the promise of better public services in cities. In
the case of Europe’s less urbanised regions, both types of factor come into play:
ƒƒ Push factors. One of the factors limiting the migration of less productive rural workers
to cities where incomes tend to be higher and job prospects arguably more promising
is the existence of extensive subsidies for the rural economy.
These subsidies artificially
enhance incomes in rural areas and therefore potentially discourage citizens from
moving to more urbanised areas. The EU’s Common Agricultural Policy supports
rural regions through direct payments to improve farmers’ incomes and subsidies to
foster rural development. Despite the fact that agriculture accounts for only 5 percent
of European jobs, the CAP commands 40 percent of the EU budget (approximately
€60 billion in 2013, of which three-quarters was in the form of direct income subsidies
to farmers).
These subsidies weaken the push towards urbanisation (Exhibit 51). CAP
transfers are particularly large compared with rural per capita GDP in Bulgaria and other
countries where urbanisation rates are lowest and where incentives to live and work in
rural areas are least needed.
Citizens in Greece
and Latvia pay
12–14X
annual income to
buy a house vs.
5X
in Ireland
ƒƒ Pull factors. Cities can attract people from other areas by becoming more competitive.
This is especially relevant for countries in the Schengen area, where cities no longer
compete on a national scale but rather a Europe-wide scale.108 This may go some
way towards explaining the declining urban populations of countries in the Baltics and
Central and Eastern Europe.
Competitive cities tend to have a favourable regulatory
environment for business, strong institutions, simple and transparent city-level policies,
efficient infrastructure, and good-quality educational and training provision.109 These
elements can attract both the businesses that provide jobs and the people who fill them.
Affordable housing is another vital pull factor for cities. As analysed in detail in recent MGI
research, a lack of decent housing as well as excessive costs for renting or acquiring it is
an increasingly urgent social and economic problem around the world.110 Within the EU,
an estimated 5 percent of the population faces severe housing deprivation (defined as
living in overcrowded or substandard housing conditions), and many more are financially
overstretched due to high housing costs. On this score, different locations within Europe
vary enormously.
In terms of buying a house, affordability is a particularly pressing issue
in Central and Eastern Europe as well as Southern European countries such as Greece
and Italy (Exhibit 52). Citizens in these economies have to pay, on average, 12 to 14 times
their annual income to buy a house, compared with five times in Ireland and six times
in Germany or the Netherlands. In other countries, the affordability challenge is more
concentrated in particular cities such as London or Paris, where newcomers often find it
difficult to find housing that offers reasonable value for money.
The Schengen Area comprises 26 European countries that have abolished passport and any other type of
border control at their common borders, also referred to as internal borders.
109
The competitiveness of cities, World Economic Forum, August 2014.
110
A blueprint for addressing the global affordable housing challenge, McKinsey Global Institute, October 2014.
108
84
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. Cities whose populations are declining urgently need to respond to this trend by boosting
their competitiveness. In order to drive growth in their urban economies, they will have to
attract new inhabitants, not only from other cities but most importantly from rural areas in
the same countries. The demographics of European rural areas underline the economic
potential of spurring rural-to-urban migration. People of prime working age constitute
a share of the total rural population very similar to that of urban areas (67 percent and
66 percent, respectively).
The performance of many European economies could be
enhanced significantly if a greater share of working-age rural people moved to cities and into
higher-productivity jobs, while still striking a productive balance between the deployment of
labour in rural and urban areas.
Exhibit 51
Common Agricultural Policy transfers per rural inhabitant are high in countries with low urbanisation rates
Size =
GDP, 2012
Nordics1
Continental
Europe2
United
Kingdom
and Ireland
Southern
Europe3
Baltics
Central
and Eastern
Europe4
Urbanisation rate, 2012
%
90
R-squared = 26.7%
85
Belgium
80
Netherlands
75
United
Kingdom
70
65
Austria
Germany
Spain
Cyprus
60
Italy
Portugal
France
55
Sweden
50
Slovenia
40
Greece
Czech Republic
Finland
45
Lithuania
Denmark
Poland
Estonia
Hungary
Latvia
35
Slovakia
30
Bulgaria
Ireland
Romania
25
20
0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5
6.0
EU Common Agricultural Policy transfers, 2013
Percentage share of rural per capita GDP
1
2
3
4
Excluding
Excluding
Excluding
Excluding
Norway.
Switzerland and Luxembourg.
Malta.
Croatia.
SOURCE: European Commission; MGI Cityscope database; United Nations; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
85
. Exhibit 52
Price-to-income ratios vary significantly within Europe, with ratios highest in
the Baltics and Central and Eastern Europe
Price-to-income ratio for housing , 2014
Nordics
Continental
Europe
United
Kingdom
and Ireland
Southern
Europe
Baltics
Central
and Eastern
Europe
Romania
13.8
13.5
Latvia
13.4
Croatia
Malta
12.5
Greece
12.5
Italy
12.4
Lithuania
11.5
Estonia
10.8
10.5
Poland
Bulgaria
10.0
Spain
9.9
Slovenia
9.9
Slovakia
9.3
France
9.3
9.0
Hungary
9.0
Czech Republic
8.5
Portugal
8.3
Austria
7.9
Norway
United Kingdom
7.2
Luxembourg
7.1
Finland
7.0
Switzerland
7.0
Cyprus
6.8
Sweden
6.8
6.6
Belgium
6.4
Denmark
Netherlands
6.1
Germany
6.1
5.5
Ireland
SOURCE: Numbeo; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
86
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. Initiatives to change the game
If Europe acted to boost the rate of urbanisation across the region and, in particular, in the
Baltics and Central and Eastern Europe, an additional 0.09 percent of real GDP growth per
annum could be generated. This estimate assumes that all European countries accelerate
the growth of their urban population to the rate of the fastest urbanising country between
2000 and 2012 (the Netherlands with 1.2 percent per year) while maintaining the difference
in labour productivity between rural and urban areas.
To make this happen, European governments should consider taking action in the
following areas:
~80%
of survey
respondents in
Luxembourg
satisfied with public
transport vs.
40%
in Cyprus
ƒƒ Enable urban redevelopment and expansion, supported by regulatory changes
and property-value capture. For cities to attract people, they must have the capacity
to support growth. Transport infrastructure—within cities, between city centres and
suburbs, between cities, and between rural and urban areas—is a vital enabler for urban
expansion.
When asked about their satisfaction levels with public transport, around
80 percent of respondents in Finland, Latvia, and Luxembourg said that they were
satisfied, in contrast to the 45 to 50 percent of respondents in Cyprus and Italy who
expressed the same view.111 Best-practice cities have been able to finance expansion of
infrastructure through innovative funding mechanisms such as property-value capture,
in which increases in the value of land near developments are used to fund projects.
While urban development can boost the competitiveness of a city, projects often
face regulatory barriers such as zoning restrictions that need to be tackled. In 1982,
the government of the United Kingdom simplified the process for obtaining planning
permission for ten years in order to redevelop derelict docklands to the east of London’s
city centre. This led to the development of the Canary Wharf financial centre that today
employs more than 100,000 people.
Hamburg’s experience of building HafenCity, Europe’s largest development zone, offers
a potential model for how to construct cost-effective infrastructure that enables highdensity development.
HafenCity Hamburg GmbH, a subsidiary of the Hamburg citystate government, planned and is managing the project that began in 2000 to reclaim
127 hectares in the former harbour areas near the city centre. It works closely with the
private sector and the city-state government to review and approve projects, and revise
the master plan according to macroeconomic conditions and feasibility reports. The
project is not due for completion until 2025 but, even today, HafenCity has enlarged the
city centre by 40 percent, created 45,000 jobs at 500 companies, and developed 6,000
homes.
HafenCity Hamburg GmbH has invested in streets, plazas, public transport
systems, and the quay wall. By 2025, the company expects to break even and will
subsequently pay taxes that will flow to the city-state.
ƒƒ Develop affordable housing. Even if a city attracts employers and develops highquality infrastructure to support growth, people will not flock there if no affordable
housing is available.
Cities can improve on this dimension by unlocking land supply,
taking an industrial approach to development, building scale efficiency, and assisting in
developer financing.112 For example, developers were able to sell half of the residential
units in Barcelona’s La Marina development at one-third of market rates and still maintain
a positive business proposition by increasing the 1.0 floor-area ratio to 2.3. By pooling
demand, one consortium dedicated to buying social housing in the United Kingdom was
able to reduce operations and maintenance costs in certain categories by 25 percent.
Since such costs can account for 20 to 30 percent of annual housing expenditure,
Europeans’ satisfaction with urban transport, Flash Eurobarometer 382b, European Commission, June 2014.
A blueprint for solving the global affordable housing challenge, McKinsey Global Institute, September 2014.
111
112
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
87
. effective asset-management guidelines set by the government can improve the
affordability of housing.
ƒƒ Remove barriers to rural-urban migration and improve city attractiveness for
talent. Europe can boost productivity by making sure that top talent goes to the right
places. Given the trend of workers moving to more attractive cities within Europe that
offer better prospects, it is imperative that governments remove barriers to both ruralurban migration and intercity migration. Existing incentive schemes such as the CAP
tend to discourage rural workers from moving and artificially inflate the share of workers
employed in agriculture and other less-productive industries.
Across Europe, there is a
negative association between the amount of rural development support on offer on a per
capita basis and the degree of urbanisation. This incentive to stay in rural areas poses a
particular challenge in less-urbanised countries, where emigration to more competitive
cities abroad depletes the urban workforce.
To reverse this trend, regions such as the Baltics and Central and Eastern Europe
should consider how to foster urban settings that enable them to retain talent. A
positive example in this respect is the city of Wrocław in Poland, which launched a
comprehensive “strategy on preventing youth migration” in 2012 to complement the
city’s economic development efforts.
This strategy covers a wide range of priority
actions, including a regional “flexicurity” model to reduce youth unemployment,
affordable housing tailored to young people, and improved child-care services. Another
element of an attractive city is citizen-centric government services. Many municipalities
in the United Kingdom have been grappling with shrinking budgets but have still
managed to restructure their departments to improve their service to customers even
while improving cost-effectiveness.
For example, Somerset County Council went
through a radical transformation effort triggered by budgetary pressure. The council
realised that, in order to maximise the value it delivers, employees at all levels needed to
develop the right capabilities. Nine behaviour sets were created for employees—from
the front line to executives—against which employees were assessed.
A complementary
training programme was put in place to address any development needs. A transition
from a command-and-control model to greater ownership for service delivery at the
point of customer contact improved customer satisfaction and has kept employee
relations positive.
88
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
6. COMPETITIVE AND INTEGRATED MARKETS IN
SERVICES AND DIGITAL
Despite Europe’s being one of the world’s most powerful regional economies, its
productivity growth in services, including digital, has long lagged behind that of the United
States. There is scope to reform the regulation governing many service activities in order
to respond more effectively to the needs of the modern marketplace. Regulation varies
significantly within Europe.
For example, in the Czech Republic, 395 professions are
licensed—restricting market entry, reducing supply, and raising prices—compared with only
45 licensed professions in Estonia. Reforming land markets in Sweden resulted in a change
in store formats and a major acceleration of productivity growth in the retail sector.
Beyond regulation, an equally important lever for enhancing competitiveness and
productivity is further integration of markets through Europe’s Single Market legislation.113
Today, the European Commission estimates that only around 40 to 50 percent of
the potential impact of the EU Services Directive has been realised because of poor
implementation and enforcement of the rules in some countries.114 We find that, in many
cases, countries with the most infringements against the Services Directive between 2002
and 2012 also achieved the least productivity growth in services.
Major initiatives within this growth driver include dismantling the remaining barriers to the
competitive provision of services, fully implementing the Services Directive, developing a
single European sky (coordinated air traffic management), and increasing connectivity and
competition in rail as well as road haulage. Europe would also benefit from an integrated
pan-European digital market.
Today, Europe’s telecoms and digital infrastructure remains
fragmented, with high price variations. There are 250 collective management organisations
in Europe for digital content, many with national monopolies in specific sectors. Further
integration, including data and consumer protection rules, is needed.
Ensuring competitive
transnational markets in services and digital could result in 0.43 percent of incremental real
GDP growth.
Services generate
~70%
>70%
of EU GDP and
of jobs
Where Europe stands
Despite accounting for only 7 percent of the world’s population, the 30 European countries
generated €14.1 trillion of GDP in 2013, or 25 percent of the world’s total compared with
22 percent for the United States and 13 percent for China.115 Creating a frontier-free
economic region among its constituent nations is a defining purpose of the EU, which has
pursued the integration between the economies of its member states since its inception. In
1986, with the adoption of the Single European Act, the EU established the free movement
of goods, services, capital, and people within its borders.
However, despite significant progress towards creating a true single market, significant
barriers to cross-border trade remain. Within countries, the regulatory framework for certain
products and services continues to act as a brake on competition and improvements in
productivity.
This is partly as a result of a disconnection between the spirit of the policies
As a member of the European Economic Area (EEA), Norway fully applies the entire acquis communautaire
relevant to the free movement of goods, persons, services, and capital. Switzerland is not a member of the
EEA, but it, too, enjoys full access to the Single Market, governed by around 100 bilateral agreements. The
future of this privileged access is, however, in jeopardy following a referendum in Switzerland in February
2014 that called for the unilateral introduction of quotas for migrants from EU countries.
Both Norway and
Switzerland are members of the European Free Trade Association, which governs their trade relations with
non-EU countries.
114
Josefa Monteagudo, Aleksander Rutkowski, and Dimitri Lorenzani, The economic impact of the Services
Directive: A first assessment following implementation, European Commission economic paper number 456,
June 2012.
115
EU-28, plus Norway and Switzerland, 2013 GDP figures. See World economic outlook: Legacies, clouds,
uncertainties, IMF, October 2014.
113
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
89
. agreed at the European level, the letter of the laws used to transpose these policies onto
the national statute books, and the specific measures implemented to make them a reality.
Overall, there is considerable scope to more fully translate European directives into tangible
change. Governments could adopt ambitious and open approaches to ensure that their
economies reap the greatest possible benefit of integration rather than doing just enough
to avoid facing an infringement case before the European Court of Justice. Member states
can also benefit by building on the EU measures to develop additional domestic policies to
promote competition and productivity.
The need to redouble efforts to integrate and liberalise Europe’s economy is particularly
significant in the services sector. Services account for roughly 70 percent of EU GDP and
more than 70 percent of EU employment.
However, most of the consumption of services
happens within national borders. Exports of services within the EU stood at just 6 percent
of GDP in 2012, while the equivalent figure for goods exports stood at 22 percent, up ten
percentage points since 1992. A survey commissioned by the European Commission in
2013 explored consumer attitudes to the markets of goods and services.
Looking at market
comparability, trust, complaints, expectations, and choice (and ease) of switching, it found
that consumers still view the performance of the Single Market less positively in the case of
services than for goods, suggesting that they find it less complete.116
The locally and nationally focused provision of services in Europe has important
consequences for productivity. In the run-up to the global financial crisis, European
productivity growth in goods had been on a par with that in the United States. However,
productivity growth in services lagged behind that of the United States by 30 percent
(Exhibit 53).
Economic integration has many drivers, including factors that are difficult for policy makers
to control, such as geographic distance and linguistic or cultural barriers.
Nevertheless,
policy plays an important role.117 The OECD’s Services Trade Restrictiveness Index tracks
the policy measures that most affect trade, with scores running between 0 (completely
open) and 1 (completely closed). Although European economies are comparatively open
overall with a score of 0.17, there is significant variation among countries as well as between
sectors of the economy (Exhibit 54).
To an extent, gaps in EU legislation and the incomplete transposition, implementation,
and enforcement of Single Market legislation by EU member states have stood in the way
of deeper integration.118 The five priority areas for completing the Single Market are those
with the greatest potential for additional growth: boosting integration and competition in
the services sector; completing the integration of Europe’s transport networks; fostering
the digital single market; consolidating the market in financial services; and constructing a
unified European energy market. Since finance and energy are discussed elsewhere in this
report, this section focuses on the first three.119
See A single market for growth and jobs: An analysis of progress made and remaining obstacles in the
member states, European Commission, November 2013, and Monitoring consumer markets in the European
Union 2013 Part I, European Commission, August 2013.
117
Natalie Chen and Dennis Novy, International trade integration: A disaggregated approach, CEP discussion
paper number dp0908, Centre for Economic Performance, London School of Economics, January 2009.
118
There are currently more than 1,600 directives that regulate the EU internal market, and most countries have
correctly transposed this legislation into national law.
Only five countries—Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Romania,
and Slovenia—have adopted less than 99 percent of Single Market legislation. However, these numbers
don’t consider how strictly EU legislation is enforced in national markets. In EU law, member states transpose
directives by passing implementation measures through either primary or secondary legislation.
119
The free movement of people is also an area with significant gaps, as seen by the low mobility between EU
member states.
Barriers to labour-market mobility are addressed in the discussion of enhanced labourmarket flexibility.
116
90
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. Exhibit 53
Europe’s trade in goods is much more integrated than trade in services
Trade integration and productivity growth
Trade integration
Trade intensity, 1992–20121
%
Services3
Productivity growth
Contribution to labour productivity
increase, 1995–20072
Percentage points
18.3
12.9
3
6
22
Goods4
12
19925
1
2
3
4
5
-5.4
9.7
2012
United States
8.9
-0.8
Europe-25
Intra-EU exports as a percentage of GDP.
Value added (at constant prices) per hour worked; sector weightings on the basis of 1995 levels.
Private and public services; NACE classification groups L–Q.
Resources and manufactured goods; NACE groups A–D.
Intra-EU exports in 1992 refer to the composition of EU at the time.
SOURCE: EU KLEMS growth and productivity accounts, March 2011 update; OECD; Eurostat; McKinsey Global Institute
analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
91
. Exhibit 54
Ranking barriers to services trade reveal large differences between sectors and
among countries
STRI1
Barriers vary between different sectors …
… and among countries
GDP weighted
average
Sector
Distribution
Country
Netherlands
0.09
Unweighted
sector average
0.10
Construction
0.10
United Kingdom
0.13
Commercial banking
0.11
Germany
0.14
Telecom
0.11
Luxembourg
0.14
Computer
0.13
Denmark
0.15
Rail freight transport
0.13
Ireland
0.15
Sound recording
0.13
France
0.15
Insurance
0.14
Spain
0.16
Motion pictures
0.14
Slovenia
0.16
Courier
0.14
Hungary
0.16
Road freight transport
0.14
Czech Republic
0.17
Maritime transport
0.15
Sweden
0.17
Belgium
0.18
Engineering
Architecture
Broadcasting
Legal
0.17
Portugal
0.19
Italy
Air transport
0.36
European economies
average
0.21
Norway
0.26
0.21
Finland
0.20
0.24
Accounting
0.19
0.22
Estonia
0.22
Greece
0.22
Austria
0.24
Switzerland
0.25
Poland
0.25
OECD average
1 OECD Services Trade Restrictiveness Index describes ease of cross-border trade in services. Averages for OECD
countries in Europe, 0–1, where 0 = no barriers at all, and 1 = fully regulated monopoly.
SOURCE: OECD; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
92
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. Boosting integration and competition in the services sector
The main vehicle for driving integration of services in the EU is the Services Directive of
2006. Activities covered by the directive accounted for 63 percent of intra-EU services
exports in 2008.120 The centrepiece of the directive is a “freedom to provide services”
clause that stipulates that member states should not impose their national requirements
upon incoming service providers unless these requirements are non-discriminatory
and justified by reasons of public policy, public safety, public health, or the protection of
the environment.121 It also prohibits discriminatory requirements such as nationality and
residence requirements or requirements such as “economic needs” tests, and establishes
single points of contact in every member state as e-government portals for entrepreneurs
active in the service sector. Finally, the directive contains measures to strengthen
consumers’ rights, including non-discriminatory requirements, and disclosure and
transparency requirements.
While the Services Directive has formally been adopted by all EU member states, the
degree to which its aims are realised in practice varies among countries. The European
Commission’s “zero-tolerance” approach, proclaimed in 2012, has prompted some
member states to implement further reforms.
However, significant restrictions on foreign
services companies still exist. The European Commission estimates that only between
40 and 50 percent of the potential positive impact on GDP of the Services Directive has
been realised thus far because of poor implementation and enforcement of the rules.122 If
all member states were to reduce the level of restrictions to that of the five best countries in
the EU per sector, additional gains amounting to 1.6 percent of GDP are projected.123 The
sluggish pace of reform in some sectors is likely to have limited productivity gains in the
services sector. In many cases, countries with high compliance with the Services Directive
between 2002 and 2012 were also those that achieved high productivity growth in services
over this period (Exhibit 55).
Beyond the implementation of Single Market legislation to facilitate cross-border provision
of services, effective competition in local services is often hampered by technical and
administrative barriers at the national level.124 These include lengthy procedures for
registering new businesses, opaque public tenders, and complex national legislation
on taxation and labour standards.
Such barriers impose high costs on the providers of
services, particularly small companies, and therefore reduce the potential for productivity
gains through competition.125
Some progress has been made in this area in recent years, according to the OECD’s
Indicators of Product Market Regulation, which tracks the openness of regulatory policy on
a scale of 0 (most open) to 6 (least open). Even throughout the economic crisis, this index for
European countries fell from an average of 1.45 in 2008 to 1.33 in 2013. The main reasons
Services covered are distributive trades, including retail and wholesale; regulated professions (e.g., legal
and tax advisers, architects, engineers); construction services and crafts; business-related services
(e.g., management consultancy, advertising); tourism and leisure services (e.g., travel agents, sports
centres); installation and maintenance of equipment; information society services (e.g., publishing, news,
programming); accommodation and food services (hotels, restaurants, caterers); training and education
services; rentals and leasing services, including car rental; real estate services; and household support
services (e.g., cleaning, nannies).
121
Directive 2006/123/EC on Services in the Internal Market.
122
Josefa Monteagudo, Aleksander Rutkowski, and Dimitri Lorenzani, The economic impact of the Services
Directive: A first assessment following implementation, European Commission economic paper number 456,
June 2012.
123
Ibid.
Also see Better governance of the Single Market: An assessment accompanying the European
Parliament’s legislative own-initiative report (rapporteur Andreas Schwab MEP), European Added Value
Assessment number 2, 2013, and A single market for growth and jobs: An analysis of progress made and
remaining obstacles in the member states, European Commission, November 2013.
124
A single market for growth and jobs: An analysis of progress made and remaining obstacles in the member
states, European Commission, November 2013.
125
Ibid.
120
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
93
. for this decline were a reduction in the administrative burden on starting a new business
and a decline in the complexity of regulatory procedures.126 Nevertheless, Europe still lags
significantly behind the United States, which was already scoring as low as 1.11 in 2008
(Exhibit 56).127
Exhibit 55
European countries that have high compliance with the EU Services Directive had higher services productivity
growth from 2002 to 2012
Nordics
Continental Europe
United Kingdom
and Ireland
Southern Europe
Baltics
Central and
Eastern Europe
Services1 productivity growth, 2002–122
Compound annual growth rate, %
3.0
Bulgaria
2.5
Czech Republic
Poland
2.0
United Kingdom
Greece
Ireland
Denmark
1.5
Slovakia
1.0
France
Netherlands
Hungary
0.5
Sweden
Portugal
Finland
Belgium
0
Germany
Austria
-0.5
-1.0
Spain
Italy
-1.5
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
22
24
26
28
30
Number of infringement cases in service sector, 2002–12
1 Private services only (NACE G–K) excluding education, health care, and social services (NACE L, M, N, O) due to value-added measurement difficulties.
2 Calculated as growth of value created by sector development relative to the numbers of hours input. Not Fisher chain-weighted. Trend triangulated and
verified with EU KLEMS and Eurostat value-added data.
SOURCE: IHS value-added data; Eurostat; European Commission; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
OECD, Indicators of Product Market Regulation. The GDP-weighted average product-market regulation
for 2013 is for the EU-28 plus Norway and Switzerland.
The 2008 average excludes non-OECD members
(Bulgaria, Croatia, Cyprus, Latvia, Lithuania, Malta, Romania) as no data are available.
127
Data collected at five-year intervals; 2013 data are extrapolated for the United States.
126
94
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. Exhibit 56
Europe has gradually liberalised product market regulation—even during the economic
crisis—but significant variations persist among countries
OECD Product Market Regulation Index
Economy-wide regulation (0 = least regulated; 6 = most regulated)
3.5
3.0
Poland
2.5
France
2.0
EU1
1.5
Germany
1.0
United Kingdom
Average product market regulation in Europe
fell from 2.1 in 1998 to 1.33 in 2013
0.5
United States2
0
1998
2000
2003
2008
2013
1 GDP-weighted average. Due to the absence of historical data on product-market regulation, excludes Bulgaria, Croatia,
Cyprus, Latvia, Lithuania, Malta, and Romania before 2013. Excludes Slovenia before 2008. Excludes Luxembourg and
Slovakia before 2003.
2 2013 data for the United States not available.
SOURCE: OECD Indicators of Product Market Regulation
Many European countries effectively grant monopolies to professionals in certain sectors
through regulations that erect high barriers to entry.
For example, by limiting the number
of licenced pharmacies within their jurisdiction and granting exclusive rights to the sale of
medicinal products, most European countries reduce consumer choice and the supply
of service providers (for example, by preventing the sale of “over-the-counter” products
in supermarkets). Similarly, attempts to protect consumers by banning advertising and
marketing (by, for instance, notaries in France and Spain, and pharmacies in Greece)
restrict competition and the potential for growth in these sectors. Moreover, the practice of
implementing price ceilings or floors for certain professions (such as architects and lawyers
in Germany and Greece) aimed at ensuring service quality and preventing overcharging in
reality remove incentives to improve efficiency.128
The restrictions are arguably most severe in the case of regulated professions such as
lawyers and accountants.
The number of licensed professions varies greatly within Europe,
from 45 in Estonia to 395 in the Czech Republic.129 There is thus significant potential to
further generate productivity gains by reducing some of the barriers faced by those in
regulated professions.
Many of the countries hit hardest by the economic crisis, including Greece, Italy, Portugal,
and Spain, have made good progress in opening up competition in professional services
over the past five years. However, in Belgium and Hungary, for instance, which were
already lagging behind others in this respect, there has been no progress. Indeed, Hungary
has gone in the opposite direction with the introduction of more restrictive educational
requirements in the architecture and engineering professions.130
Beyond austerity: A path to economic growth and renewal in Europe, McKinsey Global Institute,
October 2010.
129
Regulated professions in Hungary include bartenders, nail beauticians, and solarium owners.
130
OECD, Indicators of Product Market Regulation.
Data on professional services are disaggregated under
sector regulation.
128
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
95
. The potential for greater competition and productivity is not limited to regulated professions.
Construction is a large sector in Europe, accounting for 5 percent of GDP, but it has suffered
from prolonged stagnation in productivity. The high labour intensity and fragmentation of the
construction industry hinder the diffusion of organisational best practice and standardised
processes.131 Standardisation in the industry overall is rather low and varies significantly
among countries. For example, Finland’s use of standardised pre-fabricated materials
in residential projects is seven times that of Denmark. Failing to capture the benefits of
economies of scale associated with greater standardisation hampers Danish firms’ ability to
compete internationally and hurts the sector’s productivity in that country.132
By contrast, the United Kingdom enjoyed one of the highest productivity-growth rates
in construction in Europe of 1.7 percent over the period 1995 to 2005.
Its “Achieving
Excellence in Construction” initiative is just one example of its innovative approach. The
initiative launched a series of demonstration projects that integrated a range of best practice,
including switching to a focus on life-cycle project costs instead of lowest initial offer prices
and implementing clear cost transparency and cost-effectiveness measurements. In 2009,
these demonstration projects had nearly double the productivity of the industry average
while delivering more predictable construction times and project costs.133
Swedish retail
41%
above average
European
productivity growth
1993–2007
The retail sector is another prime example of the potential to boost productivity through
targeted government action.
The Swedish retail sector enjoys a remarkable productivity
advantage, outperforming the European average by 41 percent between 1993 and 2007.
One key reason for this was an amendment to the country’s Planning and Building Act in
1993 that required municipalities to take greater account of the competitive situation in
decisions to award licences to retailers. By easing zoning restrictions and facilitating the
growth of out-of-town superstores, the average size of new food-retail outlets doubled
between 1990 and 2000. These larger stores were able to take advantage of scale in
purchasing, supply-chain and store management, and marketing.
Advances in the use of
IT improved supply-chain, assortment, and inventory management are also best-practice
examples that other European countries could emulate.134
Completing the integration of Europe’s transport networks
Another vital service sector with significant potential for improvement is transport. Achieving
an integrated and competitive market in transport is important not only because this
would boost the sector’s productivity but also because it would enable the integration of
other sectors.
European authorities have made efforts to deepen the integration of transport in seven
areas: expanding an internal market for rail services; completing the single European sky;
developing the capacity and quality of airports; putting in place a maritime “blue belt”
(reduced or simplified customs procedures in ports); ensuring that there is a sustainable
framework for inland navigation of waterways; taking action on road freight; and putting
forth an initiative on e-freight (automation of the freight transport process through electronic
information). Recent emphasis has been on rail and aviation, for which the European
Commission launched major initiatives in 2013—the Single European Sky 2+ and the Fourth
Railway Package.
Beyond austerity: A path to economic growth and renewal in Europe, McKinsey Global Institute,
October 2010.
132
Creating economic growth in Denmark through competition, McKinsey & Company, November 2010.
133
Beyond austerity: A path to economic growth and renewal in Europe, McKinsey Global Institute,
October 2010.
134
Ibid; Growth and renewal in the Swedish economy: Development, current situation and priorities for the future,
McKinsey Global Institute, May 2012.
131
96
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. While member states have been quick to transpose the seven Single Market directives
on transport into national statute books, there is still some way to go to achieve full
implementation of the legislation. The market remains significantly fragmented along
national boundaries.
The biggest gaps remain in rail, where national monopolies and a lack of transparency in
public tenders limit cross-border competition.135 State-owned players dominate the sector,
which prevents the development of competitive intensity. In France and Italy, for instance,
incumbents hold a market share of more than 80 percent in rail freight although their shares
were previously even higher. The passenger rail sector also remains mostly a closed shop
with the exception of the United Kingdom, which holds competitive tenders for the provision
of all regional rail services; Sweden, which holds competitive tenders for all regional rail
services that cannot be profitable in a free market, with all others fully open; and Denmark
and Germany, which require tendering for at least some lines.
However, there is still a
tendency to underinvest in rail infrastructure. Projects often require complex government
permissions and long planning processes that can delay or even cancel large-scale
projects. Differing technical standards for signalling systems, power, and track gauges also
hamper cross-border operations.
Market opening has been more successful in road freight, but even in this case there are
still restrictions.
For example, “cabotage” restrictions limit access to national road-haulage
markets. This leads to an unnecessarily high number of empty return trips for non-resident
hauliers.136 Moreover, truck sizes still differ among countries, meaning that goods have to
be reloaded at borders. The use of swap bodies—standardised road-freight containers—
instead of lorries or truck trailers facilitates the use of longer, more productive vehicles (albeit
at a cost to the flexibility of loads).
Swap bodies are also easily transferrable from a road
tractor to a train, leading to greater integration. Longer, modular trucks such as those used
in Scandinavia would also increase productivity (but at the expense, opponents argue, of
increased accidents and road wear).
Productivity in the road-freight industry is also hampered by the high degree of
fragmentation, with a large number of small operators lacking the advantages that come
with scale. One reason for this is the high level of self-employment in the sector and its
related “self-exploitation” circumventing labour regulation (the self-employed working more
than would be allowed if they were employees), keeping small and less efficient players in
the business.
In 14 countries for which data are available, 59 percent of companies in the
sector have fewer than 20 employees.137 This fragmentation bears down on productivity.
Larger companies employing more people have the advantage of smaller overheads per
driver and can decrease the share of empty trucks through improved planning systems to
reduce idle time and through more substantial investments in IT.
Fostering the digital single market
Europe would also benefit from an integrated pan-European digital market. The European
Commission made creating a single digital market a priority in 2012, and action on this
front has picked up. Since 2011, 14 directives have been adopted on key areas such as
harmonising consumer rights, electronic identification, value-added taxes, and digital
content rights, and have tended to be transposed by member states.
However, some
barriers to a truly integrated digital economy remain.
A single market for growth and jobs: An analysis of progress made and remaining obstacles in the member
states, European Commission, November 2013.
136
Ibid.
137
Employment in goods road transport enterprises 2011 data from Eurostat.
135
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
97
. Every
10%
increase in
broadband
penetration adds
0.6–
0.7%
to GDP
Some European countries—particularly in Central and Eastern Europe—lag behind
on high-speed broadband penetration, and the uptake of mobile broadband has been
hampered in many nations due to insufficient investment in the enabling networks. There
is already a significant body of evidence that demonstrates the positive impact of access
to broadband on stimulating economic growth. Cross-country analysis of the effects of
broadband penetration suggests a 0.6 to 0.7 percent boost to GDP for every 10 percent
of additional penetration.138 This boost includes direct effects (for example, investment in
infrastructure, increased availability and penetration of services, and increased employment
in the ICT sector) as well as indirect effects such as productivity benefits, job creation
in related sectors, e-government benefits, improved health-care provision, and gains in
energy efficiency.
Mobile networks still tend to be national and fragmented, as revealed by wide price
differences among countries. Average phone call prices in 2011 ranged from less than
two euro cents per minute in Lithuania to almost 15 cents per minute in the Netherlands.139
Similar differences apply in flat-rate packages, with the cheapest offer in Austria costing less
than a quarter of the most expensive offer in Germany.
Online commercial activity, too, remains national in nature.
A 2013 Eurobarometer survey
on the barriers to digital trade suggests that, for a significant proportion of Europeans,
there is some way to go before they are comfortable participating in the online marketplace.
Only 45 percent of those surveyed had made an online purchase within the preceding 12
months, and most of those purchases were made within the consumer’s home country.
In essence, there are still large numbers of people who do not see the attraction of online
purchasing—37 percent of those who had never made an online purchase simply preferred
to buy in bricks-and-mortar shops, while 33 percent said they don’t need to shop online.
However, there is also a lack of confidence in e-commerce as a medium, particularly when
purchasing from abroad. While the share of respondents who encountered problems with
e-commerce is the same for domestic and cross-border purchases, in the latter case
respondents were significantly more uncertain whether products would be delivered and
concerned about whether they would be reimbursed when the products were returned.
Shipping costs were a much more important barrier to cross-border purchases than to
domestic online purchases.140
For providers, too, there are barriers to cross-border online activities. The management
of digital content and royalties is highly fragmented.
Currently, there are more than 250
content-management organisations (CMOs) in the EU that license copyrighted material and
collect royalties for the right holders they represent, typically on a national basis. In the music
sector alone, 25 CMOs, many of them acting as national monopolies, cover 27 countries;
in the United States, by contrast, only three CMOs cover the entire country. Moreover,
European countries have different value-added tax regimes, digital payment structures,
e-identification systems, and data protection rules, all of which complicate cross-border
digital trade.
Scott C.
Beardsley et al., “Fostering the economic and social benefits of ICT”, in Global information technology
report 2009–2010, Soumitra Dutta and Irene Mia, eds., World Economic Forum, March 2010.
139
European Commission press release, August 6, 2013.
140
Internal market, Special Eurobarometer 398, European Commission, October 2013. The concerns about data
protection and payment security were comparable between domestic and cross-border purchases.
138
98
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
Initiatives to change the game
Taken together, the further deepening of the Single Market and the boost to competition
in the service sector from the measures outlined have the potential to increase annual
European growth by up to 0.43 percentage points. If all countries implemented the Services
Directive to the level of the five leading countries in each sector—which comes close to the
elimination of all restrictions covered by the Services Directive—0.14 percentage points
could be added to annual GDP over ten years, according to estimates prepared for the
European Commission.141 Adopting best practice in competition and market integration
for the regulated professions and other local service sectors could add a further 0.29
percentage points in annual growth.
Creating an integrated digital sector is also a vital lever. According to an analysis by the
European Parliamentary Research Service, this could boost annual GDP growth by
0.4 percent a year over the course of a decade.142 We do not include the estimate here due
to possible overlap with other initiatives such as innovation. Since transport accounts for a
much smaller share of GDP, the impact of creating an integrated transport market comes
mostly from enabling productivity growth in other areas.
The European Commission has
made extensive recommendations on how to achieve a true internal market.143 We second
these efforts. But countries can also go beyond the spirit and letter of EU Single Market
legislation and be bolder in unlocking productivity growth in these critical sectors:
ƒƒ Dismantle remaining barriers to competitive service provision, and fully
implement the EU Services Directive. Many European countries need to redouble
their efforts to foster a truly competitive market in services, and to make the EU Services
Directive a reality.
Many de facto barriers to competitive service provision, such as
lengthy registration procedures or complex national regulations, remain in place. These
barriers should be removed, especially in regulated professions. Other sector restrictions
should also be examined, including limits on opening times in retail as well as zoning laws
that cap store size and density.
The dissemination of best practice and the promotion of
common industry standards can also boost productivity. Broadly speaking, Denmark,
Sweden, and the United Kingdom have led the way in eliminating barriers to competitive
service provision and experienced higher productivity growth than the European average
as a result. Yet even these countries may have significant untapped growth potential that
would come from a more complete single market in services.
ƒƒ Enhance the competitiveness and integration of the European transport network.
Despite ongoing efforts to create a single market for transport, significant barriers to
competition remain in the form of differing regulatory and technical standards that limit
interoperability.
The road-freight business remains highly fragmented. In rail, incumbents
still dominate the market in many European countries, despite efforts at liberalisation.
More needs to be done at the national level to enable cross-border operations and
create a truly integrated market. The economies of Continental Europe are relatively well
connected to each other.
Reflecting this, Germany and the Netherlands led the EU’s
Single Market scoreboard on transport in 2014. Each of these countries has transposed
all EU directives in this area. The Netherlands and Nordic EU countries enjoy higher
transport-sector productivity than other countries, partly reflecting the fact that these
economies allow larger, 60-ton trucks on their roads.
Josefa Monteagudo, Aleksander Rutkowski, and Dimitri Lorenzani, The economic impact of the Services
Directive: A first assessment following implementation, European Commission economic paper number 456,
June 2012.
142
Joseph Dunne, Mapping the costs of non-Europe, 2014–19, European Parliamentary Research Service,
March 2014.
143
A single market for growth and jobs: An analysis of progress made and remaining obstacles in the member
states, European Commission, November 2013.
141
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
99
.
ƒƒ Build ICT infrastructure and enhance consumer and intellectual-property
protection. Europe needs to ensure that its ICT infrastructure is adequate and that its
telecommunications market is as fully integrated and competitive as possible. This can
be achieved by ensuring adequate access to high-quality broadband across Europe,
allowing further cross-border competition and consolidation, making available sufficient
wireless spectrum (for example, through pan-European frequency auctions), and
implementing regulation that is conducive to greater competition and the extension
of networks. Nordic countries and the United Kingdom lead Europe on telecoms
infrastructure and broadband penetration.
However, expanding the use of the Internet
for commercial purposes will also require improved consumer awareness of their rights
and obligations online. Therefore, it will be important to clarify and harmonise consumer
protection, guarantees, and reimbursement rules for customers across Europe, and to
create a clear system for recourse for consumers across European national borders.
Another useful step would be to simplify intellectual property rights and royalty structures
for content providers through, for instance, a single entry point, licensing system, and
collective management of intellectual property and royalties for the EU.144
As proposed by the February 2014 European Commission directive on collective management of copyright
and related rights and multiterritorial licensing.
144
100
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
7. PUBLIC-SECTOR PRODUCTIVITY
One UK study says
public-sector
productivity
2000–10 grew
0%
1.4%
vs.
in private sector
The public sector delivers vital services to citizens and is a key component in a wellfunctioning society. Its productivity is particularly important in Europe—even more so at a
time of significant fiscal pressures—because the public sector accounts for 26 percent of
GDP and public transfers account for an additional 22 percent of GDP. Measuring publicsector productivity is notoriously difficult, but the evidence available suggests it is weak
and broadly static.
Among the key measures that should be considered are fostering
competitive conditions in the public sector wherever possible, creating dedicated bodies
within the public sector with a mandate to drive productivity improvements, redoubling
efforts to improve the measurement of productivity in order to establish accountability and
enable progress to be tracked, and pursuing ways of pooling procurement and resources.145
Stepping up productivity growth to 1.4 percent in those parts of the public sector amenable
to a measure of competition could yield additional real GDP growth of 0.15 percent a year.
Where Europe stands
Europe’s public sector (output and transfers) is very large compared with those of other
economies. For instance, government consumption in Japan accounts for only 19 percent
of annual GDP.
Yet most attempted calculations of Europe’s public-sector productivity suggest that it
is static or has even slightly dropped in recent times (Exhibit 57). According to one UK
measure, the productivity of the public sector was static between 2000 and 2010, a period
during which the private sector increased its productivity by 1.4 percent a year.146 Ambitious
efforts are under way to develop an effective measurement method of public-sector
productivity, but it remains very difficult because the nature of the sector’s output, which
often lacks a market price, means that there is still only a broad indication of trends.
In the
absence of a methodology for calculating value added, many measurements assume that
input equals output for public services.
The task ahead will vary according to the specific characteristics of the public sector in
different European countries. The size of Europe’s public sectors ranges widely (Exhibit 58).
In 2012, government investment and consumption ranged from 18 percent of GDP in
Slovakia to 38 percent in Denmark.147 Even among the continent’s largest economies,
significant variation is evident, In the United Kingdom and France, for example, direct
government consumption as a share of GDP was approximately ten percentage points
higher than in Germany in 2012.
Governments also differ significantly in how much they spend on different priorities such as
social protection and defence, and the type of spending (for example, the compensation
for employees compared with investment) (Exhibit 59). Some examples illustrate these
variations.
Greece spends 14 percent of GDP on general public services compared with the
European average of 6 percent. Germany spends 2 percent of GDP on social protection,
one-quarter of Denmark’s 8 percent. How public-sector programmes are designed
McKinsey & Company and the McKinsey Global Institute have published extensively on the topic of publicsector productivity.
For instance, see Better for less: Improving public sector performance on a tight budget,
McKinsey & Company, July 2011, and The public-sector productivity imperative, McKinsey Public Sector
Practice, March 2011.
146
With no price for the output of the public sector, there is no quantifiable value added. For this reason,
most measurements of public-sector productivity assume that output is equal to inputs, resulting in zero
productivity growth by definition.
147
These figures do not include transfers and subsidies, which are not directly consumed by the government
and thus not directly affected by public-sector productivity. However, the mechanisms by which transfers and
subsidies are distributed can be a source of efficiency gains, especially in systems rife with leakages.
See, for
example, From poverty to empowerment: India’s imperative for jobs, growth, and effective basic services,
McKinsey Global Institute, February 2014.
145
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
101
. typically has a major impact on the amount of resources they absorb. For instance, in
Germany’s health-care system, the majority of costs are covered by public and private
health insurance providers. This means that government outlays amount to only 1 percent
of GDP. Meanwhile, the government-funded National Health Service in the United Kingdom
accounts for 8 percent of GDP.
Such differences mean that it is not possible to use spending
as a percentage of GDP as a proxy for productivity. The scope, quantity, and quality of
services delivered have to be taken into account.
Exhibit 57
The public sector accounts for 26 percent of European GDP, but one experimental measure finds
its productivity was flat during the 2000s
Public-sector share of final consumption,
Europe-30, 2012
% of GDP
Productivity development by sector in the United Kingdom1
Private
consumption via
public transfers
120
Gross value added, labour productivity
Index: 100 = 2000
Compound
annual growth
rate, 2000–10
%
Private
Private
115
22
1.4
110
51
Public
26
105
100
Public
0
95
2000
2005
2010
1 Measuring public-sector productivity is very difficult due to the nature of the sector’s output, which often lacks a market price. In the absence of a
methodology for calculating value added, many value-add measurements assume input=output for public services (thus assuming constant productivity).
The
most sophisticated method to measure public-sector productivity comes from the UK Office for National Statistics, which tracks annual productivity trends by
collecting >100 input data sets (e.g., labour input, capital, purchased services) and comparing this with the change in output (e.g., number of surgeries,
doctor appointments, trained students, children in social care). Health care and education output are adjusted for quality (e.g., mortality, patient surveys,
PISA score). For the remaining ~one-third of spending (police, defence, general), input=output is assumed as the output affects all inhabitants.
NOTE: Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
SOURCE: Eurostat; UK Office for National Statistics; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
102
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. Exhibit 58
Government consumption among European countries varies from 18 to 38 percent of national GDP
Government spending in selected Europe-30 countries, 2012
% of GDP
59
Transfers and
subsidies
(Not consumed by the
government and
therefore excluded
from analysis of publicsector productivity)
57
53
21
38
Government
investment and
consumption
Direct consumption by
general government
7
3
10
Other
49
48
23
16
Procurement
32
30
38
11
7
7
2
2
5
12
11
17
29
18
Compensation
45
22
12
Government
investment
42
27
3
6
13
26
6
20
25
7
25
20
5
18
6
4
6
2
5
2
11
9
8
7
2
7
5
Denmark United
(maximum) Kingdom
Total government
investment and
consumption
€ billion
x2
Greece
France
Europe30
Poland
Germany
Slovakia
(minimum)
93
58
596
3,653
97
523
13
615
NOTE: Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
SOURCE: Eurostat; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
103
. Exhibit 59
The composition of government consumption varies hugely among countries, especially in
general services, health care, and social protection
Government spending (less transfers and subsidies) in Europe-30 countries, 2012
% of GDP
38
Other
2
1
1
Defence
Public order and safety
8
Social protection
2
Economic affairs
7
Health care
32
30
1
3
2
2
2
2
1
3
4
2
26
2
3
2
3
3
4
3
1
2
3
4
4
7
6
6
1
2
2
4
3
9
6
6
20
2
1
2
2
18
3
1
2
1
2
11
3
11
5
5
14
General public services
x2
25
3
3
2
8
Education
29
4
6
6
4
6
5
Denmark United
(maximum) Kingdom
Total government
investment and
consumption
€ billion
Greece
France
Europe30
Poland
Germany
Slovakia
(minimum)
93
58
596
3,653
97
523
13
615
1 In some countries, health care is managed privately but funded to some extent by government transfers or subsidies, excluded in this exhibit.
NOTE: Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
SOURCE: Eurostat; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Because policy design and delivery have a major bearing on productivity in the public sector,
a systemic view is necessary. Labour productivity, the typical measure of productivity in the
private sector, is only one factor affecting the public sector’s ability to deliver value for money
(Exhibit 60). In the public sector, factors such as an evidence-based approach to policy,
a clear definition of the boundary between public and private tasks, and sound financial
management are all just as important determinants of government efficiency.
104
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
Exhibit 60
Labour productivity is only one factor affecting the public sector’s ability to deliver value for money
Examples
Define the scope,
objectives, and
priorities of
government
Policy design
Refine policy
and regulatory
framework
Achieve
government
objectives
Improve government
performance given
chosen scope,
objectives, and
priorities
Set public-, privatesector boundaries
Define policy
interventions and
tools
Defining the respective
roles of the public and
private sectors
Thorough economic
analysis of alternative
policy options, e.g., in
carbon abatement or
public health
Productivity
Increase productivity
through higher
quality and
efficiency1
Policy delivery
Improve delivery
of public services
within given policy
framework
Lean techniques that can
produce simultaneous
improvements in outputs,
customer service, job
satisfaction, and cost
efficiency
Financial
management
Lower cost of
government inputs
Reduce financial
leakage
Adoption of best practice
in procurement
Reducing fraud and
error in tax, through
prioritisation of cases
for audit
1 While the OECD’s definition of efficiency implicitly includes quality improvements, we include them explicitly because they are a large, yet often overlooked,
component of productivity improvements.
SOURCE: OECD; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
A large body of evidence has demonstrated that competition is an important driver of
productivity. Productivity growth has consistently been higher in market sectors with higher
competitive intensity than in monopolistic or tightly regulated markets. If that evidence
is applied to the public sector, where there is typically little internal competition and few
productivity-enhancing mechanisms, indications of low productivity are unsurprising.
Therefore, one way to achieve improved public-sector productivity is to develop an element
of competition. In many functions, introducing competition through private alternatives to
public-service providers would be neither beneficial nor plausible due to the nature of the
service.
Yet, there are many ways to introduce “competition-like” mechanisms other than
through outright privatisation or introducing private alternatives. Concentrating on creating
conditions that foster a competitive attitude and setting up institutional capabilities focused
on driving productivity improvements can help governments get closer to private-sector
efficiency levels.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
105
. We find that there are five broad characteristics of competition that relate to accountability
and institutional capacity (Exhibit 61). Specific approaches are competitive benchmarking,
increased transparency of quality and rights, dedicated delivery units, improved handling of
sub-contracts, and an increased focus on performance within organisations. Examples can
be found of each approach being pursued successfully within Europe; the challenge is to
spread such best practice more widely and consistently.
Exhibit 61
There are five characteristics of competition that the public sector can leverage
to unlock productivity growth
Characteristics of competition
Accountability
NOT EXHAUSTIVE
Examples of potential public-sector interventions
Degree of customer
“satisfaction” with service
that the organisation
provides
Competitive benchmarking
ï‚§ Create indirect competition by benchmarking similar
units
ï‚§ Introduce alternatives and let customers choose
supplier
Reputational
Societal expectations of
performance enabled
through clear standards
and targets
Quality and rights transparency
ï‚§ Define clear customers’ rights that service providers
are accountable to
ï‚§ Leverage data technologies to make performance
and quality transparent for customers when
choosing suppliers
Structure
Organisation designed to
promote a culture of
performance
Dedicated delivery unit
ï‚§ Establish a centralised group to track and enable
productivity enhancements through metric design,
prioritisation, and monitoring
Processes
Improved sub-contract execution
Ability to leverage
ï‚§ Tender multiyear execution contracts, with clear
technology and lean
management to streamline
performance targets coupled to incentive schemes
processes
People
Institutional
capacity
Transactional
Sufficient resources
invested in hiring people
with right capabilities and
retaining talent
Performance-focused organisation
ï‚§ Focus on recruiting talent that is motivated to boost
productivity in the public sector across all levels of
the organisation
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute analysis
One example of the power of accountability to drive productivity in the public sector is the
Programme for International Student Assessment (PISA), the OECD’s comparative study of
educational outcomes that was launched in 2000. This initiative transformed educational
attainment in Germany by providing transparency on its performance.
PISA revealed
that Germany lagged behind the OECD average on reading, mathematics, and science.
Germany also had the highest educational inequality (measured as the correlation between
educational outcome and socioeconomic background) of any country in the OECD. These
poor readings triggered a vigorous national debate—the PISA shock—that galvanised
rapid reform. By 2009, Germany had boosted its ranking in reading from 21 to 16 and in
mathematics from 22 to 10, largely reflecting improved performance among disadvantaged
students.
Even more impressively, these gains were achieved without an increase in
spending on education. To the contrary, spending as a percentage of GDP fell slightly to
4.0 percent in 2008 from 4.1 percent in 2000.
Europe also boasts examples of institutions driving public-sector productivity. In 2008,
Sweden was facing an influx of refugees from Afghanistan and Iraq.
In response, the
Swedish Migration Agency streamlined its operations and improved the quality of the
106
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. services it provided by using lean-management principles and developing the capabilities
of its employees.148 The agency identified and supported “change agents” whose job was to
transfer skills and knowledge throughout the organisation. The result of these initiatives was
a fall in the average time it took to process an application from 270 days to 105, generating
savings of more than €100 million. The focus on the quality of the workforce also led to more
accurate decisions on applications, demonstrated by a decline in successful appeals from
5 percent to 3 percent.
Initiatives to change the game
It is not easy to measure the precise impact of the introduction of competition-like
mechanisms. However, our analysis suggests that this approach, effectively implemented,
would enable the public sector to close much of the gap with private-sector productivity
growth, potentially generating incremental GDP growth of 0.15 percent per annum.
We
acknowledge that not all parts of the public sector are amenable to such measures. In our
estimate of the potential impact on GDP growth, we therefore assume faster productivity
growth only for the 41 percent of public-sector final expenditure devoted to compensation—
approximately 11 percent of Europe’s GDP. Our estimate is only an approximation at
best.
Governments may already have achieved productivity improvements that have not
been measured, and not all mechanisms can be implemented effectively in each country.
With these caveats, initiatives in four areas could help to change the game in Europe’s
public sector:
Dutch health
websites led to
insurance
switching rate of
4–6%
ƒƒ Create conditions for competition in the provision of public services where
possible. Governments can all too easily become complacent about the quality of
services when citizens cannot choose their providers. Introducing choice is not possible
in all parts of the public sector, but where it is possible—say, a choice of doctor or
school—choice can be a powerful incentive for providers to become more productive.
The introduction of regulated competition in health care in the Netherlands increased
choice and improved the efficiency of hospitals.
The Netherlands replaced its dual
system of mandatory health insurance and voluntary private insurance with mandatory
private insurance for all in a bid to address long-standing criticisms. The new system
emphasised controlling health-care spending, increasing consumer choice, raising
effectiveness and quality, guaranteeing accessibility, and stimulating innovation.
Between 2006 and 2009, hospital prices fell and the volume of treatments increased
considerably. The launch of websites with price and quality information on insurers led to
a switching rate of 4 to 6 percent, and hospital productivity grew by 2.9 percent between
2003 and 2008.
Competition also harmonised the standard of care across the country—
variations among hospitals decreased in both the length of stay and the price of care.149
ƒƒ Set up an internal stakeholder to identify, advocate for, and potentially implement
productivity-enhancing initiatives. Efforts to improve public-sector productivity are
often hampered by the fact that no single government stakeholder “owns” the problem
and is accountable for setting it right. This argues for new organisations with a remit to
focus on improving productivity.
These organisations need to have the political clout and
the right incentives, and they need to be held accountable for results. In 2010, the United
Kingdom set up an Efficiency and Reform Group within the central government as part
of the Cabinet Office. The unit works jointly with HM Treasury and other government
departments to identify and deliver savings, focusing on six areas: defining and
implementing spending controls; sharing best practice across government on executing
projects; centralising procurement in selected categories and, in others, disseminating
See Transforming government performance through lean management, McKinsey Center for Government,
December 2012.
149
Ilaria Mosca, “Evaluating reforms in the Netherlands’ competitive health insurance system”, Eurohealth,
volume 18, number 3, January 2012.
148
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
107
.
best practice; managing the government’s property portfolio; developing commercial
models for delivering services; and promoting a mindset of “digital by default”. The unit
achieved savings—reviewed and verified by an auditor—of £14.3 billion in the fiscal year
2013–14 compared with a 2009–10 baseline forecast, equivalent to around 2 percent
of total government spending. Examples of the savings that resulted from the group’s
efforts include £2.4 billion saved from reducing the size of the civil service, £1.5 billion
from the centralisation of purchasing of common goods and services, £0.8 billion from
higher efficiency in construction projects, £0.5 billion from lower real estate costs by
vacating, renting, or consolidating underused properties, and £0.2 billion from moving
many government transactions online.
ƒƒ Launch a productivity-measurement programme and publish results that
establish accountability. Without a comprehensive way to measure public-sector
productivity, government agencies can avoid being held accountable by citizens.
They
may be attempting to improve value for money in the services that they deliver, but it
is virtually impossible to assess whether they are doing so successfully. Mechanisms
such as published scorecards are not a perfect solution, but they are useful because
they can track input and output metrics over time that show taxpayers how their
money is being spent and can also enable governments themselves to assess the
effectiveness of initiatives. It is important that these scorecards are published for specific
departments within a government to establish accountability.
In France, then-President
Nicolas Sarkozy put in place a General Review of Public Policies in 2007, aimed at
making significant cuts to public spending and boosting the effectiveness of existing
spending.150 A central piece of this effort was a customer-centric barometer that tracked
indicators based on customer expectations developed through focus groups. An annual
report monitors progress on 450 initiatives across all 18 ministries. Since the launch,
there has been very significant progress.
Accident and emergency waiting times have
fallen by 28 percent. The civil service has 100,000 fewer employees through the simple
mechanism of not replacing one of every two retirees. Over the past three years, the
government has saved €10 billion—lowering its payroll by €3 billion, reducing operating
expenses by €2 billion, and saving €5 billion through more efficient processes.
Consolidation of
medical
procurement in
Norway cut
costs by
62%
ƒƒ Implement joint purchasing and pooling of resources.
Although Europe is one
of the world’s largest economies, its governance and operations are fragmented
among its many separate countries, and this means that many government activities
are subscale in efficiency terms. Leveraging Europe’s huge size and its degree of
political integration could greatly improve the productivity of numerous operations.
This is especially true in public procurement, as consolidating procurement processes
strengthens governments’ bargaining positions and thereby lowers costs. In Norway,
national consolidation of the procurement of medical consumables reduced the average
cost for the same or similar goods by 62 percent.
Government activities can even be
consolidated on a pan-European scale. As a first step, the European Commission
has put in place EU-level procurement of pandemic vaccines and other strategic
supplies. Another area with significant savings potential is defence—development and
maintenance fixed costs are particularly high in this sector, and the use of defence
equipment remains highly fragmented among member states.
As illustration, there are
154 main weapon systems in the EU-28 compared with 27 in the United States, leading
to higher costs for all. Steps towards an integrated European defence policy clearly
require common objectives, careful analysis of scenarios and equipment needs, and
a strong political mandate. Notwithstanding the challenges, by pooling resources and
joint purchasing, Europe could potentially save more than 30 percent on its military
equipment budget.
Karim Tadjeddine, “‘A duty to modernize’: Reforming the French civil service”, McKinsey Quarterly, April 2011.
150
108
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. 8. FURTHER OPENNESS TO TRADE
Europe had
13%
share of global
goods and services
trade in 2012,
higher than the
United States and
China
In the current economic environment of deleveraging and anaemic domestic demand in
Europe, exports have been, and will continue to be, a vital component of the recovery from
recession. But beyond the needs of the short-term recovery, trade is important because the
competition it creates is a strong driver of longer-term productivity gains and helps to shift
economies towards innovative knowledge-intensive sectors. Europe is already the world’s
largest exporting region, but there is scope for trade to play an even larger role in growth.
Excluding intra-European trade flows, the EU’s share in global flows in goods and services
was 13 percent in 2012, higher than the share of China, Japan, or the United States.
The
rising prominence of emerging markets in global trade is a formidable opportunity (and
competitive threat) for European businesses to grow and for consumers to access less
expensive goods and services.
Among the measures that Europe could consider to enhance its trade performance are
agreeing to robust trade agreements with the growth engines of the next decade, namely
China, India, and the United States; improving its trade logistics systems; establishing trade
support networks similar to Germany’s networks of chambers of commerce in destination
countries; and designing policies to offset any adverse effects from trade. Tapping into
greater trade with the China, India, and the United States through these initiatives could
generate 0.08 percent additional annual GDP growth.
Where Europe stands
Europe-30 is the world’s largest exporting region. Excluding intra-European trade flows,
the EU’s share in global flows in goods and commercial services was 13.4 percent in 2012,
exceeding China’s share of 9.9 percent, the US share of 9.7 percent, and Japan’s share of
4.2 percent.
Germany is Europe’s largest trading nation, participating in 3.5 percent of global
trade excluding intra-European trade. It is followed by the United Kingdom with 1.9 percent
of global trade and France with 1.5 percent.
Global trade activity has increased substantially over the past decade, driven by the rise
of emerging markets. Today, roughly one-fifth of all money spent on goods in the global
economy goes on a product shipped across borders, up from one in seven in 1995.
Over this period, the global flow of goods has increased at a rate of 7.7 percent a year
(Exhibit 62).151 The counterpart of increasing participation in global trade by emerging
markets has been a steady decline in Europe’s share of global trade activity.
Yet the growing
presence of emerging economies in international trade makes it even more important
for Europe to be open to the opportunities that they bring. The importance of exports in
Europe-30 GDP has increased substantially, from 12 percent in 2004 to 17 percent in 2012.
Stunning strides have been made by many countries. The economies of the Baltic region
and Central and Eastern Europe have posted remarkable growth in exports, doubling and
tripling over this period to reach 14 percent and 30 percent of their GDP, respectively.
Overall, the EU has historically imported more than it exports, but the region ran a trade
surplus for the first time in 2013.
Strong surpluses with countries such as the United States
and Turkey more than offset significant deficits with countries like China and Russia.
Europe’s exports are generally geared towards knowledge-intensive, high-value-added
goods and services, which are traded against primary resources and labour-intensive
goods. Broadly speaking, the EU is a strong net exporter of machinery and equipment,
chemicals, and manufactured goods, and a net importer of crude materials and fuels as well
as of miscellaneous manufactured articles.152
Global flows in a digital age: How trade, finance, people, and data connect the world economy, McKinsey
Global Institute, April 2014.
152
European Commission, Directorate General for Trade.
151
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
109
. However, there are significant differences among European countries and regions.
Continental Europe drives the EU’s impressive overall trade performance. It is a large net
exporter of knowledge-intensive manufacturing. The United Kingdom and Ireland stand
out for their large surpluses in knowledge-intensive services. Overall, Southern Europe
fares less well in knowledge-intensive sectors, but there are signs of improvement.
Italy,
in particular, stands out for its strength in labour-intensive manufactured goods including
apparel and furniture; it is also one of the largest European producers of machinery and
equipment. The Nordic countries run a surplus in capital-intensive manufacturing, notably in
fuel products and capital-intensive crude materials (Exhibit 63).153
Exhibit 62
Global goods trade has increased in both its value and share of GDP since 1995
Nominal values, 1995–2012
$ trillion
Growth of global goods trade
Growth of global services trade
18
Capitalintensive
16
Laborintensive
14
Primary
resources and
commodities
12
10
18
16
14
12
10
8
8
6
6
R&Dintensive
4
2
Transport
4
Travel
2
Other
services
0
0
1995
Share
16
of GDP
%
2000
2005
2012
1995
2000
2005
2012
20
23
24
4
5
5
6
SOURCE: UN Comtrade; IHS; United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD); World Development Indicators, World Bank; McKinsey
Global Institute analysis
Trading myths: Addressing misconceptions about trade, jobs, and competitiveness, McKinsey Global
Institute, May 2012.
153
110
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
Exhibit 63
Continental Europe has a large surplus in knowledge-intensive manufacturing, and
the United Kingdom and Ireland have a large surplus in knowledge-intensive services
Net exports1,2
% of GDP
2009
Continental Europe
Primary resources
United Kingdom
and Ireland
-2.5
-3.5
-1.1
-1.7
0.8
0.9
Capital-intensive
manufacturing
-0.2
-0.2
0.7
1.7
0.1
0.1
2.5
0
3.9
-0.2
-1.1
-0.3
-0.5
1.7
1.7
-0.4
4.6
-0.1
-0.1
1.8
1.8
-0.1
0
-0.1
-0.1
0.1
1.8
Health care, education,
and public services
1.0
-0.6
-0.1
1.4
Knowledge-intensive
services
-1.3
1.5
0.3
0.1
0.1
Capital-intensive
services
-0.7
-0.7
0.1
1.4
-1.5
5.8
Labour-intensive
services
3.8
4.1
0.3
0.8
4.1
Knowledge-intensive
manufacturing
Nordics
-2.8
-4.4
-1.8
-1.7
-0.7
-0.7
Labour-intensive
manufacturing
Southern Europe
2013
0
0
0
0
0
1 Excludes unclassified commodities and confidential trade that may lead to deviations from national accounts data.
2 2013 data were not available for specific services categories for several countries (Finland, Greece, Lithuania, Poland, and Switzerland). In these cases,
2011 data were used. Construction services is not available for Ireland; 2013 data for services from ITC are preliminary.
SOURCE: World Bank World Integrated Trade Solution; ITC Trade Map; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
The continuing rise of emerging markets is a significant growth opportunity for European
businesses and has the potential to create new jobs in knowledge-intensive industries and
services. In the past 25 years, Europe has, for example, benefited from growth in Africa,
which has long relied on Europe as its biggest trading partner.
Trade volumes between the
two regions have grown by 12 percent a year over this period. However, as South-South
trade volumes have increased, Europe’s share of trade with Africa has dropped from around
65 percent to 39 percent.154 Future incremental demand for European exports is likely to be
concentrated in China, India, and the United States, which together are expected to account
for 48 percent of incremental growth in global GDP between 2012 and 2025 (Exhibit 64).
China alone will account for 24 percent of global GDP growth to 2025, although the United
States and India are also of significance with shares of 17 and 7 percent, respectively.
Lions go global: Deepening Africa’s ties to the United States, McKinsey Global Institute, August 2014.
154
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
111
. Exhibit 64
EU preferential trade agreements cover only a fraction of future incremental demand
Global real GDP, 2012 and 2025
2005 $ trillion
2.3
100.7
4.8
2.2
4.0
4.2
2.2
5.7
8.2
67.0
2012
China
United
States
India
Western
Europe
Latin
Middle
America/
East and
Caribbean Africa
% of
increment
24
17
7
12
12
No trade
agreements in place
EU
7
Trade agreements
with 40 countries1
Other
Other
Asia Pacific
14
2025
7
Scarce trade
agreements2, 3
1 Preferential trade agreements with 40 countries including Chile, Colombia, Peru, Mexico, Caribbean members of the African, Caribbean, and Pacific Group of
States (APAC), Algeria, Egypt, Israel, Morocco, Tunisia, and South Africa.
2 Other APAC = South Korea and Papua New Guinea.
3 Other = customs union with Andorra, Monaco, San Marino, and Turkey; European Economic Area with Iceland, Liechtenstein, and Norway; preferential trade
agreements with Albania, Bosnia-Herzegovina, FYR Macedonia, Montenegro, Serbia, and Switzerland.
NOTE: Without consideration of preferential trade agreements currently under negotiation. Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Growth Model; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Europe already maintains strong trading relations with these countries. Being among the
world’s largest economies, China and the United States are Europe’s main trading partners
today. While Europe runs a trade surplus with China and a trade deficit with the United
States, both countries are important sales outlets for European goods; 13.4 percent of EU
exports go to the United States and 7.1 percent to China.
Due to the still relatively small size
of the Indian economy in comparison with the United States and China, the importance of
exports to India for EU companies is still limited at 2.1 percent of exports, but that will grow
along with the size of the Indian market.
Given the strong and growing importance of these outlets for European goods and
services—trade with China, India, and the United States accounts for roughly 4 percent of
Europe’s GDP—it is disappointing that the EU has not concluded free trade agreements with
any of these countries. The volume of EU exports to the United States and China already
exceeds exports to each of the three main existing free trade agreements—the European
Free Trade Association, which includes Iceland, Liechtenstein, Norway, and Switzerland;
112
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
the Euro-Mediterranean Partnership with nine Middle Eastern and North African countries;
and the Customs Union with Turkey. Given slow growth in Europe and the uncertainties
associated with Central Asia and the Middle East, it is increasingly critical that Europe
secures and extends its access to the growth markets in the rest of Asia and the Americas.
Trade in services in the form of tourism from these countries is a particular opportunity for
Europe (see Box 5, “Opportunities from China: Attracting students and tourists”).
European countries are not all equally prepared to seize current trade opportunities. Small
countries in northern and Continental Europe have long been among the world’s most open
economies. In 2013, total exports reached 102 percent of GDP in Ireland, 83 percent in
Belgium, 79 percent in the Netherlands, 55 percent in Austria, and 54 percent in Denmark.
In total, extra-EU exports in 2013 amounted to 24 percent of GDP in the Nordics, 19 percent
in Continental Europe, and 18 percent in the United Kingdom and Ireland.
The Baltic
countries have rapidly internationalised over the past ten years, increasing their extra-EU
exports from 17 percent of GDP to 30 percent. However, extra-EU exports still account for
just 15 percent of GDP in Central and Eastern Europe and in Southern Europe (Exhibit 65).
It is noteworthy that these differences among European economies exist despite their being
subject to the same international trade regimes set by the EU Customs Union.
Box 5. Opportunities from China: Attracting students and tourists
Incomes in developing economies are rising faster and
Europe can further tap into the increasing demand from
at a greater scale than at any previous point in history.
China and other emerging markets by improving on
This trend is driving the growth of the global consuming
the following:
class from 2.4 billion people in 2010 to 4.2 billion in 2025.
ƒƒ Simplify immigration.
Europe can improve its
Chinese households will account for 19 percent of global
accessibility to Chinese tourists and students by
growth in urban households with an annual income of
simplifying the visa application process through a
more than $20,000. The new consumer class is finding its
single online visa application portal. Non-Schengen
way to Europe, primarily as tourists or students.
Between
countries should also consider joining the Schengen
2005 and 2011, the number of arrivals from China almost
area. After Switzerland entered the Schengen area in
doubled from about 1.7 million to roughly 3.1 million.
2008, the number of Chinese visitors more than tripled
The number of inbound students from Asia into Europe
from around 130,000 to more than 450,000 in 2011.
increased to around 300,000 in 2012.
With its rich cultural heritage, Europe is well-positioned
to further benefit from an increasingly travel-oriented
consumer class in China. A top performer in this regard is
Switzerland, which attracted 58 Chinese visitors for every
1,000 Swiss citizens in 2011.
With a share of 35 percent
of the top 100 universities in the world, Europe is also
well-positioned to attract Chinese students. The United
Kingdom, which boasts some of the most prestigious
universities in Europe, attracted more than 76,000
Chinese students in 2012.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
ƒƒ Enable seamless access. Increasing airport capacity
and connectivity with China’s main hubs facilitates
travel into Europe.
Schiphol Airport in the Netherlands
serves six Chinese cities daily and provides several
services to welcome Chinese tourists. For instance, all
Schiphol shops accept Chinese renminbi.
ƒƒ Become an education powerhouse. To attract
more Chinese students, European universities should
intensify their efforts to establish an international
academic reputation in line with that of the United
Kingdom’s cutting-edge institutions and should
market themselves in China more actively.
113
.
Exhibit 65
Extra-European trade corresponds to ~18 percent of European GDP, a share that has been increasing
across all regions of the continent since 2004
Extra-territorial trade, 2004–131
% of GDP
2013
Compound annual
growth rate, 2004–13
%
2004
Canada
36
30
Baltics
12
24
Nordics
20
Australia
18
Continental
Europe
19
Southern
Europe
9
1
5
1
6
1
4
2
7
-1
5
13
18
United Kingdom
and Ireland
Central and
Eastern Europe
1
17
13
9
Exports
17
18
Europe-282
United
States
GDP
29
14
15
10
15
10
1 Export of goods and services.
2 Europe-30 excluding Norway and Switzerland.
SOURCE: Eurostat; UNCTAD; IHS; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
The difference in the export performance of different developed economies is increasingly
explained by the countries’ involvement in global value chains of businesses and the
imports of intermediate goods that this entails. Structural, economy-wide factors such as
geographic location and sector specialisation play a diminishing role.155 Since developing
new markets abroad is an expensive, time-consuming task with high risks and substantial
fixed costs, larger, more productive, and more highly skilled companies are more likely to
export than other companies, irrespective of the country in which they are located.156 For
example, Germany benefits from a high concentration of innovative businesses in the fastgrowing machinery and equipment industry, which contributes to its position as the world’s
top exporter in 2013, running a bigger trade surplus than China.157 In other countries—
particularly in Southern Europe and Central and Eastern Europe—companies are smaller
and less productive on average. Moreover, these regions have a less beneficial sector
Andrea Beltramello, Koen De Backer, and Laurent Moussiegt, The export performance of countries within
global value chains (GVCs), OECD science, technology, and industry working paper number 2012/02,
April 2012.
156
Giorgio Barba Navaretti et al., The global operations of European firms: The second EFIGE policy report,
Bruegel Blueprint Series, volume XII, July 2011; Loris Rubini et al., Breaking down the barriers to firm growth in
Europe: The fourth EFIGE policy report, Bruegel Blueprint Series, volume XVIII, August 2012.
157
This includes exports to other European countries.
155
114
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
composition—companies tend to be specialised in products with slower-growing demand
than their Continental European counterparts.158
Finally, infrastructure also plays a part in enabling or preventing companies' access to
foreign markets. The Continental European trading hubs of Germany, the Netherlands, and
Belgium as well as the United Kingdom topped the World Bank’s Logistics Performance
Index in 2014, while the southern and Central and Eastern European countries lagged
behind; Bulgaria, for instance, ranks 47th.
Preferential trade agreements with China, India,
and the United States could add 0.08 percent to
Europe's real GDP growth.
Initiatives to change the game
Establishing preferential trade relations with China, India, and the United States would
significantly spur export growth, allowing domestic companies to achieve scale and realise
productivity gains while lowering prices for consumers in tradable sectors. The European
Commission estimates that the realisation of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment
Partnership with the United States alone would result in 0.5 percent additional GDP for
Europe, amounting to roughly 0.05 percent additional growth per year in the period to
2025. Scaling this estimate to China and India on the basis of current export volumes, we
estimate that preferential trade agreements with these three growing economies could yield
incremental real GDP growth of 0.08 percent to 2025.
Our analysis suggests that the priorities to consider in the trade arena include:
ƒƒ Agree on robust trade agreements with the growth engines of the next decade:
China, India, and the United States.
The biggest near-term opportunity is concluding
the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership with the United States, which
not only would further integrate the world’s two largest developed markets but could
also establish a framework for future European trade negotiations. Europe has been
negotiating with India on a free trade agreement since 2007 and with China on an
investment agreement since 2013; however, neither has reached a significant degree
of maturity. Even more than is the case with trade in goods, trade in services is still
significantly restricted with these two countries, with tariff equivalents exceeding
60 percent.159 As we have argued, establishing open and fair terms by which firms in
the respective countries can conduct commerce in goods and services will be a critical
determinant of Europe’s growth trajectory to 2025.
ƒƒ Expand an efficient trade logistics ecosystem.
Much of the friction of global trade
can take place before goods or services even leave the country of origin. In addition to
the manufacturing and trading hub of Germany, the Netherlands is an example of how
to minimise the burden on domestic companies by building world-class infrastructure,
streamlining customs procedures, and ensuring that high-quality support services
are available. The Dutch export infrastructure is ranked third in the world after that of
Andrea Beltramello, Koen De Backer, and Laurent Moussiegt, The export performance of countries within
global value chains (GVCs), OECD science, technology, and industry working paper number 2012/02,
April 2012.
159
Trading myths: Addressing misconceptions about trade, jobs, and competitiveness, McKinsey Global
Institute, May 2012.
Also see J. Bradford Jensen, Global trade in services: Fear, facts, and offshoring,
Peterson Institute for International Economics, 2011, and Gary Clyde Hufbauer, Jeffrey J. Schott, and Woan
Foong Wong, “Figuring out the Doha Round”, Policy Analyses in International Economics, number 91,
July 2010.
158
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
115
.
Germany and Singapore on the World Bank’s Logistics Performance infrastructure
sub-index. In 2012, the Port of Rotterdam shipped about twice the bulk cargo and
processed about 30 percent more container shipments than the second-busiest
European port, the Port of Hamburg. Processing about 1.6 million metric tons of cargo in
2013, Amsterdam’s Schiphol airport ranks third in Europe, not far behind Frankfurt and
Paris. Efficient customs procedures place a minimum burden on the conduct of trade.
Exporting requires seven days and $915 per container, lower than the OECD average of
11 days and $1,070.
Finally, the Netherlands boasts high-quality support providers such
as shipping brokers and agents. It ranks fifth in Europe after Finland, Denmark, Austria,
and Germany on the quality of its support services.
ƒƒ Establish support networks in destination countries. For many firms, especially
SMEs, developing new markets abroad is expensive, time-consuming, and risky.
Germany has helped its businesses access foreign markets by establishing a dense
constellation of related organisations at the regional and national levels that pull together
to support businesses and their export aspirations.
These include, for instance,
Germany Trade and Invest, which has more than 50 international representative offices
and a worldwide network of 130 German chambers of commerce around the world—a
system of “coordinated decentralisation”. Germany Trade and Invest acts as a hub and
convenor of entities including national- and regional-level development agencies, and
others. Development agencies based in Germany’s Länder have detailed knowledge
of local businesses and are able to access resources at the national level.
For instance,
KfW, the government-owned development bank, had a credit portfolio of about
€60 billion in export and project finance in 2013. Germany also provides its exporting
firms with export guarantees—the Hermes cover—that protect exporting firms from both
country and buyer risk.
ƒƒ Offset the adverse effects from trade through adequate investments and policies.
While trade promotes longer-term productivity gains and the transition to knowledgeand innovation-driven economies, it can, in the short run, create disadvantaged groups
in labour-intensive industries. Rather than focusing on winning back low-skilled jobs,
European policy makers should prepare their economies and workforces for higherskilled activities.
Promoting world-class education and innovation is critical if Europe
is to build on its comparative advantage in knowledge-intensive goods and sustain
high-skilled job creation. In the short term, Europe should seek to create employment for
those who have been disadvantaged by trade in industries that help improve Europe’s
competitiveness and trade performance in the future. Investment in infrastructure that
improves the access of firms to foreign markets, as well as in energy-efficiency measures
such as the insulation of residential buildings, can create low-skilled employment while
contributing to the improvement of the trade balance of most European countries.160
Trading myths: Addressing misconceptions about trade, jobs, and competitiveness, McKinsey Global
Institute, May 2012
160
116
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. 9. GREY AND FEMALE LABOURFORCE PARTICIPATION
Europe faces the prospect of a shrinking working-age population—those aged between 15
and 64—which, left unaddressed, could dampen GDP growth. One vital element of a gamechanging growth strategy would be boosting participation among groups that are currently
under-represented in the workforce, in particular “grey”—adults aged 55 to 74—and female
workers. Labour-market policies and pension and taxation systems should be geared
towards promoting participation.
Governments and companies need to provide more
support and flexibility for their workers to encourage participation, and remove barriers—
perceived and real—to employment. Finally, everyone needs to be able to access lifelong
learning to ensure that they are, and remain, employable. Stepping up participation in both
groups to best-practice levels by 2025 could boost European GDP growth by 0.39 percent
per annum.
Where Europe stands
Despite improvements over the ten-year period to 2013, female and grey participation rates
of 79 and 35 percent, respectively, continue to lag behind the rate for prime working-age
males, which stands at 91 percent (Exhibit 66).
Narrowing the gap by one-quarter would
result in an additional 19 million workers—an 8 percent increase in the current labour force
of approximately 250 million.
Exhibit 66
Europe has large variations in labour-force participation rates among gender and age groups
Europe-30 labour-force participation rate, 2013
%
91
79
Age
Male
Female
45
15–24
Difference between
male and female
participation
Percentage points
5
40
25–34
91
35–44
93
45–54
90
78
35
Change
-0.1
since 2003
Percentage
points
Female2
4.4
79
63
55–64
Male1
81
47
Grey3
8.2
12
65–74
>75
2
6
1
13
12
11
16
6
1
1 Activity rate of male population aged 25–54.
2 Female workers aged 25–54 to avoid overlap with grey workers.
3 Grey workers defined as aged 55–74.
SOURCE: Eurostat; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
117
. Female workers
Europe has much to celebrate in its effort to expand opportunities for women in the
workforce, but scope remains to do even better. Over four decades, labour-force
participation for females aged 25 to 54 increased from less than 50 percent to 79 percent by
2013, higher than the 74 percent in the United States.161 Moreover, while female participation
in the United States is stagnating, in Europe it continues to increase.
However, variation in female participation within Europe reveals ample scope to boost
participation further. In the Nordics and Baltics, 86 percent of women are part of the labour
force. That is 12 percentage points more than in Southern Europe.
Many women are also
inclined to work more. According to Eurostat, about one-third of women over the age of 15
who are classified as economically “inactive” are willing to work, and almost one-quarter of
female part-timers are willing to work more hours. This finding about part-timers also implies
that there is an opportunity to increase female participation, as 30 percent of European
women in the workforce are currently not working full time (Exhibit 67).
Exhibit 67
Europe has increased female labour-market participation but the incidence of women’s part-time work is
higher than in the United States
Female labour-force participation rate
Female population aged 25–54, %
85
80
Regional variation in Europe, 2013
75
Baltics
86.1
Nordics
85.6
70
65
60
Part-time incidence of
women 25–54, 2013
%
20
Canada
55
50
Europe1
Australia
40
41
United States
45
30
Continental
Europe
82.8
United Kingdom
and Ireland
Central and
Eastern Europe
79.1
77.9
19
Southern
Europe
74.0
35
1970
1980
1990
2000
2013
1 Europe-15 before 1995 due to data availability; remainder is Europe-30 with missing data for Bulgaria, Croatia, and
Malta to 2000 and for Cyprus, Czech Republic, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Romania, and Slovakia to 1997.
SOURCE: OECD; Eurostat; US Bureau of Labor Statistics; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
We focus the discussion on the 25-to-54 age segment to avoid overlap with our analysis of grey labourforce participation.
161
118
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. Female integration into the workforce can be assessed on two dimensions: participation
rates and the average number of hours worked per capita, each relative to the same figures
for men.162 On both, the performance of European countries varies to a significant extent
(Exhibit 68). In many countries, there is a relatively strong degree of parity between men and
women, with many Central and Eastern European countries, as well as Baltic countries,
standing out with high participation. In contrast, female participation rates in Italy and Malta
are only 75 percent and 65 percent, respectively, those of men, with hours worked per
capita for females at about the European average level of 83 percent of hours per capita
for males. Many continental European countries have achieved relatively strong female
participation rates but lag behind the European average on hours worked per capita.
In the
Netherlands, for example, nearly four-fifths of employed women work part time, resulting in
an average working week of just 25 hours, 30 percent less than for men.
Exhibit 68
MGI has defined female participation in the European workforce in terms of activity rates and hours worked
Nordics
Continental Europe
United Kingdom
and Ireland
Southern Europe
Baltics
Central and
Eastern Europe
Female hours worked
Average actual weekly hours worked by women as a % of men, all ages
100
Bulgaria
Romania
Slovakia
95
90
Greece
85
Europe-30
Italy
80
Hungary
Czech Republic
Malta
Luxembourg
Ireland
United Kingdom
75
Croatia
Cyprus
Poland
Estonia
Latvia
Lithuania
Portugal
Slovenia
Finland
France
Spain
Belgium
Sweden
Denmark
Norway
Austria
Germany
Switzerland
70
Netherlands
65
64 65
75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98
Female labour-force participation rate
Female activity rate as a % of men’s, 25- to 54-year-olds
SOURCE: Eurostat; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
While both dimensions are important, one of the levers for improving female participation rates is flexible
working arrangements, which in some cases may lead to a higher incidence of part-time work.
162
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
119
. Countries that outperform on both dimensions are a diverse group, including Portugal
and Spain and many from Central and Eastern Europe, the Baltics, and the Nordics.
Overall, a U-shaped relationship between per capita income and female participation can
be observed both across and within countries.163 The challenge for the countries with
relatively lower income levels included in this group will be to maintain and improve on
their participation rates as welfare increases. High-income countries that do not share this
outperformance should look to the example set by the Nordics to find policies that can
accelerate their progress up the right-hand side of the field (Exhibit 69).
Exhibit 69
Low-income countries need to maintain high female participation rates as welfare increases
Nordics
Continental Europe
United Kingdom
and Ireland
Southern Europe
Baltics
Central and
Eastern Europe
Female labour-force participation rate
Female activity rate as a % of men’s, 25- to 54-year-olds
98
Lithuania
96
94
92
Sweden
Denmark
Austria
Finland
Portugal
Latvia
Bulgaria
Slovenia
Croatia
90
France
Estonia
88
Netherlands
Spain
Cyprus
Germany
Slovakia
Belgium
Europe-30
United
Czech
Kingdom
Republic
Poland
Hungary
86
84
82
Norway
Romania
Switzerland
Luxembourg
Ireland
80
Greece
78
76
Italy
74
10
12
14
16
18
20
22
24
26
28
30
32
34
36
46
48
66
68
70
72
74
Per capita GDP
Purchasing power standard per inhabitant, thousand
SOURCE: Eurostat; OECD; Jobs and growth: Supporting the European recovery, IMF, 2014; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
See Kristin Mammen and Christina Paxson, “Women’s work and economic development”, Journal of
Economic Perspectives, volume 14, number 4, fall 2000, and Claudia Goldin, “The U-shaped female labor
force function in economic development and economic history”, in Investment in women’s human capital and
economic development, T. Paul Schultz, ed., University of Chicago Press, 1995.
163
120
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
Grey workers
Grey labour-force participation in Europe was 35 percent in 2013, 50 percentage points
less than the participation rate of 25- to 54-year-olds. In a handful of countries—including
Norway, Switzerland, Sweden, and the United Kingdom—grey participation rates are more
closely aligned with those of the prime working-age population. These cases are largely the
exception to the rule, but the trend is positive. Over the past ten years, grey participation
has increased by more than eight percentage points compared with an increase of just two
percentage points among 25- to 54-year-olds.
The United Kingdom is notable because
it already had a relatively high grey participation rate of 37 percent in 2003 and posted a
significant 4.7 percentage point increase in that rate over the subsequent ten years. In
Germany, at 41 percent in 2013, participation increased three times as much as it did in the
United Kingdom, but from a lower base in 2003 of 27 percent.
A major determinant of grey participation is the statutory retirement age, which acts as an
anchor around which actual retirements occur.164 Most European regions match or exceed
the average statutory retirement age in the OECD of 65, with some catch-up occurring in
the Baltics and Central and Eastern Europe, where the average statutory retirement age for
males is 62 and 64 years, respectively. France recently decreased the official age to 60 with
an increase to 62 planned for 2017.
Germany recently introduced the option that workers
with 40 years of continuous service can retire two years earlier than the official retirement
age.165 In all European regions, the average individual stops working before reaching the
official retirement age. The gap between the statutory and effective retirement age is
particularly large in Continental and Southern Europe at 3.6 and 3.2 years, respectively.
Despite significant increases in life expectancy and healthy life years across Europe,
most increases in the statutory retirement age have taken place only in recent years.166
Life expectancy has increased by more than nine years since 1970, but, over the same
period, the male average effective retirement age has fallen by six years (Exhibit 70). This
has caused the gap between the average age at which people retire and life expectancy
to balloon to 18 years in 2012.
Having started at the same level as the United States, the
effective retirement age in Europe has dropped to 62 compared with 65 in the United States
and 69 in Japan. As a result, the 54 percent European participation rate of those aged 55 to
64 is ten percentage points lower than the 64 percent rate in the United States.
See, for example, Romain Duval, The retirement effects of old-age pension and early retirement schemes in
OECD countries, OECD Economics Department working paper number 370, November 2003, and JeanOlivier Hairault, Thepthida Sopraseuth, and François Langot, “Distance to retirement and older workers’
employment: The case for delaying the retirement age”, Journal of the European Economic Association,
volume 8, issue 5, September 2010.
165
The current retirement age in Germany is 65 years and three months, although it currently rises by one month
each year and is set to rise by two months a year starting in 2024.
166
Adair Turner, “Population ageing: What should we worry about?” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal
Society, volume 364, issue 1532, October 2009.
164
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
121
. Exhibit 70
Although life expectancy has increased, the effective retirement age has fallen in Europe
more than it has in the United States
Average
improvement,
2003–13
Percentage points
Grey participation
across Europe
Activity rate, 2013
% of 25- to 54-year-olds
Nordics
50
49
United
Kingdom
and Ireland
0.7
4.5
Effective retirement age and life expectancy1
Age
80
Life
expectancy
Europe-27
78
76
74
46
Baltics
8.4
Continental
Europe
41
12.6
Europe-30
41
8.8
Retirement
age
72
70
Japan
68
66
64
Central
and Eastern
Europe
38
8.3
Southern
Europe
36
6.9
United
States
62
Europe-27
60
1970
80
90
2000
2012
1 Average effective male retirement age and total average life expectancy at birth.
SOURCE: Eurostat; OECD; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Boosting female
and grey
participation
could add
0.39
percentage points
to real annual GDP
growth
Initiatives to change the game
Increasing female and grey labour-force participation to best-practice levels could boost
real GDP growth by 0.39 percentage points per annum to 2025. This estimate is based
on the incremental improvement that European countries could achieve if they catch up
with 2013 best practice in 2025. In the case of female participation, achieving this boost to
growth would entail catching up with Sweden’s 25- to 54-year-old female labour market
participation rate of 88 percent. In the case of grey participation, it would entail catching up
with Hungary’s ratio between grey and prime working-age participation rates of 0.58.
The
incremental increase in participation is compared with an expected baseline scenario, in
which average female and grey participation rates across Europe are assumed to grow in
line with historical experience from countries that have developed participation rates similar
to the European averages of 2013. Our estimates suggests that grey participation could
become a major driver of future GDP growth, with an expected effect of about double the
size of increased female participation. Both estimates are based purely on increased activity
rates, keeping average weekly hours worked and productivity constant.
Among the key
levers to achieve rising participation rates are:
ƒƒ Reduce incentives to not work. Labour-market policies, and pension and taxation
systems, should be geared towards promoting participation.167 According to a 2012
Eurobarometer survey on “active ageing”, 53 percent of Europeans oppose a mandatory
For elaboration, see Economic policy reforms: Going for growth 2013, OECD, 2013; Pensions at a glance,
OECD, 2012; OECD pensions outlook 2012, OECD, 2012; Employment trends and policies for older workers
in the recession, European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions, 2012; and
David Sinclair, Jessica Watson, and Brian Beach, Working longer: An EU perspective, International Longevity
Centre, September 2013.
167
122
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
retirement age. The United Kingdom recently phased out its default retirement age,
so that most people can work as long as they wish. The country has also moved to
a defined contribution system that reduces the incentives to retire early. Meanwhile
Finland’s recent pension reforms propose a gradual increase in the retirement age to 65,
and thereafter to link it to life expectancy.
With respect to female participation, tax policy
can shape incentives in important ways. In Germany, household incomes are pooled and
progressive income taxes applied on the average amount, resulting in a particularly high
taxation of income for second earners. An alternative and potentially fairer arrangement
would have working couples experiencing a reduction in their combined tax burden
compared with single earner households.
ƒƒ Provide more support and flexibility to workers.
Research shows that childcare provision and flexible working arrangements are key drivers of female and grey
participation.168 In Sweden and Finland, municipalities provide child care to parents
during the ordinary working day, and in many cases even outside these times. In
Sweden, about one-third of children up to the age of three are in child care for more than
30 hours per week compared with 4 percent in the United Kingdom. To make child care
affordable, Sweden and Denmark subsidise it to the tune of 1.4 percent of GDP, double
the European average.169 Part-time work is an attractive form of employment for people
rearing their children and as a gradual pathway to full retirement.
In the United Kingdom
and Belgium, about one-third of grey workers work part time, compared with an average
of 22 percent in Europe. Other measures to improve flexibility—more common in the
Nordics than elsewhere in Europe—include being able to determine the start and end of
the working day, “save up” hours and days worked overtime to use as holiday, and even
choose total hours worked.170 In Germany, Daimler has put in place a “senior-expert”
programme that rehires retirees on short-term contracts for particular projects—a
win-win for the company that buys-in the knowledge, experience, and motivation it
needs, and for the grey worker. Such schemes help to preserve and share experience
across generations.
ƒƒ Eliminate (perceived) barriers to employment.
Many employers worry that grey
workers will be less productive than their younger colleagues and that female workers
will take breaks to give birth to and care for children or opt for part-time work, adding
complexity compared with their male colleagues. In the case of females, harmonising
paternity and maternity leave would reduce the bias against hiring women of childbearing age. In Sweden, parents receive 480 days paid leave, of which 120 days cannot
be reallocated between parents and must therefore be taken as 60 days per parent or
be lost.
A monetary bonus is provided when both parents take more than 60 days. For
each day extra above 60 days taken by the parent who has taken the least parental
leave, the government pays 50 Swedish kroner to each of the parents. At most, couples
can receive an additional 13,500 Swedish kroner combined.
In 2007, Germany changed
its parental leave scheme in similar ways and, within two years, 20 percent of fathers
took paid leave compared with an initial 3 percent.171 In the case of grey workers, a more
flexible system of wages would greatly help maintain their attractiveness for employers.
In Denmark and the United Kingdom, the average full-time wage declines once workers
have reached the age of 50, breaking the system of automatic increase of wages
with seniority.172 Replacing seniority with performance clauses in public-sector wage
See, for example, Olivier Thévenon, Policy drivers of female labour force participation in OECD countries,
presented at Seminar on Early Childhood Education and Care in Brussels, December 4, 2013, and Ted
Aranki and Corrado Macchiarelli, Employment duration and shifts into retirement in the EU, London School of
Economics Europe in Question discussion paper number 58, February 2013.
169
Latest available data from OECD are from 2009.
170
EU Expert Group on Gender and Employment (EGGE).
171
“Why Swedish men take so much paternity leave”, The Economist, July 22, 2014.
172
Ageing and employment policies: Norway 2013: Working better with age, OECD, June 2013.
168
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
123
. arrangements, as Sweden does, can point the way for companies in the private sector.173
In addition, protective legislation and an “Age Positive” campaign in the United Kingdom
aim to overcome age discrimination. Such discrimination is deemed to be widespread by
almost half of Europeans.174
~40%
of women in
Sweden and
Norway have
tertiary education
vs. European
average of 25%
ƒƒ Offer lifelong learning to everyone. Ensuring workers have the right skills is the key
criterion for employability.
In the case of female workers, we find that completion of a
tertiary education is the most important driver of their participation in the labour force.
In the best-performing countries, Sweden and Norway, about 40 percent of women
over the age of 25 have a tertiary education compared with the European average
of 25 percent. Grey workers can also benefit from lifelong education and training.
Germany’s “Perspektive 50plus” programme finances training in communication skills
and job applications as well as internships, personal coaching, and counselling. In
2011, 200,000 long-term unemployed went back to work, and 70,000 of them found
regular jobs.175 Businesses can do more, too.
Siemens, for example, experienced an
increase of almost two years in its average retirement age following reforms in 2011.
These included an increase in the firm’s maximum age by three years to 70, personal
“milestone” dialogues with employees aged between 55 and 60, and company health
and fitness schemes.
Pensions at a glance 2011, OECD, 2011.
Eurobarometer, 2012.
175
EEO review: Employment policies to promote active ageing 2012, European Commission, 2012.
173
174
124
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. 10. PRO-GROWTH IMMIGRATION
Pro-growth
immigration
could add
0.26%
to annual real GDP
growth
One way that Europe could compensate for its declining prime working-age population
would be through greater inflows of immigrants from outside the Europe-30 region who
are equipped with the skills needed for positions that employers currently struggle to fill.
Although immigration is a contentious political issue in many countries, revisiting this topic—
and viewing it through a pro-growth lens—could have significant economic benefits, These
include expanding the workforce, increasing demand and investment as more people need
housing or local services, contributing to more sustainable debt levels as debt is carried on
more shoulders, and reducing some of the pressure from ageing because immigrants tend
to be younger than established citizens. On average, immigrant populations feature a much
higher share of working-age people than natives, and in some countries they are better
educated than native individuals.
Some European countries, notably Belgium, Norway, and Sweden, already have high
levels of net migration from outside Europe. Others could emulate their approach.
By
increasing net non-European migration from 2.6 people per 1,000 inhabitants per year to
4.9, the European working-age population could stabilise by 2025. Among the measures
that European countries could consider are introducing open and transparent systems
contingent on employment as Sweden has done, using shortage lists as Germany does,
enhancing education and integration support for immigrants, setting up welcome centres
overseas to attract skilled migrants, and creating a pan-European immigration portal. If
Europe boosted its net immigration from non-European countries to this level—and did so
in a way that led to equal employment rates between natives and immigrants—real GDP
growth could accelerate by 0.26 percent per annum.
Where Europe stands
Europe can counteract the demographic drag on its workforce through higher participation,
increased fertility rates, or greater inflows of non-European migrants.176 Fertility is an option
that can be addressed only indirectly through government policy and, in any case, evolves
over a long period.
In reality, in addition to action to boost participation, only immigration
offers a genuine potential to expand the working-age labour pool in the period to 2025.
Together, these two approaches could have a powerful effect on European economies.
Today, annual net non-European migration ranges from zero in the Baltics and Central
and Eastern Europe to three immigrants per 1,000 inhabitants a year in the Nordics. On
average, extraterritorial—non-Europe-30—net immigration is about 60 percent lower than
the equivalent figure in the United States and 85 percent below the rate in Canada.177 Over
time, this has resulted in only 6.6 percent of the population of Europe having been born
outside the region. This is significantly lower than the share in the United States, Canada,
New Zealand, and Australia where between 13 percent and 27 percent of the population
was born abroad.
If we were to assume that immigration was the only tool available to Europe to stabilise its
working-age population, we estimate that Europe could need an additional 11 million nonEuropean immigrants by 2025 compared with the UN Population Division’s 2025 normal
migration scenario.
To achieve this increase, Europe may need to boost its net migration
rate from 2.6 people per 1,000 inhabitants per year to 4.9 people (Exhibit 71).178 Today,
Belgium, Norway, and Sweden are the only European countries that have such levels of
We focus on immigration from countries outside Europe rather than migration among Europe-30 countries.
This comparison uses Central Intelligence Agency data for Canada and United States; we note that
comparability with Eurostat figures for Europe-30 may be limited.
178
This scenario is the base case 2025 normal migration scenario of the UN Population Division.
176
177
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
125
. net migration. By way of contrast, Canada and Australia receive about 5.7 newcomers per
1,000 inhabitants.
Exhibit 71
To stabilise its prime working-age population, Europe-30 needs 11 million more immigrants,
increasing the net migration rate to 4.9 per 1,000
Europe-30 prime working-age population,
15- to 64-year-olds
Million
European-born
Additional net migration
Annual net migration
Persons per 1,000 population3
Current
1.3
345
Base case 2025,
no migration1
0
321
Base case 2025,
normal migration1
321
Stable prime WAP
case, 20252
321
12
2.6
333
24
4.9
345
+11
Annual net migration of non-Europe-30 migrants
Persons per 1,000 population, 2013
4.3
3.0
2.3
1.6
1.3
0.9
0.2
-0.1
Highimmigration, highpopulation
countries4
Share of
foreign-born
population6
%
Nordics
United
Kingdom
and Ireland
Continental
Europe
Europe-30
Southern
Europe
Central and
Eastern
Europe5
Baltics
8.6
7.1
7.9
8.3
6.6
7.2
1.5
8.9
1 Based on a medium-fertility scenario.
2 Working-age population.
3 Assumes stable working-age population to total population ratio.
4 Belgium, Norway, Sweden, i.e., countries with non-Europe-30 net migration of >4 newcomers per 1,000 population and population >5 million.
5 No data for Croatia, so Slovenia’s immigrant share is used as a proxy.
6 For Europe-30, this is non-Europe-30 immigrant share of total population.
NOTE: Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
SOURCE: Eurostat; United Nations Population Division; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
126
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. We acknowledge sensitivities around this issue, but it is indisputable that, in economic
terms, there are distinct advantages to growing the labour pool through immigration.
One of these is that the age mix of immigrants tends to be skewed towards working age
compared with the overall population. In 2013, 80 percent of non-European immigrants
were aged between 15 and 59, compared with 60 percent in the European-born population
(Exhibit 72). Consequently, a large part of the immigrant population is active in the labour
market. At the same time, many studies have shown that this higher prevalence of
immigrants in employment does not result in fewer jobs for the indigenous population.179
There is a counterpoint to the disproportionate share of immigrants in the workforce,
however.
Unemployment among immigrants stands at 20 percent of those active in the
labour force, compared with 10 percent among established EU-27 citizens (Exhibit 73).
Exhibit 72
The positive impact of immigration comes from differences in the age structure
between natives and incomers
Distribution of population by age category, 2013
%
Age
>85
75–85
–
Non-Europe-30
immigrants
1
=
Europe-30
natives
3
-3
6
9
16
23
45–59
22
15–29
-7
21
7
18
16
+2
21
35
30–44
Difference
Percentage points
-1
2
60–74
<15
Prime working-age
population
+14
+4
-9
SOURCE: Eurostat; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
See Alain Jousten et al., The effects of early retirement on youth unemployment: The case of Belgium, IMF
working paper number 08/30, February 2008; Arie Kapteyn, Adriaan Kalwij, and Asghar Zaidi, The myth of
worksharing, IZA discussion paper number 188, August 2000; and Tom Walker, “Why economists dislike a
lump of labor”, Review of Social Economy, volume 65, issue 3, September 2007.
179
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
127
. Exhibit 73
Non-European immigrants are more likely than native Europeans to be of working age
and active in the labour force
Breakdown of total non-Europe-27 immigrant population compared with
native population, 20131
%
100% =
461 million
35 million
16
Not of prime
working age2
36
24
Prime working
age not in the
labour force
Unemployed
18
5
Prime
working-age
population2
Employed
11
42
Europe-27
natives3
49
Non-Europe-27
immigrants4
1 Immigrants are people who were not born in the EU-27; natives are individuals born in the reporting country.
2 Prime working-age population is defined as 15- to 64-year-olds.
3 Natives are individuals born in the reporting country.
4 For Germany, foreign-born individuals are considered due to data availability.
NOTE: Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
SOURCE: Eurostat; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Rates of unemployment among immigrants from outside Europe compared with the
established population vary in different countries (Exhibit 74). In the Czech Republic and
Lithuania, for example, unemployment rates for immigrants are equal to or even lower than
those of the native population. In Ireland and the United Kingdom, unemployment rates
for both groups are also relatively similar. In Ireland, the unemployment rate of immigrants
stood at 15.6 percent in 2013 compared with 12.7 percent for the native population.
In the
United Kingdom, the equivalent shares are 9.8 percent and 7.5 percent. In many European
countries, immigrants tend to be more educated than the average native citizen. In Ireland,
56 percent of non-European immigrants have completed a tertiary education compared
with 34 percent of the native population.
However, this is not always the case. In Belgium,
Norway, Sweden, and Switzerland, unemployment among non-European immigrants is
more than triple that among established citizens, and an equal or lower share of immigrants
has a higher education compared to established citizens.
128
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
.
Exhibit 74
Unemployment rates among immigrants compared with European natives vary
from country to country
Unemployment rate of immigrants vs. natives, 15- to 64-year-olds, 20131
% of native values
Immigrant
unemployment rate
>2x native rate
1–2x native rate
< native rate
No data
1 Malta excluded from analysis due to data being unavailable.
SOURCE: Enerdata; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Initiatives to change the game
If Europe opted for policies that boosted the number of immigrants by the amount needed
to fully offset the projected decline in its working-age population—with no other efforts on
this front such as boosting participation or fertility—we estimate that this could increase real
GDP growth by 0.26 percent per annum to 2025. This estimate assumes that governments
put in place immigration systems that are better geared towards attracting immigrants
who have received a higher education and therefore have better job prospects than many
immigrants today, equalising employment rates among immigrants and natives. Apart from
the direct boost to GDP from immigration, the rebalancing towards a larger working-age
population would help to carry the costs of an ageing population, including the fiscal burden
of pensions and health care.
Among the initiatives that Europe could consider are:
ƒƒ Introduce open and transparent immigration systems contingent on employment.
At the very minimum, governments need to make immigration less burdensome and
shape it according to societal and economic needs.
Sweden, for example, introduced
an uncapped “demand-driven system” in 2008 following concerns about labour
shortages.180 The system enables employers to hire from abroad as long as the vacancy
had been advertised for more than ten days and the job meets collective wage and
conditions contracts. Upon unemployment, immigrants have three months to secure a
new job offer or they are required to leave. Australia has a two-stage system that relies
Recruiting immigrant workers: Sweden 2011, OECD, December 2011.
180
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
129
.
heavily on temporary visas.181 There is no cap on temporary workers but light regulation
of them. Immigrants are incentivised to undertake high-skilled employment, education,
or training to qualify for permanent residency. The system has reduced unemployment
among immigrants, and about 50 percent of temporary visa holders are given the right
to stay permanently. Canada’s “supply-driven system” is based on points awarded for
specific criteria.
These standardised criteria can change according to what jobs need to
be filled, but at all times they are updated and available online with a test so that potential
immigrants can calculate their personal score. Applications can be filled out online (unlike
in 80 percent of Europe), reducing processing times and costs.182 The points-based
system also helps to assure citizens that immigrants bring specifically needed skills and
desired characteristics, thereby tempering political opposition to their arrival.
ƒƒ Implement shortage lists that ease entry. Matching the skills of immigrants with the
needs of employers can help to ensure that immigrants are employed for a sustained
period.
Denmark, Germany, and Sweden have “shortage lists” published online in an
effort to focus immigration on occupations with vacancies. In Sweden, the demandbased system guarantees employment; in addition, anyone who desires to fill an
occupation on the shortage list does not need to return to the home country to apply for
a work permit. One result has been a stronger correlation between visa applications and
job openings, and about half of immigrants arriving under the worker immigration rules
are focused in shortage occupations.183 In Denmark, someone whose skills match the
shortage list receives bonus points to enable the applicant to obtain a residence permit
for seeking and undertaking work.
In Germany, any immigrant whose skills match the
shortage list can be hired without the employer having to meet a labour-market test.
Such a test would usually be required to determine whether a job offering can be filled by
someone from abroad.
ƒƒ Increase education and integration opportunities. The potential value added of
immigrants increases with their employment status and participation in society. As
workers retire and the population ages, Europe faces a potential skill shortage, in
particular for medium- and high-skilled jobs in engineering, information technology, and
health.184 Germany and the Netherlands have average stay rates of highly educated
international students that are 26 percent and 27 percent, respectively, above the
OECD average of around 25 percent.185 International graduates in these countries
have direct access to job-search visas and can apply for a permit without having to
return to their home country.
Both countries have reformed their academic systems
to international standards to attract foreign students. The Netherlands also benefits
from widespread use of English.186 Internationally, stay rates remain below Canada’s
34 percent. By allocating additional points for higher education, immigration to Canada
is skewed towards the higher-skilled end of the spectrum.
Notwithstanding the political
complexities, expanding the EU Blue Card system to Denmark, Ireland, Norway,
Switzerland, and the United Kingdom could help to encourage skilled immigration.
The scheme gives highly educated immigrants who have a job offer at strict salary
requirements the right to work in Europe through a single application procedure. Post Robert G. Gregory, The two-step Australian immigration policy and its impact on immigrant employment
outcomes, IZA discussion paper number 8061, March 2014.
182
Comparative immigration study 2013–2014: Migration formalities for third-country nationals in 26 European
countries, Deloitte, November 2013.
183
Recruiting immigrant workers: Germany 2013, OECD, February 2013; Recruiting immigrant workers: Sweden,
OECD, December 2011.
184
Martin van der Ende et al., European vacancy and recruitment report 2012, European Commission,
November 2012; 2013 skills and demand forecasts from the European Centre for the Development of
Vocational Training (Cedefop).
185
International migration outlook 2011, OECD, July 2011.
186
Brooke Sykes, Mobile talent? The staying intentions of international students in five EU countries, Migration
Policy Group, April 2012.
181
130
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. entry, Canada provides free language training to immigrants, helps them find a job and a
place to live, and provides information about available community services to encourage
integration. Similarly, Germany offers free language classes and has recently opened
online, as well as physical, welcome centres that offer personal assistance to improve
immigrant perceptions and aid integration.
ƒƒ Establish European welcome centres abroad to attract foreigners. To attract more
foreign migrants, Europe would need to brand itself as an attractive destination with
a strong job market, high social mobility, and a pleasant living environment for highly
skilled immigrants. Agencies can support foreign students and qualified workers in the
immigration process, establishing better links with local universities and businesses.
For example, the British Council is represented in more than 100 countries, its aim
being to encourage educational and cultural exchanges with the United Kingdom.
The
organisation promotes educational opportunities in the United Kingdom and provides
English-language training. Similarly, the Australian Agency for Education and Training has
a number of offices in the Middle East to attract students from that region. With a central
point of contact—rather than individual universities marketing themselves separately—
countries can increase their reach and impact.
ƒƒ Create a pan-European immigration portal.
A significant barrier for incoming
immigrants in Europe is admission procedures that tend to impose a multitude of
requirements and involve long processing times for applications and high rejection
rates.187 The EU Blue Card is promising because it has a single application procedure.
A single online visa application portal for all European countries could potentially serve
to streamline the immigration process while maintaining national sovereignty over the
assessment and decisions on entry. The idea would be that a candidate for immigration
would be able to access all the documents required in one place, and then decide
which European country (or countries) to apply for. This system would have similar
characteristics to the Common Application, a single portal for students to apply to more
than 500 universities in 12 countries.
Such a system could also be a useful step towards
a unified points-based immigration system.
Recruiting immigrant workers: Germany 2013, OECD, February 2013; Recruiting immigrant workers: Sweden
2011, OECD, December 2011.
187
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
131
. 11. ENHANCED LABOUR-MARKET FLEXIBILITY
The labour market is where most people feel the ups and downs of the economy most
acutely. In the two decades to 2012, two-thirds of European economic growth accrued to
workers through labour incomes.188 The effective functioning of the labour market is the
most important way of ensuring that growth is inclusive. Yet Europe is underperforming
other developed economies.
In 2013, the share of people of working age employed in
Europe was lower than the OECD average, and there is a large degree of bifurcation
between workers on permanent and temporary contracts, with many young people
employed on the latter. Moreover, labour mobility in Europe is relatively low.
Given these relatively poor labour-market outcomes, it is essential that everything be done
to ensure that the job market works more effectively. A number of European economies
have successfully reformed their labour markets over the past decade, reducing
unemployment or increasing the share of people of working age with jobs in other ways.
Initiatives to change the game include a reduction in employment protection and labour
taxes to incentivise hiring, particularly in the case of younger workers (Spain used both
levers in its labour-market reform), adopting more assertive active labour-market policies
at the expense of passive benefits such as Denmark’s flexicurity model, or making wagebargaining mechanisms more flexible.
Europe should also intensify efforts to make the
single labour market work in reality. Reforms of this nature could unlock approximately
0.15 percent of additional real GDP growth per annum.
64%
labour-force
participation
among 15–64 age
group in Europe in
2013
Where Europe stands
Europe’s labour markets are not in good shape. In 2013, the continent’s share of those
aged 15 to 64 in employment stood at 64 percent.
That compared with 72 percent in
Australia and Canada, for instance. Even before the financial crisis in 2007, only 66 percent
of Europe’s working-age population was employed. The two percentage point decline since
late 2007 was led by Southern European countries, whose share fell by seven percentage
points to only 55 percent by late 2013.
In other parts of Europe, the picture is not as bleak.
In the Nordic countries and the United Kingdom and Ireland, the employed share in late
2013 stood at 73 and 70 percent, respectively, despite a decline of 1.5 percentage points
since late 2007. During the same period, the countries of Continental Europe experienced
an increase of two percentage points, to 70 percent, in the share of people employed. While
the Baltics’ share dropped dramatically, from 67 percent to 59 percent, in only three years, it
had recovered to 67 percent by late 2013 (Exhibit 75).
188
132
The annual labour income share is calculated by the OECD as total labour costs (compensation of employees,
adjusted for the self-employed) divided by nominal output.
It is available for all Europe-30 countries except
Croatia and Malta.
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. Exhibit 75
European employment rates are, on average, below those of other OECD economies but have improved lately,
except in Southern Europe
Employed share of working-age
population, 20131
Annual data, %
Employment rate, 1Q07–4Q13
%
78
72
Australia
76
74
72
Canada
Nordics
72
United Kingdom
and Ireland
70
68
OECD
67
65
66
Baltics
64
United States
Continental
Europe
Europe-30
62
Central and
Eastern Europe
60
58
Europe
64
56
Southern Europe
54
2007
08
09
10
11
12
2013
1 Defined as aged 15–64.
SOURCE: OECD; Eurostat; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Many of Europe’s labour markets are also characterised by a high degree of bifurcation
between workers on permanent and on temporary contracts, and—related to
that—between the older and younger labour force (Exhibit 76). At 25 percent, youth
unemployment (aged 15 to 24) in 2013 was nearly three times that of adult (aged 25 to 64)
unemployment at 9 percent. Moreover, those young people who are employed are much
more likely to work on temporary contracts: 43 percent of employees younger than 25 are
temporary workers, with shares exceeding 60 percent in some countries (69 percent in
Poland, 65 percent in Spain, 61 percent in Portugal). The equivalent number for the adult
population is 11 percent.
Incomes, too, have developed less favourably for young workers
than for older employees. In Spain, for instance, the incomes of adult workers have declined
by 1 percent a year since 2007, while young employees have experienced a 4 percent fall in
their incomes every year.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
133
. Exhibit 76
Labour-market conditions are toughest for young people, particularly in Southern Europe
Indicators of labour-market duality
Unemployment, 2013
%
Temporary employment, 2013
% of total employees
Income increases, 2007–12
Median equivalised net income;
compound annual growth rate,
purchasing power standard
%
Youth
15–24
15–24
18–24
Adult
25–74
25–64
25–54
27
58
Greece
-5
9
25
-3
65
56
Spain
21
24
-1
53
40
Italy
11
10
Germany
Europe
1
1
59
24
France
-4
4
12
8
4
53
8
3
8
5
2
43
25
11
9
1
2
SOURCE: Eurostat; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
In Europe, the labour market also has an important international dimension. A major element
of the European single market is that the EU and its partners Iceland, Liechtenstein, and
Norway have written into law the free movement of labour across borders. However, the
reality still lags behind the aspiration. In 2012, intra-EU immigration stood at 0.35 percent
of the EU population compared with 1.4 percent internal migration among the German
Länder, 1.7 percent internal migration among the Swiss cantons, and 2.2 percent interstate
migration in the United States.
What explains these poor European labour-market outcomes? There is no doubt that
the post-crisis economic environment has compounded the employment situation, but
many structural labour-market issues were apparent well before 2008.
Moreover, the
stark differences observed in the outcomes of various European countries point towards
the importance of different labour-market regulations and institutions in determining the
performance across the business cycle (Exhibit 77).
134
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. Exhibit 77
Regulation and institutions determine how well a national labour market works
for employers and employees
Labour-market regulation and institutions during the job life cycle
â–ª Wage-setting mechanisms such as
â–ª
â–ª The generosity of (and
constraints on) unemployment
benefits shapes the incentives
for the unemployed and
inactive to return to the labour
market
Active labour-market policies
support the unemployed in
their job search, e.g., through
training and matching
â–ª
Seeking
employment
centralised bargaining determine the costs
and conditions of employment
The tax wedge on remuneration also affects
the cost of keeping people employed
During
employment
Exiting
employment
â–ª Employment protection legislation
affects the degree of contract
flexibility and labour mobility
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute analysis
European labour markets have often been characterised as falling into four different social
models: Anglo-Saxon, Continental/Germanic, Nordic, and Mediterranean (Exhibit 78).189
Three of these archetypes have achieved more favourable labour-market outcomes:
the Anglo-Saxon countries with a highly flexible liberal model, the Germanic countries in
Continental Europe with a cooperative model supporting (re-)entry into employment, and
the Nordic countries with a flexicurity model that combines relatively flexible labour markets
with high support for the unemployed. In recent years, some Mediterranean countries,
notably Portugal, Spain, and Greece, have made considerable progress towards making
their labour markets more flexible. It is vital that others emulate some form of the successful
arrangements in order to boost employment and ensure that businesses have access to the
workers they need.
The liberal Anglo-Saxon model is characterised by very low unemployment protection. It
prevails in the United Kingdom, Ireland, and, to a lesser extent, Eastern European countries
such as Poland.
While the highly flexible Anglo-Saxon model provides only limited support
for job seekers, modest unemployment benefits ensure high personal incentives for reentry
into employment. The tax wedges between labour costs and take-home income in the
United Kingdom, Ireland, and Poland are at the bottom end of the OECD spectrum.
André Sapir, “Globalization and the reform of European social models”, Journal of Common Market Studies,
volume 44, number 2, June 2006.
189
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
135
. Exhibit 78
There are four main labour-market archetypes
Labour-market regulation and institutions
across the employment life cycle
Employment protection
legislation, 2013
OECD indicator on
the protection of regular
contracts against
dismissals1
Anglo-Saxon
1.6
0.4
Continental/
Germanic
Nordic
Spending on active
labour-market
policies, 2011
Active measures2
(% of GDP)
0.9
2.4
Europe
1.0
2.7
2.5
OECD
31.1
2.9
Mediterranean
2.3
0.6
0.7
0.4
Tax wedge on
labour costs, 2013
Income tax plus social
security contributions
(% of labour costs)
Labour-market
outcomes, 2013
%
Employment rate
Unemployment rate
70
45.2
43.0
45.4
41.4
35.9
8
73
6
73
7
58
16
64
11
65
8
1 Scale: 0 = least restrictive, 6 = most restrictive; weightings: 5/7 weight on individual dismissals, 2/7 weight on collective dismissals.
2 Including placement services, training, employment or start-up incentives, supported employment and rehabilitation, and job-creation measures.
NOTE: Anglo-Saxon = United Kingdom and Ireland; Continental/Germanic = Germany, Austria, Switzerland, Belgium, and Netherlands; Nordics = Denmark,
Norway, Sweden, and Finland; Mediterranean = France, Italy, Spain, Portugal, and Greece.
SOURCE: OECD; Eurostat; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
The second archetype is the coordinated Continental/Germanic model, typified by
Germany and Austria and characterised by widespread tripartite cooperation. Belgium and
the Netherlands also fall within this archetype. While employment protection is high and
labour-market flexibility low, an extensive infrastructure ranging from vocational training
to short-term working schemes help keep employment levels relatively high and resilient
in times of downturns. In contrast to the extensive active labour-market policies, passive
unemployment benefits are subject to tight eligibility criteria, underpinning the incentives for
the unemployed and inactive to pick up employment.
Moreover, a significant degree of wage
restraint is embedded in the coordinated bargaining process of Germany and Austria and
partly offsets the high tax wedge on employment. Indeed, Continental Europe is the only
European region in which real labour costs did not increase between 2000 and 2008, driven
by German wage moderation. Since the crisis, however, real labour costs have declined in
all European regions.
The third archetype is the Nordic model, typified by the Danish system of flexicurity.
This
approach balances high labour-market flexibility with high levels of support for those seeking
employment. With a significant degree of tripartite cooperation, the Nordic countries also
benefit from wage restraint in coordinated bargaining systems while maintaining a relatively
high tax wedge on labour costs.190 The Danish labour-market reforms in the 1990s that
began to develop the country’s flexicurity model enabled a sharp fall in unemployment.
Between 1993 and 2008, Danish unemployment dropped from 8.9 percent to 2.5 percent,
while during the same period EU-wide unemployment decreased from 8.2 percent to only
Jan Hendeliowitz, Danish employment policy: National target setting, regional performance management and
local delivery, Danish National Labour Market Authority, February 2008.
190
. 6.0 percent. The Danish reforms included a partial decentralisation of wage bargaining, a
tightening of eligibility criteria for unemployment benefits, and the strengthening of active
labour-market policies focused on upgrading the skills of those unemployed. In 2008,
Denmark spent 1.3 percent of GDP on such programmes.191
A less successful approach has been typical in Southern Europe and France. This
Mediterranean model is characterised by high employment protection for permanent
workers, high tax wedges on labour incomes, and high unemployment benefits,
while providing limited support to activate the unemployed.
Partly in consequence,
the Mediterranean countries have suffered from high unemployment and high social
expenditure, especially since the 2008 crisis. Moreover, the duality between highly protected
permanent workers and less protected temporary workers has led to young people being
particularly vulnerable in the labour market. In recent years, some Southern European
countries, notably Greece, Portugal, and Spain, have made considerable progress in
making their labour markets more flexible.
However, reform efforts are still lacking in France
and Italy, though in the latter case legislation is being prepared that proposes greater labour
flexibility and reform of unemployment-related social protection.
Initiatives to change the game
Reforming Europe’s labour markets could increase GDP growth between 0.1 percent and
0.2 percent a year. The IMF and the ECB estimate that growth would increase by 0.1 percent
per year if Europe were to close half of the gap with “best-in-class” OECD countries in terms
of looser employment protection legislation, moderate unemployment benefits, and more
assertive active labour-market policies.192 Of this total, 0.04 percent would come from each
of employment protection legislation and unemployment benefits, and 0.01 percent from
active labour-market policies. Other estimates point towards a higher impact from labourmarket flexibility.
The OECD has estimated that a 0.5-point reduction in the employment
protection legislation score could result in a 0.3 percentage point increase in labour
productivity growth in the business sector.193 This would imply an impact on growth of
between 0.1 and 0.2 percent for the same change in employment protection legislation.
While we suggest some specific labour-market reforms, it is important to note that the
problems of unemployment in Europe are multifaceted and country-specific and that there is
no “one-size-fits-all” solution at the national or EU level. Moreover, individual labour-market
policies or reforms are most effective when they are part of a comprehensive strategy that
is consistent with the particular institutional context in individual countries.194 Our analysis
suggests that the following should be considered as potential cornerstones of that strategy:
ƒƒ Reduce employment protection and labour taxes to incentivise hiring, particularly
for younger workers. While the impact of employment protection on overall
unemployment is ambiguous, high employment protection for permanent contracts
can exacerbate the duality between permanent and temporary employees as well
Beyond austerity: A path to economic growth and renewal in Europe, McKinsey Global Institute,
October 2010.
192
The assumptions behind this calculation are as follows: reduction of half the gap on employment protection
legislation to the average of the three lowest levels in the OECD (Canada, the United Kingdom, and the United
States); reduction in half of the gap in the average replacement rate of unemployment benefits relative to the
average within a set of countries with low replacement rates (Australia, Canada, Japan, New Zealand, the
United Kingdom, and the United States); increase in the ratio of spending on active labour-market policies
relative to six OECD countries with high spending (Austria, Denmark, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden,
and Switzerland).
We assume that 80 percent of the long-term potential (to 2060) is realised by 2025. See
Derek Anderson et al., “Assessing the gains from structural reforms for jobs and growth”, in Jobs and growth:
Supporting the European recovery, Martin Shindler et al., eds., IMF, 2014.
193
The 2012 labour market reform in Spain: A preliminary assessment, OECD, December 2013.
194
Euro area policies: 2014 Article IV consultation, selected issues, IMF Country Report number 14/199, July
2014; Andrea Bassanini and Romain Duval, “The determinants of unemployment across OECD countries:
Reassessing the role of policies and institutions”, OECD Economic Studies, number 42, issue 1, 2006.
191
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
137
. as between older and younger employees.195 Elevated hiring costs due to high tax
wedges are associated with lower employment across groups, while high minimum
wages particularly affect younger workers.196 The Spanish labour-market reforms in
2012 focused on introducing greater flexibility in wage-setting and working conditions
and making work contracts more flexible, particularly for small businesses. The OECD
estimates that these reforms will result in a longer-term decline in unit labour costs of up
to 2 percent and in an increase in annual labour productivity growth by 0.25 percent,
while reducing the bifurcation between permanent and temporary workers (Exhibit 79).197
Exhibit 79
Some Southern European countries have made considerable progress in making their labour markets more flexible
and reducing bifurcation
Labour-market reform and labour-market bifurcation, 2008–12
Nordics
Continental Europe
United Kingdom
and Ireland
Southern Europe
Baltics
Central and
Eastern Europe
Change in temporary share of employment
Percentage points
2.5
Slovakia
2.0
Hungary
1.5
Estonia
1.0
Ireland
Luxembourg
Netherlands
United Kingdom
0.5
Czech Republic
Italy
France
0
Finland
Austria
Poland
Denmark
Belgium
Switzerland
Slovenia
-0.5
Norway
Germany
-1.0
-1.5
-2.0
Greece
Portugal
-5.5
-6.0
-0.90
Spain
-0.50
-0.45
-0.40
-0.35
-0.30
-0.25
-0.20
-0.15
-0.10
-0.05
0
0.05
0.10
Change in employment protection
legislation score for regular contracts
Points
SOURCE: OECD Indicators of Employment Protection; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Ibid.
Ana Rincon-Aznar and W. S. Siebert, Employment protection, productivity, wages and jobs in Europe,
INDICSER discussion paper number 36, December 2012; Euro area policies: 2014 Article IV consultation,
selected issues, IMF Country Report number 14/1999, July 2014.
197
The 2012 labour market reform in Spain: A preliminary assessment, OECD, December 2013.
195
196
138
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. ƒƒ Adopt more assertive active labour-market policies at the expense of passive
benefits. Stepping up active labour-market policies (for instance, training and
matching employment seekers with vacancies) while tightening eligibility criteria for
unemployment benefits is generally associated with an increase in employment,
although the effectiveness varies by the type of the programme.198 The German Hartz
reforms of 2002 to 2005 combined a strengthening of active labour-market policies with
a comprehensive reform of passive unemployment benefits, which included tightening
of eligibility criteria, shortening of payment durations and reduction of amounts.199
This combination attempts to activate the unemployed in their search for work, while
supporting them in the process. It is widely held that these reforms, alongside the
existing extensive active labour-market policies, contributed to Germany’s favourable
employment outcomes.200
ƒƒ Intensify efforts to make the single labour market work. Increasing labour mobility
among European countries can help improve the matching of workers and jobs across
countries.
While personal, cultural, and language barriers likely dwarf administrative or
policy-induced barriers to migration, there are some measures policy makers can take
to improve the functioning of the European Single Market.201 For instance, promoting
English-language education across the EU as well as enhancing the provision of training
in local languages could ease the path for people seeking jobs outside their home
country. Another useful step would be to improve the coordination of job centres and
employment agencies to help match available workers with available jobs. A system in
which professional qualifications in one country are recognised in another and pensions
are transferable would further reduce friction.
100K
Germany, where unemployment is among the lowest in the EU, has made proactive
efforts to attract EU nationals from countries with higher unemployment, for example,
through a “permanent co-operation bridge” between Spanish and German job centres.
In 2013, there was a net influx of more than 100,000 Southern Europeans—40,000 of
whom were Italian—into Germany.
That compares with annual figures of only about
40,000 prior to the crisis. However, there is considerable room for growth, as no other
region has yet reached the mobility levels of Central and Eastern Europe, the region from
which almost 500,000 people net moved to Germany in 2013.
Southern
Europeans
migrated to
Germany in 2013
A common European unemployment insurance scheme is a complementary tool to
mitigate asymmetric business cycles in Europe, and particularly the Eurozone. It serves
as an automatic stabiliser transferring funds from booming regions to those in recession,
thus helping to offset the consequences of negative economic shocks.
As long as the
unemployment benefits funded under such a scheme are limited to a relatively short
duration (say, less than one year), they remain linked to the economic cycle rather than to
structural differences and therefore would not result in systematic fiscal transfers across
countries over the business cycle.202 As a consequence, every country should, at times,
become a net contributor as well as a beneficiary. The European Parliament estimates
Andrea Bassanini and Romain Duval, “The determinants of unemployment across OECD countries:
Reassessing the role of policies and institutions”, OECD Economic Studies, number 42, issue 1, 2006; Euro
area policies: 2014 Article IV Consultation, selected issues, IMF Country Report number 14/1999, July 2014.
199
For example, reform and expansion of federal job centres as well as start-up grants for the unemployed
transitioning into self-employment.
200
See, for example, Tom Krebs and Martin Scheffel, “Macroeconomic evaluation of labor market reform in
Germany”, IMF Economic Review, volume 61, number 4, December 2013.
201
Internal market, Special Eurobarometer 398, European Commission, October 2013.
202
Sebastian Dullien and Ferdinand Fichtner, “A common unemployment insurance system for the euro area”,
DIW Economic Bulletin, volume 3, issue 1, January 2013.
198
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
139
. that an integrated scheme for short-term unemployment benefits would have attenuated
the GDP loss in the most affected countries of the Eurozone by €15 billion per year.203
•••
The 11 growth drivers discussed in this chapter together would constitute a sweeping
programme of reform that has the potential to transform Europe’s growth prospects. It
is notable that three-quarters of them can be put in place at the national, rather than the
EU, level—holding out the promise of real change that doesn’t rely on the complexities of
European decision making. However, it is highly unlikely that the transformative change
that they could deliver will be possible without strong investment and job creation in Europe
to pay for the up-front investment needed, and to ease the transition and make reform
palatable to Europe’s citizens. We turn to the question of investment and job creation in the
next chapter.
Joseph Dunne, Mapping the costs of non-Europe, 2014–19, European Parliamentary Research Service,
March 2014.
203
140
McKinsey Global Institute
2.
Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. © Getty Images
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
141
. Chapter photo
Chapter 3: Orange scientists
© Getty Images
142
McKinsey Global Institute
2. Reform—much of it national—can deliver growth
. 3. HOW EUROPE CAN REIGNITE
INVESTMENT AND JOB CREATION
A programme of structural reform based on the 11 growth drivers that we have discussed
has the power to profoundly change the way the European economy works, boosting
productivity and competitiveness in the long term. But such a programme will cost money
in the short term. This is the nub of Europe’s challenge.
The continent needs reform to boost
the long-term performance of the economy to meet Europeans’ economic and societal
aspirations. But, in order to reform and produce healthier long-term growth, Europe needs
more investment and job creation in the short term.
Europe has a significant demand deficit, leaving the continental economy to rely largely
on exports to drive the recovery thus far. Households are attempting to deleverage,
corporations are piling up cash rather than investing because of the uncertain economic
outlook, and the public sector has embarked on austerity policies to keep debt levels under
control.
While each sector is acting rationally in its own right, the result is that aggregate
demand remains weak. Output overall remains 15 percent below where it would have been
on pre-crisis trends.
Many proposals have been made on how investment and job creation could be unleashed,
but discussion to date has tended to focus narrowly on the magnitude and composition of
a QE programme and on the capacity for fiscal stimulus. Europe needs to engage urgently
in a robust and unbiased debate on a broader range of investment and job creation options.
Some options are comparatively feasible.
For example, there could be moderate increases
in some government deficits in line with the Fiscal Compact. Others, such as central bank–
financed spending vouchers, are bolder and more radical, requiring a substantial shift
in thinking. This does not mean that they should be dismissed.
Rather, their merits and
drawbacks should be debated in the public and political arena so that Europe can create
innovative solutions to its investment and job creation crisis.
We acknowledge that there is bound to be nervousness about some measures for
stimulating investment and job creation. Decision makers and citizens are rightly concerned
about any unsustainable spending. All the options we discuss in this chapter entail risk and
possibly unintended, often distributional, consequences.
But the status quo has significant
risks, too. The onus is therefore on policy makers to find ways to enable additional public
and private spending that is sustainable. Only by doing so will Europe be able to put in place
a credible programme of reform that enhances the continent’s long-term competitiveness
and growth prospects.
.
Successful reform requires productive investment and demand for jobs—and
vice versa
Many growth drivers will be difficult to implement without more spending. Those that invest
for the future could require additional spending of between 1.7 percent and 3.7 percent
of European GDP per annum (Exhibit 80).204 For example, developing competitive cities
will require the construction of more good-quality affordable housing and transport
infrastructure.205 Establishing a more nurturing environment for innovation will require
governments to gear public procurement towards R&D-intensive goods and services.
Exhibit 80
To be put into practice, the growth drivers will require investment and stronger demand to create jobs
Up-front investment required
Estimated
annual outlay1
% of Europe-30
GDP
Nurturing
ecosystem for
innovation
Effective education
to employment
Investing
for the
future
0.6–1.6
0.4–0.7
Supporting urban
development
Stronger demand required to create jobs
and make reforms palatable
Competitive and
integrated markets in
services and digital
0.4–0.5
Productive
infrastructure
investment
Reduced energy
burden
Total
Boosting
productivity
Public-sector
productivity
Further openness
to trade
Grey and female
labour-force
participation
0.3–0.9
Mobilising
the
workforce
1.7–3.7
Pro-growth
immigration
Enhanced labourmarket flexibility
1 Estimate assumptions are in the appendix.
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Many of the growth drivers involve substantial transitional costs to society. Those that
mobilise the workforce may not be palatable to many citizens—and are therefore not
politically feasible while investment and job creation are weak and unemployment high. They
could exacerbate a difficult economic context in the short term even while likely to produce
favourable outcomes in the longer term.
Although, for example, enhancing labour-market
flexibility will help the economy over the long haul, many individuals may be negatively
Costs are calculated at the country level and aggregated for Europe. The cost of an improved innovation
ecosystem is based on the gap between the proportion of R&D spending in the private and public sectors
together among European countries and the international top performer (South Korea) and the third-best
performer (the United States). Education costs are estimated based on the gap between each country
and average spending as a share of GDP among countries that score highly on the effective education-toemployment growth driver, corrected for the number of students in each country.
Affordable housing draws on
the 2014 MGI report A blueprint for addressing the global affordable housing challenge and takes the estimate
of the cost to raise housing across Europe to the minimally acceptable standard. Costs are allocated to
countries, where specific estimate is not available, on the basis of severe housing deprivation from Eurostat’s
SILC data set. The cost of future infrastructure needs is calculated based on the range of projected GDPgrowth rates and the methodology developed in the 2013 MGI report Infrastructure productivity: How to save
$1 trillion a year.
205
A blueprint for addressing the global affordable housing challenge, McKinsey Global Institute, October 2014.
204
144
McKinsey Global Institute
3.
How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. affected in the short term.206 Further openness to trade can harm those working in sectors
that are newly exposed to global competition.
Growth drivers that boost productivity involve difficult transitions as economies rebalance
and companies and public organisations restructure. Such transitions are difficult even in
benign phases of an economic cycle and are all but politically impossible when those who
may lose their jobs in the process will find it hard to find another one. Helping those whose
economic prospects are hurt by the transition may require generous outlays.
In addition to the direct and indirect costs of implementing the growth drivers, there is
a broader need for a positive demand environment that can help create jobs. This can
make many reforms easier.
For example, increasing female and grey labour participation
or immigration at a time of already high unemployment will be difficult. Policy makers
may find that political resistance to trade agreements is too strong when voters feel
economically insecure.
Of course, some of the reforms can themselves trigger private investment and therefore
stimulate investment and job creation. For instance, greater immigration may require
investment in housing and create opportunities for local service firms such as retailers.
Progress on building a single market in energy or telecoms and clarity on regulation in those
sectors could unleash investment in the respective infrastructure.
Spain's R&D
budget needs to
increase by
€24B
to match that of
South Korea
In practice, European countries will need to prioritise reforms that meet their most pressing
needs.
Regardless of which items in the menu of growth drivers a country chooses to
implement, there will be substantial additional costs that will not be met in the current
demand context. For instance, Spain’s education-to-employment system is in need of an
overhaul, and its total R&D budget would need to increase by €24 billion to almost three
times its current level in order to reach South Korea’s R&D share of GDP. At the same time,
Spain’s infrastructure spending is near or above the level required for expected long-term
GDP growth, suggesting that additional resources devoted to infrastructure are unlikely
to be productive.
Similarly, Italy has a large need for further spending on education and
innovation. In contrast, Germany already has relatively high levels of R&D spending but
spends €14 billion less on infrastructure than would be suitable for long-term GDP growth.
Germany also spends relatively little on education to employment as a share of GDP and
controlling for the number of students—almost €30 billion less per year than what would
be expected.
A gap in aggregate demand persists in all domestic sectors of the economy,
leaving Europe to rely on net exports
Seven years on from the global recession of 2008, the European economy is running well
below its long-term potential. Thus far, Europe has relied on net exports—despite the
weakness of the world economy—while all other sources of demand remain constrained.
Accommodative monetary policy has not compensated, and it cannot on its own
compensate for weak demand.
All sectors will need to play their part to overcome Europe’s
demand deficit and thereby help to build the platform needed for structural reform.
Daiji Kawaguchi and Tetsushi Murao, Labor market institutions and long-term effects of youth unemployment,
IZA discussion paper number 8156, April 2014.
206
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
145
. A large output gap persists
In 2014, Europe was still running an output gap—the difference between the actual GDP and
the potential capacity of existing labour and capital—of 2.4 to 2.7 percent of GDP, according
to the European Commission, the IMF, and the OECD.207 That is slightly more than the size of
the economies of Greece and Ireland combined.208
There are other ways to measure how much the economy is running below its potential. For
instance, real potential output growth has dropped from 2 percent a year before the crisis
to 0.7 percent per annum (Exhibit 81). This has left Europe’s economy at 10 percent below
its pre-crisis potential output trend. The drop in the potential output growth rate stems from
factors including a loss in human capital due to long-term unemployment, falling investment,
and a rebalancing of the economy resulting in a glut of unproductive assets in some sectors.
Looking at actual output, extrapolating from the pre-crisis trend that in the mid-2000s was
running ahead of potential output suggests that the output of the European economy is
currently around 15 percent below where it would have been if the crisis had not occurred.
Exhibit 81
Across all measures, output has significantly lagged behind the potential of the European economy
Europe-28 actual vs.
potential output
2010 chain-linked € trillion
Actual output
Potential output1
Extrapolated
pre-crisis actual2
Extrapolated
pre-crisis potential3
16.0
Output gap
% of GDP
15.5
15.0
14.5
-15.4
14.0
-10.0
13.5
-2.4
13.0
12.5
12.0
11.5
2004
05
06
07
08
09
10
11
12
13
2014
Forecast
1 “Potential output” describes the productive capacity of an economy in case of sustainable use of available labour, capital, and technologies.
2 “Extrapolated pre-crisis actual” assumes real growth continues at same rate as it did during the pre-crisis boom years. This would have been unsustainable
even in the old economy.
3 “Extrapolated pre-crisis potential” assumes that potential GDP continues to grow at same rate as it did pre-crisis. In this regime, sustainable growth could
have occurred faster.
SOURCE: European Commission; OECD; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Based on European Commission (2.4 percent for the EU-28), IMF (2.5 percent excluding countries amounting
to 6.9 percent of EU-28 GDP for which data were not available), and OECD (2.7 percent excluding countries
amounting to 3.3 percent of EU-28 GDP for which data were not available).
208
Output gaps cannot be directly observed from the economy and are therefore subject to a great deal of
uncertainty.
While they are usually directionally correct, revisions to the magnitude of output gaps are frequent
and large. The average revision is 1.5 percent of GDP. See, for example, Karel Havik et al., The production
function methodology for calculating potential growth rates and output gaps, European Commission
economic paper number 535, November 2014, and Eugen Tereanu, Anita Tuladhar, and Alejandro Simone,
Structural balance targeting and output gap uncertainty, IMF working paper number 14/107, June 2014.
207
146
McKinsey Global Institute
3.
How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. The European average masks a great deal of variation among countries (Exhibit 82). Greece
has an output gap of 11 percent of GDP, and its economy’s output is 45 percent below
its pre-crisis trend. Italy’s output gap amounts to nearly 5 percent of GDP and France’s
to 2 percent of GDP. Germany and the United Kingdom are two major exceptions to the
general picture of significant output gaps across Europe.
Both economies are running at
approximately their estimated potential, although, like other European economies, still far
below their pre-crisis trend.209
Exhibit 82
The output gap measures only a small part of the difference between European GDP today and
where it would have been on pre-crisis trends
Output gap
Output gap and gap to position on pre-crisis trend1
% of potential GDP, 2014 (forecast)
Germany
-0.8
United Kingdom
Spain
-0.8
France
Italy
Greece
Ireland
Portugal
-0.2
-2.3
-4.5
-6.0
-6.5
Gap to pre-crisis trend
-5.0
-11.0
-15.4
-10.9
-13.5
-16.1
-25.9
-29.3
-44.7
1 Based on European Commission data. Pre-crisis trend defined from the geometric mean of actual real growth between 2002 and 2007.
SOURCE: European Commission; IMF; OECD; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Countries with high output gaps are not using the full capacity of their economies, which
leaves almost everyone worse off than they would otherwise be. Periods with large output
gaps impose a substantial human cost and raise the risk of a “lost generation” as young
people are forced out of the job market and lose the opportunity to develop the skills
that would make them more productive in the future.210 It is no coincidence that roughly
75 percent of survey respondents in Spain and Italy, countries with high output gaps, say
that they are unhappy or very unhappy with their countries compared with only 27 percent of
respondents in Germany, whose output gap is close to zero (Exhibit 83).211
Estimates of Germany’s output gap come from the European Commission (-0.8 percent), the IMF
(-0.6 percent), and OECD (0.1 percent).
210
Daiji Kawaguchi and Tetsushi Murao, Labor market institutions and long-term effects of youth unemployment,
IZA discussion paper number 8156, April 2014.
211
MGI European Aspirations Conjoint Survey, August 2014 (N = 2,000 in each country).
209
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
147
.
Exhibit 83
European survey respondents in countries with high output gaps and unemployment tend to be
significantly less satisfied
Respondents “unhappy” or “very unhappy” with their country
Weighted; %
Unhappy
Very unhappy
77
73
64
34
39
47
39
27
23
7
32
22
22
20
16
34
31
6
24
14
12
9
43
34
Poland
Germany
Sweden
United
Kingdom
France
Romania
Spain
Italy
Output gap
% of GDP, 2014
-0.8
-0.8
-1.6
-0.8
-2.3
-1.3
-6.0
-4.5
Unemployment
rate
%, 2013
10
5
8
8
11
7
26
12
NOTE: Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
SOURCE: MGI European Aspirations Conjoint Survey, August 2014; World economic outlook: Recovery strengthens, remains uneven, IMF, April 2014;
McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Europe has had to rely on net exports to drive recovery while spending in all
domestic sectors remains weak
A rise in net exports has not been nearly enough to counteract contracting spending in all
domestic sectors. Net exports as a share of GDP for Europe grew by 2.4 percentage points
between 2008 and 2013, the only source of demand that grew significantly over the period
(Exhibit 84).212 In contrast, the recovery in the United States has been mostly generated by
the domestic economy.
While net exports have performed strongly since the crisis in Europe, questions linger
over how much further they can grow as the global economy remains weak and further
imbalances can contribute to low economic growth elsewhere in the world, depressing
destination markets. Much of the growth in net exports outside the EU came from Germany,
which had increases in gross exports of greater than €100 billion between 2008 and 2013.
212
148
Where statistics on the European economy are cited without other clarification, they are based on the
AMECO database.
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
.
This is a mixed blessing for the European economy. Export-led growth is susceptible to
sudden changes in the external economic environment outside domestic policy makers’
control. High net exports can also be a symptom of weak domestic demand.
At the same time, the Eurozone has started to rebalance. The economies of Southern
Europe have strongly increased their net exports.
Spain increased its nominal net exports
by €90 billion from 2008 to 2013, and Italy increased its by €45 billion over the same period.
Such rebalancing can help the most troubled economies and will be required for longer-term
sustainability. However, such rebalancing is difficult to achieve in a monetary union.
Exhibit 84
Europe’s recovery has mainly come from exports despite a weak global economy,
while the US recovery has been powered by domestic consumption
Change in real GDP, 2008–13
% of real 2008 GDP
Europe-30
GDP in 2005 €
United States
GDP in 2009 $
Real GDP 2008
100.0
Corporates
-2.3
Households
Public sector
-1.2
0.3
100.0
1.0
4.6
-0.7
Net exports
2.4
0.9
Real GDP 2013
99.1
105.8
NOTE: Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
SOURCE: Eurostat; AMECO database; US Bureau of Economic Analysis; National Export Initiative; McKinsey Global
Institute analysis
Meanwhile, companies, governments, and households have all been cutting their spending
at the same time that they seek to reduce their debts. Public debt has ballooned since
the financial crisis, but private sector balance sheet repair is slowly under way in Europe
(Exhibit 85).
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
149
.
Exhibit 85
Balance sheet repair is under way in private sectors in Europe
Debt by sector in 20 major European economies, 1Q04–4Q131
% of GDP
Lehman Brothers
bankruptcy
110
Change since
Lehman
bankruptcy
Percentage points
105
100
95
Non-financial
corporations
90
Quarters of
deleveraging
since peak
-2
18
Government
+26
2
Households
-1
18
85
80
75
70
65
60
55
50
2004
05
06
07
08
09
10
11
12
2013
1 Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal,
Romania, Slovakia, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom.
SOURCE: Haver Analytics; national central banks; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Corporations are piling up cash in response to weak demand
Corporate investment has dropped precipitously in response to a fragile macroeconomic
outlook and weak demand. If history is a guide, the trend will not reverse until public and
household spending recover and grow. Access to, and the cost of, finance, in contrast,
appear to be constraints mostly in the SME sector in those economies worst hit by the crisis.
Corporate investment has historically made up 11 to 12 percent of GDP and lays the
groundwork for future productivity growth. However, since 2008, corporate investment
has fallen by 19 percent.
Corporate investment would need to increase by an estimated
€200 billion to €250 billion to reach pre-crisis levels.
Corporate cash holdings are hitting record highs. Europe’s 500 largest companies
increased their excess cash holdings—the amount of cash over and above what they
need for day-to-day operations—by 60 percent from 2008 to 2013 to nearly €800 billion
(Exhibit 86).213 The cash holdings of SMEs have also risen but by less. Although many SMEs
are finding it hard to get the financing they need, cash assets increased by 1.4 percentage
“Excess cash holdings” are defined as the amount of cash above that needed to meet the day-to-day running
of the company, estimated as cash above 2 percent of revenue.
See McKinsey Corporate Performance
Analysis Tool, 2013.
213
150
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. points as a share of turnover between 2008 and 2012.214 Since SMEs generate 60 percent of
value added in the EU-28, this build-up of cash is significant.215
Exhibit 86
Corporations are piling up cash, citing weak demand and regulation—not credit—as the primary obstacles
to investment
Excess cash holdings of Europe’s 500 largest
companies (by revenue)2
€ billion
800
High
Investment barriers
% of respondents citing high or
medium barriers, 20133
Macroeconomic
outlook
750
Medium
67
Regulation
700
56
Product structure
and economics
650
+60%
600
24
Taxes and incentives
23
21
Market infrastructure
550
Information and
transparency
16
500
Internal governance
and capabilities
16
450
2008
09
11
10
12
2013
Accounting principles
10
1 Potential borrowing capacity for September and December 2014 long-term refinancing operations (LTRO) combined.
2 “Excess cash” defined as cash above 2% of revenue. Data used for 457 companies for which excess cash figures above zero were available for the full
sample 2008–13.
3 Interviews with executives of 36 large corporations with combined revenue of €400 billion commissioned by the Association for Financial Markets in Europe
(AFME).
SOURCE: McKinsey Corporate Performance Analysis Tool; Unlocking funding for European investment and growth, AFME, 2013; McKinsey Global Institute
analysis
Corporations are piling up cash largely because of weak demand. In a recent survey,
respondents from 67 percent of a selection of large corporations in France, Germany, Italy,
Portugal, Spain, and the United Kingdom ranked the macroeconomic outlook as a high
or medium barrier to investment—higher than regulation or taxes.216 A historical review of
recessions characterised by large declines in private investment reveals that the recovery
of the broader economy typically leads the rebound in private investment by several years
(Exhibit 87).217 This is likely due to businesses first working through their overcapacity before
building up additional capital stock.
BACH database from the Banque de France, data pulled in 2014 but available only to 2011. Data are from
Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic, France, Germany, Italy, Poland, Portugal, Spain, and Slovakia weighted by
turnover.
SME is defined as an organisation with turnover of less than €50 million.
215
Survey on the access to finance of enterprises in the euro area, European Central Bank, November 2014.
Note that this figure is based on defining SMEs as having fewer than 250 employees, which is different from
the BACH definition. Also see Patrice Muller et al., Annual report on European SMEs 2013/2014: A partial and
fragile recovery, Final report, European Commission, July 2014.
216
Unlocking funding for European investment and growth: An industry survey of obstacles in the European
funding markets and potential solutions, Association for Financial Markets in Europe, 2013. AFME surveyed
32 large European corporations.
217
Investing in growth: Europe’s next challenge, McKinsey Global Institute, December 2012.
214
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
151
.
Exhibit 87
Private investment typically recovers with a lag compared with the overall economy
Private investment and GDP indexed to 100 in the year prior to each recession identified1
Current crisis
GDP middle quartiles
Private investment middle quartiles
Index: 100 = peak real GDP prior to recession
150
140
130
120
110
100
90
80
70
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Years following recession
1 Episodes in which private investment fell at least 10% from GDP peak to GDP trough, excluding 17 episodes when
private investment fell by less than 10%. All values in year zero are equal to 100 since private investment is indexed to
100 in that year.
NOTE: Data for 2014 not yet available for real GDP.
SOURCE: Investing in growth: Europe’s next challenge, McKinsey Global Institute, December 2012; McKinsey Global
Institute analysis
Relatively few business leaders complain that access to financing is a substantial barrier
to investment (Exhibit 88). In 2014, only 11 percent of executives from large companies
expressed the view that access to finance is the most pressing problem their organisation
faces. For businesses with fewer than ten employees, the equivalent figure is 15 percent,
down from 21 percent in 2009.218 Corporate lending rates have fallen to roughly 3 percent in
most large European economies.219
However, there are still pockets of Europe in which potentially creditworthy borrowers are
finding it difficult to access finance.
For the very smallest enterprises, and particularly those
in peripheral economies where liquidity is still not universally present, access to finance
can represent a potential barrier to investment. In some countries, the situation is far more
severe; 55 percent of Greek SME executives have said that on a scale of 1 (no need) to 10
(high need), their need for finance in 2014 was 8 or more.
Survey on the access to finance of enterprises in the euro area, European Central Bank, H1 2014.
ECB statistical data warehouse.
218
219
152
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
.
Exhibit 88
Access to finance has improved for firms of all sizes since 2009,
and the gap between large firms and the rest has shrunk
Financing constraints by company size, 2009–14
% of executives responding that “access to finance” is
“currently the most pressing problem your firm is facing”
21
19
15
Micro
<10 employees
2009
2014
17
13
Small
10–49 employees
64%
11
Medium
50–249 employees
13
11
35%
Large
>250 employees
SOURCE: Survey on the access to finance of enterprises in the euro area, ECB, November 2014; McKinsey Global
Institute analysis
Governments have embarked on austerity in order to control debt levels
For fear that public debt levels are unsustainable, fiscal stimulus in Europe has been
shorter and less aggressive than it has been in the United States. The focus of European
governments has moved to consolidation, public investment has been cut, and European
economies have reinforced their commitment to containing debt and deficit levels through
the Fiscal Compact. But slow growth and low inflation have nonetheless resulted in an
increase in public debt levels of close to 30 percentage points of GDP since the crisis.
Deficit cutting has become an imperative for European governments because of concern
over the effect of rising—and potentially unsustainable—sovereign debt levels. Research
suggests that when debt rises above around 90 to 100 percent as a share of GDP, it
becomes much less sustainable and begins to have a negative impact on growth (although
the debate is not fully settled on this point).220 Average European government debt stood at
85 percent of GDP in 2014.
The sovereign debt burden is especially high in Belgium, Greece,
Ireland, Italy, and Portugal, each of which has a sovereign debt-to-GDP ratio in excess of
100 percent (Exhibit 89). Some of Europe’s largest economies, including Germany, France,
and the United Kingdom, have public-sector debt ratios of 75 to 100 percent of GDP.
Silvia Ardagna, Francesco Caselli, and Timothy Lane, Fiscal discipline and the cost of public debt service:
Some estimates for OECD countries, NBER working paper number 10788, September 2004; Cristina D.
Checherita-Westphal and Philipp Rother, The impact of high and growing government debt on economic
growth: An empirical investigation for the euro area, European Central Bank working paper number 1237,
August 2010.
220
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
153
. Exhibit 89
European governments have limited capacity to further stimulate and invest in growth
Government debt1 and fiscal balance by Europe-30 country
% of GDP debt
Size =
Population, 2013
Nordics
Continental
Europe
EU target
United
Kingdom
and Ireland
Southern
Europe
Baltics
Central
and Eastern
Europe
Fiscal balance, 2013
15
Norway
10
Germany
5
Switzerland
0
France
Italy
Sweden
-5
Portugal
Poland
Ireland
-10
United Kingdom
Spain
Greece
-15
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
110
120
130
140
150
160
170
Gross government debt1, 20132
1 Includes all non-consolidated loans and fixed-income securities.
2 Or latest available.
SOURCE: Haver Analytics; national central banks; Eurostat, McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Government spending increased during the recession as automatic stabilisers and stimulus
kicked in. However, most of this stimulus has ended. In 2013, the government spending
share of GDP was only marginally higher than it was in 2008.
There has been a shift away from investment towards government consumption.
Government investment cumulatively fell by 16 percent between 2008 and 2014 while
consumption grew by 3 percent. This largely reflects the fact that the slow recovery has
meant that automatic stabilisers such as unemployment benefits have remained in place
while discretionary investment spending has been cut as governments seek to meet deficit
reduction targets.
Stimulus in Europe, particularly in the Eurozone, was shorter and less aggressive than that
in the United States (Exhibit 90).
Between 2008 and 2010, the Eurozone’s fiscal stimulus
was 4.7 percent of GDP and the United Kingdom’s was 6.9 percent of GDP compared with
8.9 percent of GDP in the United States. About three-quarters of the US stimulus came from
an uptick in discretionary spending; in the Eurozone, that share was only one-third. Because
fiscal stimulus in the United States coincided with the depth of the recession, the effective
fiscal multiplier on the stimulus was much larger than it was in Europe, contributing to more
robust growth afterwards (although we note that the exact effect of government spending
on output is uncertain).
154
McKinsey Global Institute
3.
How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. Exhibit 90
The Eurozone gave a comparatively small fiscal stimulus after the crisis and experienced
a slow recovery
Change in real GDP and fiscal impulse,
2007–10 and 2010–131
% of start of period GDP
Real GDP
Fiscal impulse, including
the effect of fiscal multipliers
Fiscal impulse, direct effect
United States
2008–10
United Kingdom
Eurozone
19.5
12.2
7.9
6.9
8.9
-0.6
2011–13
-2.2
-4.3
6.3
4.7
3.1
0.5
-2.2
-6.7
-0.6
-5.6
-3.4
-3.8
1 “Fiscal Impulse” is defined as the negative change in deficits.
NOTE: The effect of fiscal multipliers on the cumulative effect is large, although there is a great deal of uncertainty about its
size. The fiscal multiplier during recession is estimated to be large (United States: 2.18; Eurozone: 2.56; UK: 1.0) while
the multiplier outside of a recession is small (United States: 0.33; Eurozone: 0.43, UK: 0.1). The timing of fiscal impulse
therefore plays a large role it its effectiveness.
SOURCE: Batini et al, 2012; Eurostat; FRED; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Not only was fiscal policy more aggressive and better timed in the United States, but
monetary policy was, too (Exhibit 91). This can partly explain why demand has been slower
to recover in Europe than in the United States.
Average European
government deficit
4.6
percentage points
smaller than US
deficit over past
7 years
McKinsey Global Institute
Real per capita GDP, population, and prices have all grown faster in the United States,
and therefore debt as a proportion of GDP has grown less quickly despite high borrowing.
Roughly half of the gap in real GDP growth between the United States and Europe is
attributable to population growth rates.
Although the average European annual general
government deficit has been 4.6 percentage points smaller on average than the deficit in
the United States over the past seven years, this has resulted in an increase in debt levels
over the period that was only eleven percentage points lower than in the United States
(Exhibit 92).
A window of opportunity for Europe
155
. Exhibit 91
The United States acted faster and more decisively than Europe
in response to financial and economic crisis
ILLUSTRATIVE EXAMPLES
United States
Eurozone
Timeline
(crisis in Europe occurred approximately 1–2 quarters later than in the United States)
Decision
domain
Action
2009
2010
2011
2012
Acting as
lender of
last resort
NOV
US agency
debt
($175B)
and
mortgagebacked
securities
($1.25T)
JUL
Covered
Bond
Purchase
(€60B in
first round)
MAY
Initiated
Securities
Market
Programme
to buy
government
bonds
(€220B)
Maturity
Extension
Program:
buying
long-term
and selling
short-term
securities
JUL
Draghi’s
“do
whatever it
takes”
speech
Funds rate
Central
banks
2007 2008
DEC
Lowered
funds rate
to 0–0.25%
MAY
Reached
policy rate
of 1%
MBS
purchases
also
provided
liquidity
MAR
Extended
purchases
to Treasury
securities
($900B to
Increase of
mid-2012)
liquidity
and higher
provision to
volumes
banking
sector
Liquidity
provision,
securities
purchases,
QE
OCT
Troubled
Asset Relief
Program
gives
immediate
relief to
financial
institutions
Stress
tests/
recapitalisation
Bank
cleanup
2013
2014
SEP
Lowered
policy rate
to 0.05%
Long-term
refinancing
operations
(LTRO):
2011/12:
~€1T;
targeted
programme
2014
DEC
Monthly
asset
purchases
while
unemployment
>6.5%,
totalling
$1,665T
MAY
Supervisory
Capital
Assessment
Program
JAN 2015
€60T of
monthly
asset
purchases
up to
September
2016 to
reach
inflation
target
OCT–NOV
Comprehensive
stress test
and Single
Supervisory
Mechanism
to monitor
financial
stability in
force
Bank nationalisations and recapitalisations ongoing beginning in 2008 in both the
United States and Europe1
Bank stress tests in 2009, 2010, and
2011, but not assessed to be fully
comprehensive
Regional
transfers
Fiscal
measures
Regionwide
stimulus
Annual transfers between states accounting for 8.4% of GDP—as an example, Florida in 2013
received 17.9% of its GDP through federal transfers
Intra-EU transfers at 1.6% of GDP only via EU budget, mostly structural, no automatic stabilizers
Cumulative 2007–10 stimulus
8.9%2 of 2007 GDP
Cumulative 2007–10 stimulus
only 4.7%2 of 2007 GDP
1 European countries faced additional challenges as the banking sector is much larger as a percentage share of GDP than in the United States, requiring
larger recapitalisation amounts and limiting countries' capacities to stem banking crises.
2 Combined discretionary and automatic fiscal impulses.
SOURCE: ECB; Federal Reserve System; Congressional Research Service; European Commission; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
156
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. Exhibit 92
The US annual deficit was 4.6 percent larger on average between 2007 and 2013,
but the country’s debt rose only 11 percentage points more than Europe’s
2007–13
% of GDP
Europe
Fiscal deficits1
United States
General government debt
12.7
12.0
+41 p.p.
105
+29 p.p.
10.6
87
9.2
7.0
3.6
6.9
6.5
6.2
4.4
3.9
2.4
58
64
3.3
0.9
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2007 2013
2007 2013
1 EU-28 general government deficit under the excessive deficit procedure (EDP); US general government deficit; ESA 2010 and former definitions.
NOTE: Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
SOURCE: Eurostat; FRED; Haver Analytics; national central banks; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Households are slowly deleveraging
Household demand is still weak as households cut investment in residential property
while holding savings rates steady to slowly work through their burden of debt. Household
spending fell by €154 billion in real 2005 terms between 2008 and 2013. More than
80 percent of this decline was due to a drop in household investment as the real estate
boom collapsed. When asset prices fell sharply in 2008, many households were left with a
larger debt burden—on the order of 70 percent of GDP in 2008—relative to the underlying
assets than originally expected.
However, the process of deleveraging has been slow.
In the final quarter of 2013, household
debt as a percentage of GDP was only one percentage point below its level in the third
quarter of 2008 when the financial crisis began in earnest—even after around five years
of successive deleveraging. The fact that debts remain relatively high is constraining
households from spending.221
Weak household demand cannot be explained by precautionary saving, but rather by a
lack of demand for investment. Earlier in the recession households had faced high levels
of uncertainty, and reacted to it by increasing their savings rates in order to ensure against
future shocks.
These precautionary savings led to a spike in savings rates in 2009, reaching
13.2 percent of gross household disposable income across Europe. Savings rates have
since stabilised at roughly their long-term trend levels of 11 percent (Exhibit 93). However,
household investment has not recovered.
Indeed, 91 percent of the fall in household
investment between 2007 and 2013 comes from only five economies—Greece, Ireland, Italy,
Spain, and the United Kingdom. Spain was particularly badly affected by its housing bubble,
with a decline of more than 50 percent in household investment.
Karen Dynan, “Is a household debt overhang holding back consumption?” Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, spring 2012.
221
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
157
. Exhibit 93
Although household savings rates spiked in some countries following the crisis,
in Europe as a whole these rates were largely unaffected
Household savings rate
% of household gross disposable income
18
16
14
12
EU
United Kingdom
10
8
Spain
Greece
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
2003
Italy
France
Ireland
04
05
06
07
08
09
10
11
12
2013
NOTE: Greece, Bulgaria, Latvia, and Romania all have negative savings rates. This is because households in these
countries are borrowing to consume, meaning that consumption is greater than gross disposable income.
SOURCE: AMECO database; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
The demand situation is very different among European economies
Although clusters of European nations face very similar issues, the context can vary and
decision makers cannot ignore differences among nations. Different European economies
have very different capacities to spend to stimulate investment and job creation (Exhibit 94).
ƒƒ Germany did not experience a housing bubble, and the economy is running at or near
potential output. As a result, Germany is unique among major European economies in
needing to focus on growth-enhancing reforms; aggregate demand would gain little from
stimulus, despite the fact that Germany’s public sector is in a fairly solid fiscal position
and would be capable of financing it.
However, although the German economy is
growing, growth in household demand remains weak and corporate investment remains
€24 billion below 2008 levels in nominal terms.
ƒƒ Spain has experienced a housing bubble and subsequent asset write-downs followed
by deleveraging in both the household and the corporate sectors. Spain faces an
output gap of at least 5 percent of potential GDP as investment has collapsed and
unemployment soared. Stimulating private spending in this deflationary environment
will be difficult, particularly because the economy is now also hamstrung by a heavily
indebted public sector after saving failing banks.
The country will need to rely on net
exports or European support to change its demand situation.
158
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. ƒƒ The United Kingdom has similarly experienced a housing bubble, followed by a strong
decline in household and corporate investment and high levels of debt. Despite public
deficits that began larger than those in many other European nations and remain high
at 5.4 percent of GDP, general government expenditure has contracted as a share
of GDP since 2008 because both government revenue and expenditure grew more
slowly than GDP. With its own currency, the United Kingdom has been engaging in
more expansionary monetary policy than the Eurozone. Robust growth has returned.
Corporations are becoming more optimistic.
Households continue to deleverage and
have reduced debt substantially below 2008 levels. After dipping sharply, household
investment has recovered and grown 8 percent in nominal terms since the crisis. The
corporate sector continues to deleverage more slowly.
ƒƒ In France, household debt was low before the crisis and remains small in comparison
with other large European nations, but household investment is down after a steep
increase in real estate prices.
Other sectors have experienced weak growth in nominal
terms, while the trade balance is deteriorating. The public sector expanded by
approximately four percentage points of GDP between 2008 and 2014 and has a deficit
of 4.4 percent of GDP in continued violation of the Fiscal Compact. France still has a
potential GDP output gap of 2.3 percent.
ƒƒ Italy’s household debt remains low despite an increase before the crisis.
Household and
business investment rates have declined slightly, and GDP growth has declined further
from very low levels even before the crisis. Household consumption has hardly grown
despite a material reduction in the savings rate as wage growth has been slow and even,
at times, negative. Public debt, at around 128 percent of GDP, is very high.
Italy has been
able to reduce its deficit below the threshold specified by the Fiscal Compact and run
a primary surplus, but its debt is large enough that it will take many years to reach the
debt target. Italy’s output gap—at almost 5 percent of potential GDP—remains one of the
biggest of the large European nations.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
159
. Exhibit 94
The largest European economies have significantly different priorities and spending capacities
% of GDP unless noted
Domain
Indicator
Germany France
Output gap
to close
-0.8
United
Kingdom Sweden
Spain
Italy
-2.3
-6.0
-4.5
-0.8
-1.6
-0.8
United
States
Europe1
-1.3
-0.5
-2.4
Poland Romania
Net exports
Current account balance
2007
7.0
-1.1
-9.6
-1.4
-2.7
9.0
-6.5
-14.0
-5.0
-0.5
2013
6.9
-2.0
1.5
1.0
-4.2
6.5
-1.4
-1.4
-2.5
1.4
-1.9
0.0
Corporate (non-financial)
Corporate
debt
2004
2008
2012/13/14
150
0
Business
investment2
25
0
Household
Household
debt
100
0
Household
investment2
10
0
20
Household
savings rate3
%
0
Public
Public debt 150
0
Fiscal capacity4
To reduce debt to
60% of GDP in
20 years (approx.)
1.3
-4.8
-8.2
-7.8
To reach 3% deficit
3.2
-1.4
-2.6
0.0
-2.4
0.6
-0.4
0.9
Investment
opportunities2
2.0
2.3
3.4
4.6
2.4
0.9
6.5
12.9
1.7–3.7
1 Figures for Europe-30 where available, or extrapolated figures for subset (Europe-27, Europe-28, etc.).
2 Figures for business and household investments are defined as gross fixed capital formation expressed as a percentage of GDP for the business and
households sectors. Investment opportunities listed under “Public” include a selection of private and public opportunities—and could include partnerships.
3 Household savings rates are gross saving as percentage of gross disposable income
4 Fiscal capacity under current debt rules assumes no effect on growth—United Kingdom, Sweden, and Poland are not bound by the Fiscal Compact debt
reduction rules.
NOTE: Not to scale.
SOURCE: Eurostat; AMECO; IMF; FRED; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
160
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. Europe has several options for igniting investment and job creation
Now is the time for Europe to consider all feasible options for igniting investment and
job creation. While there are different economic schools of thought on demand (and the
neoclassical view would negate the need for stimulus) the sector analysis in the previous
section, in our view, provides proof that, without measures to shore up investment and job
creation, a strong recovery seems difficult at best and Europe’s debt overhang will only
increase (Exhibit 95).
Exhibit 95
Outside of a neo-classical view of the crisis, measures will be required to stimulate
investment and job creation
Commonalities
Neoclassical economics:
Rational expectations
(Robert Lucas)
New Keynesianism:
Liquidity trap
(Paul Krugman)
Post-Keynesian:
Balance sheet recession
(Richard Koo)
Diagnosis
of the
ongoing
crisis
ï‚§ Financial crisis as a temporary
shock to the economy caused
by a liquidity crisis
ï‚§ Stagnation as a consequence
of overextension of the
government in the economy
(over-regulation and
overspending on welfare)
ï‚§ Stagnation as consequence of
uncertainty and volatility in
private investment demand
ï‚§ After the crash, households
have a higher propensity to
save at any given interest
rate,1 so that rates would have
to drop sharply to spur
spending (“liquidity trap” at the
zero-lower bound)
ï‚§ Risk of a permanent
depression
ï‚§ Stagnation as consequence of
an inherently unstable
economy that creates creditfuelled bubbles
ï‚§ As households are left with a
debt overhang and binding
balance sheet constraints,
savings are inelastic with
respect to changes in the
interest rate
ï‚§ Risk of a permanent
depression/deflationary spiral
Role for
monetary
policy
ï‚§ Case for temporary monetary
policy measures to stimulate
bank lending; longer-term
need to keep money supply in
line with production to avoid
over- or under-supply
ï‚§ Case for unconventional
monetary policy to drive up
inflation expectations and thus
drive real interest rates below
the zero lower bound of
nominal rates (e.g., QE)
ï‚§ Limited/no role for monetary
policy since saving/borrowing
decisions do not respond to
changes in the interest rate
because the money multiplier
is zero
Role for
fiscal
policy
ï‚§ Case for fiscal contraction and
deregulation/supply-side
reforms, since the economy
will return to equilibrium if
unimpeded by distortionary
government policy and
spending (“expansionary
austerity”)
ï‚§ Case for expansive fiscal
policy to support aggregate
demand
ï‚§ Case for expansive fiscal
policy to support aggregate
demand; explicit prescription
to fully offset private-sector
deleveraging through publicsector borrowing and spending
1 Propensity to save meaning tendency to run a financial surplus.
SOURCE: Richard C. Koo, “The world in balance sheet recession: Causes, cure, and politics”, Real-World Economics Review, issue number 58, 2011; Paul
Krugman Blog; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Recent discussions on stimulating investment and job creation have tended to focus
narrowly on the traditional prescription of additional fiscal spending and quantitative easing.
But spending within the Fiscal Compact as well as QE will likely be insufficient to drive the
recovery without additional measures. Moreover, loosening the Fiscal Compact, mutualising
debt, or stepping up transfer payments appears impossible in the current Eurozone
institutional framework.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
161
.
However, more feasible options with significant potential effects receive relatively little
discussion (Exhibit 96). These include choices such as changing public-accounting
standards so that investments are activated on a public balance sheet and depreciated over
time rather than being accounted for immediately as a deficit in the year in which they occur.
Another option is stimulating private consumption, for instance by carefully adjusting tax
structures to reduce the burden on labour while increasing taxation on property and capital
gains, or by creating attractive services that help unleash spending by older people in the
economy. There is also the possibility of opting for more radical options with little or no track
record, such as issuing vouchers redeemable by the ECB directly to the populace. This
approach has strong potential to increase investment and job creation while reducing the
risk of deflation, but, with the exception of a small number of commentators, has not been
part of the mainstream debate.222
Exhibit 96
A menu of investment and job creation options can complement structural reform even outside a federal setup
Prerequisites for all options: Progress on competitiveness and growth drivers and structural reform
Addresses
>50% of
aggregate
demand gap
Fiscal stimulus and debt relief
ï‚§ Introducing cyclical flexibility
beyond 3% in the Fiscal
Compact
ï‚§ Partially mutualising debt
Issuing
vouchers
redeemable
with the
ECB to
households1
Demand
impact
Options deserving wider debate
ï‚§ Accounting for public
investments as they depreciate
ï‚§ Carefully adjusting taxation and
wage structures
ï‚§ Unleashing the silver economy
Improved monetary and
financing conditions
Addresses
<50% of
aggregate
demand gap
ï‚§ Quantitative easing
ï‚§ Expanding fiscal-transfer
schemes between countries
(possibly including debt
restructuring)
ï‚§ Improving access to finance for
businesses and increasing
European Investment Bank lending
ï‚§ Maximising spending within the
Fiscal Compact
Requires “European Federation” with
common fiscal and economic policy to
establish trust and avoid moral hazard
Conceivable in current
“Maastricht +” setup
Feasibility
1 Debate persists over whether this option would constitute hidden fiscal policy.
NOTE: There is a neoclassical school of thought that argues that structural reform is enough; however, our analyses clearly indicate a structural weakness in
demand across all sectors of the economy in line with the balance sheet recession or liquidity trap school of thought.
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Willem H.
Buiter, Helicopter money: Irredeemable fiat money and the liquidity trap, NBER working paper
number 10163, December 2003. Commentators including Lord Adair Turner and Financial Times columnist
Martin Wolf have promoted the concept.
222
162
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
.
All options for increasing investment and job creation entail risk and may have possibly
unintended, often distributional, consequences that require careful consideration. For
instance, making it easier for corporations or households to access finance could, if done
carelessly, cause a build-up of excessive debt like the one that led to the 2008 crisis.
Changing tax regimes can have unintended consequences either by changing incentive
structures in a deleterious way or by causing capital flight. Debt monetisation would require
very strong governance and reinforced central-bank independence to avoid overuse by
governments and inflation. Redistributive policies that support the deleveraging of debtors
through one mechanism or another can create moral hazard.
Mitigating the risks associated with the fiscal, monetary, and redistributive options that
are available requires careful design and trade-offs, but inaction is not an option.
Every
extra year of low growth shrinks the long-term path of the economy. The risks of deflation
in Europe are uncomfortably high. Forecasts for Eurozone inflation in the remainder of
2015 and 2016 are still well below the target rate.
Deflation in a context of deleveraging is
dangerous because it becomes harder to repay debt.
Which, if any, of the options we discuss in this chapter is pursued and what specific policies
should be deployed to achieve any of these outcomes is a decision for policy makers rather
than economists because many of these choices entail some form of redistribution in the
broader economy and may have unintended consequences. It is for this reason that we
present a range of options that we believe, with humility, deserve broader debate. While we
reflect on the feasibility and effectiveness of the options presented, we do not advocate any
one specific solution.
In the Eurozone, the traditional prescription of higher fiscal spending and debt
relief cannot be easily replicated
During a balance sheet recession—one in which companies and households en masse opt
to deleverage, potentially resulting in deflation and rising debt burdens in real terms—the role
of government is especially important in shoring up investment and job creation and thereby
helping to accelerate private-sector deleveraging.223
The example of Finland and Sweden in the early 1990s is telling.
After a financial crisis
induced by a burst asset-price bubble, both countries faced deep recessions (Exhibit 97).
The governments of these two countries nationalised bank assets, particularly bad ones,
and attempted to cushion the impact of the recession by expanding public debt by 15
percentage points of GDP in the first two years after the crisis. They went on to expand the
public-debt-to-GDP ratio by 21 percentage points over the following four to six years.224 This
helped the private sector in both countries deleverage by 26 percentage points of GDP while
keeping growth positive. Tellingly, public-sector deleveraging did not begin until after GDP
growth started to recover and private debt levels began to fall.
Richard C.
Koo, “The world in balance sheet recession: Causes, cure, and politics”, Real-world Economics
Review, issue number 58, 2011.
224
Debt and deleveraging: Uneven progress on the path to growth, McKinsey Global Institute, January 2012.
223
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
163
. Exhibit 97
Episodes of successful private-sector deleveraging
have been supported by public-sector spending
ILLUSTRATIVE
Average of Swedish and Finnish deleveraging episodes
Deleveraging
Recession
Real GDP
Private
debt/GDP
Public
debt/GDP
Pre-crisis
period
Early stage
of
recession
Private-sector
deleveraging
Rebound and
public-sector
deleveraging
10 years
1–2 years
4–6 years
~10 years
-3%
1%
3%
Real GDP growth
3%
Annual average (%)
Time
Change in debt/GDP
Percentage points
â–ª
â–ª
Private sector
60
8
-26
87
Public sector
3
15
21
-30
SOURCE: IMF; Haver Analytics; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
In contrast, European governments today have begun to reduce debt levels at a time when
the private sector has deleveraged by only about five percentage points of GDP relative
to their position when they left recession in the first quarter of 2009. The countries of the
Eurozone have attempted to contain deficits and debt levels through such institutional
vehicles as the Fiscal Compact (see Box 6, “The Fiscal Compact”).
164
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. Box 6. The Fiscal Compact
The fiscal rules that today govern the members of the
Fiscal Compact grew out of the convergence criteria of
the Maastricht treaty of 1993 that European economies
were required to meet before being allowed to join
the euro. The convergence criteria specified limits
of 60 percent of GDP for debt and 3 percent of GDP
for budget deficits, set a reference value for inflation,
established exchange rate stability, and gave guidance on
long-term interest rates. The aim of setting these criteria
was to ensure that any economy joining the monetary
union was sufficiently “harmonised” with other members
to limit the risk of economic imbalances developing
that could not be mitigated by unilateral currency
devaluation and/or independent changes in monetary
policy—a flexibility that was no longer available in the
monetary union.
These limits were converted into fiscal rules for
Eurozone members, and the other EU member states
that voluntarily subscribe to it, through the Stability
and Growth Pact in 1998 and 1999.
This set out an
enforcement mechanism whereby countries could be
fined up to 0.3 percent of GDP if they broke the rules
and were found not to have a good reason for doing so.
This procedure proved toothless, as both Germany and
France broke the limits of the pact in the early 2000s
and faced no consequences. The then-president of the
European Commission, Romano Prodi, described the
pact as “stupid” in 2002.1
The pact has since been reformed and strengthened
several times, most recently as the Fiscal Compact in the
Treaty on Stability, Coordination, and Governance that
came into force in 16 countries in 2013 and nine more in
2014. Key points in the current framework include:
ƒƒ Countries are obliged to keep deficits below 3 percent
of GDP, while also targeting a structural deficit of no
more than 0.5 percent of GDP.2
ƒƒ Countries are obliged to keep general government
debt below 60 percent of GDP, and if above the limit,
they must close 1/20th of the gap to that threshold
annually.3
ƒƒ Countries are obliged to transpose the stipulations
of the Fiscal Compact into national law—and
are encouraged to make the stipulations
constitutional provisions.
Quoted in an interview with Romano Prodi in Le Monde, “Le pacte
de stabilité est-il stupide?” November 15, 2002.
2
In some instances, a structural budget deficit of 1 percent of GDP
is allowed.
3
This must happen, on average, over three-year periods.
However,
it is rarely enforced. For example, although Belgium and Italy are
unlikely to reach the debt target of 60 percent of GDP anytime soon,
neither is currently subject to the excessive deficit procedure.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
1
ƒƒ Successive treaties have made penalties clearer,
more automatic, and harder to avoid, and they have
increased the oversight faced by countries in the
excessive deficit procedure (EDP).
The original limits were intended as membership criteria
for monetary union rather than as fiscal rules. Some
commentators suggest that the choice of numbers,
particularly for the debt limit, may have been influenced by
a desire to exclude some nations from the union.4
Most purpose-built fiscal rules are very different from
those of the Fiscal Compact.
Typically, a more explicit
adjustment is made for changes in the business cycle
or the main drivers of government revenue. It is also rare
to have a fiscal rule that does not have a mechanism
to actively encourage a surplus during good times—a
property known as symmetry. Observers of the Fiscal
Compact have been particularly critical of the 60 percent
debt limit, calling it “devoid of theoretical value” and
“arbitrary and neither necessary nor sufficient for national
fiscal-financial sustainability”.5
An example of a purpose-made fiscal rule is the one used
by Switzerland.
The rule stabilises government spending
over the economic cycle. When the economy is running
below potential, the government can spend more than it
earns. When the economy is operating above potential,
the government must put money aside.6 Enforcement
of the rule as well as an incentive to estimate correctly
comes from the use of a compensation account.
Any
overspending, including that due to poor forecasting, is
debited to the compensation account. Once the account
passes a threshold, the government must budget to bring
the account into credit within three years.7
A similar rule, applied across all of Europe and adjusted
for the relative sizes of government spending, would
require most European economies to cut their deficits.
Among the members of the Fiscal Compact, it would
require deficit cuts of roughly €60 billion.
Willem H. Buiter, “The ‘sense and nonsense of Maastricht’ revisited:
What have we learnt about stabilization in EMU?” Journal of
Common Market Studies, volume 44, issue 4, November 2006.
5
See Panos C.
Afxentiou, “Convergence, the Maastricht criteria,
and their benefits”, The Brown Journal of World Affairs, volume
VII, issue 1, winter-spring 2000, and Willem H. Buiter, “The ‘sense
and nonsense of Maastricht’ revisited: What have we learnt about
stabilization in EMU?” Journal of Common Market Studies, volume
44, issue 4, November 2006.
6
Alain Geier, The debt brake: The Swiss fiscal rule at the federal level,
Swiss Federal Finance Administration working paper number 15,
February 2011.
7
The problem of bias in forecasting is substantial. Even with an
external body standardising forecasts as in the EU, countries have
a substantial optimistic bias in forecasts that becomes larger further
into the future.
This is especially the case in EU countries that risk
going above the 3 percent deficit limit. See Jeffrey A. Frankel and
Jesse Schreger, “Over-optimistic forecasts and fiscal rules in the
Eurozone”, Review of World Economics, volume 149, issue 2,
June 2013.
165
4
.
Independent fiscal regimes in a monetary union require either stringent rules to control
deficits or credible no-bailout commitments to avoid requiring some countries to pay the bill
for high deficits in another country within the union (Exhibit 98).
Exhibit 98
Many investment and job creation measures are not viable in the current Eurozone setup
Two stable regimes in a currency union
Current European setup
“Gold Standard/Maastricht +”
“European Federation”
â–ª Independent sovereign
â–ª Key fiscal and economic policies
â–ª
decisions for fiscal and economic
policies
Stringent fiscal rules to avoid
moral hazard from implicit
guarantees across the currency
union
and/or
â–ª Strict “no-bailout” rule put into
decided at the federal level as a
means to avoid moral hazard and
ensure trust for:
– Debt mutualisation and
common liabilities across the
federation
– Fiscal flexibility
– Fiscal transfers
practice including clear regime for
sovereign bankruptcy to ensure
exposure to financial market
discipline
Setup for countries under EDP
Sovereignty partially limited via bailout conditions
in return for debt guarantees and fiscal flexibility
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Although the Fiscal Compact has been criticised for aggravating the shortage in demand at
a time when the private sector deleverages, it has had the benefit of helping to restore trust
among Eurozone nations. It paved the way for bailouts of highly indebted economies, limited
restructuring of government debt in Greece, and later bolder action and a commitment by
Mario Draghi, president of the European Central Bank, to do “whatever it takes” to preserve
the currency union (Exhibit 99).225 The Fiscal Compact is also an important step towards
removing the moral hazard embedded in a monetary union among economies that retain
national fiscal policies.
Mario Draghi said, “Within our mandate, the ECB is ready to do whatever it takes to preserve the euro.
And believe me, it will be enough”. The commitment was made during a speech at the Global Investment
Conference in London on July 26, 2012.
225
166
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
.
Exhibit 99
Decisive action was necessary to calm markets and restore access to credit
German-Spanish spread on long-term bonds1
Percentage points
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
2007
08
09
10
11
May 2010
EFSF and EFSM established2
12
December 2011
LTRO1 by ECB
January 2012
Fiscal compact finalised
February
LTRO2 by ECB
March
Fiscal Compact signed;
Greek debt restructuring
13
2014
January 2013
Fiscal Compact in force
September
ESM established3
July
Draghi pledges to do
“whatever it takes”
June
Spanish bank rescue
announcement
1 Difference in yields of long-term euro-denominated bonds issued by Spain and Germany.
2 European Financial Stability Facility and European Financial Stabilisation Mechanism.
3 European Stability Mechanism.
SOURCE: Datastream; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Maximising spending within the Fiscal Compact would allow around €50 billion in
additional fiscal expenditure
The Fiscal Compact sets clear targets for countries to maintain deficits below 3 percent
of GDP and debt below 60 percent of GDP.226 While some countries currently exceed the
deficit limit, including the major economies of France and Spain, other economies have
headroom for additional spending. These countries could increase their borrowing without
breaking the rules of the Fiscal Compact. Even those countries that are above the debt limit,
but not the deficit limit, could potentially increase spending.227
The Fiscal Compact sets out separate requirements for structural and total deficits. The structural deficit must
be below 0.5 percent of GDP, while the noncyclically adjusted deficit must be below 3 percent of GDP.
227
Countries are expected in most cases to reduce their debt levels by 1/20th of the gap between their existing
debt and the 60 percent target every year, on average.
In some cases, like Germany, this would set a
1.5 percent deficit limit, after growth forecasts are considered. In other cases, like Italy, this requirement is
plainly unmanageable. Italy’s debt stands at 135 percent of GDP and therefore Italy would have to reduce
its debt by 3.5 percent of GDP.
This would require budget cuts of more than 6 percent of GDP even after
accounting for growth.
226
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
167
. If countries that have less than 3 percent deficits were to increase their spending to reach
the deficit limit, but those with debt above 60 percent with extra spending capacity worked
towards meeting their debt reduction targets, additional spending capacity of €48 billion
would be created. Germany would account for €39 billion of that capacity. However,
because Germany’s economy has a negligible output gap, this additional spending would
have little effect on aggregate demand. After applying fiscal multipliers, the overall demand
effect is likely to lie between €15 billion and €49 billion.
This large range reflects considerable
uncertainty around the size of the fiscal multiplier (see Box 7, “Fiscal multipliers”). What’s
more, the effect of that spending on Southern European economies facing the largest
shortages in demand is unclear, as Southern European exports to Germany account for
only 2.4 percent of Southern European GDP.
Box 7. Fiscal multipliers
When a government spends, the impact on aggregate demand can be larger or smaller
than the absolute amount spent.
On the one hand, fiscal expenditure can circulate through
the economy as suppliers to government procurement hire more workers who in turn
have more money to spend on their needs. On the other hand, government spending may
simply displace private-sector spending or increase imports, leaving aggregate demand
largely unaffected.
For our calculations of the size of fiscal multipliers in cases where empirical estimates for the
fiscal multiplier of a nation during recession were not available, we have drawn on the IMF’s
methodology suggested for calculating back-of-the-envelope fiscal multipliers. This process
has led to a range of fiscal multipliers such as 0.2 to 1.0 for Germany or 1.6 to 2.1 for Italy
(see the appendix for full details).
Many factors affect the fiscal multiplier:
ƒƒ Output gap.
Large output gaps mean larger multipliers as the economy has more
capacity before government spending crowds out private activity.
ƒƒ Monetary policy. Countries with monetary policy near the zero lower bound have higher
multipliers because monetary policy will be less sensitive to changes in demand.
ƒƒ Trade openness. Closed economies typically have higher multipliers as spending does
not lead to additional imports.
ƒƒ Exchange rate.
Countries with fixed exchange rates have higher multipliers, as
exchange rates will not move to offset increased spending.
ƒƒ Debt level. Countries with low debts have higher multipliers as increased spending
does not lead to businesses and households embarking on precautionary saving in the
expectation of higher taxes or interest rates.
ƒƒ Labour market rigidity. Countries with rigid labour markets have higher multipliers
because rigid wages mean spending creates more new jobs rather than just inflating
wages and prices.
ƒƒ Automatic stabilisers.
Countries with smaller stabilisers have higher multipliers
because the new demand reduces unemployment payments, for example, and
increases tax take that counteracts the output effect.
ƒƒ Public administration. Countries that are better run have higher multipliers because
money is spent more effectively.1
1
168
Nicoletta Batini et al., Fiscal multipliers: Size, determinants and use in macroeconomic projections, IMF,
October 2014.
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
.
Introducing cyclical flexibility beyond 3 percent in the Fiscal Compact would help
but is hardly conceivable in the current Eurozone setup
Throughout the recession, incremental government spending, also known as the fiscal
impulse, in Europe has been substantially below that of the United States. At its peak, in
2009, the US structural fiscal impulse—the magnitude of change structural spending—was
2.2 percentage points of GDP larger than Europe’s.228 This may explain at least part of the
difference in real GDP growth between the two regions.
A European fiscal
impulse of
2.2%
of GDP could have
maximum
impact of
€440B
If Europe implemented a one-time fiscal impulse of 2.2 percent of GDP—increasing
spending uniformly by 2.2 percentage points—the impact on the size of the output gap
would be dramatic. A rough estimate—it can only be rough since this impact is larger than
the total output gap—suggests a maximum impact in the order of €440 billion, including
fiscal multipliers. As the output gap shrinks due to the stimulus, one would expect additional
government spending to be less effective and multipliers to change.
A government that is willing to rewrite the rules when expedient, even for a short time, might
be expected by financial markets to do so again.
As such, a change to fiscal rules to allow
more spending for only a short time might be treated by the markets similarly to how they
would treat a long-term change. This would effectively require Europe to mutualise the debt
of the more indebted and currently economically weaker nations, and it would likely require a
federal institutional framework to avoid the associated moral hazard.
Partially mutualising debt can lower the cost of borrowing if governance issues
could be resolved
A partial mutualisation of European debt could remove concerns over the solvency of
the continent’s most indebted governments and lower average interest rates across the
continent. But major governance changes would be required to avoid moral hazard.
Although all Eurozone members issue government debt in euros, each country is liable for
its own debt.
If the Greek government cannot repay its debt, it is the Greek government
that must default. Other Eurozone countries are not liable for the debt simply because they
share a currency. That is the official version.
However, the Greek debt crisis and subsequent
bailout by the IMF, ECB, and European Commission demonstrate that national debts of
countries within the Eurozone are not, in reality, separate. Because European economies are
so deeply intertwined, debt default has enormous externalities. Eurozone debt is ambiguous
and involves an implicit partial guarantee.
Despite convergence in recent years, there is still a significant spread between the eurodenominated debts of different countries.
Although yields on Greek debt are well below
their 2011 peaks, spreads over the German bund remained around seven percentage
points even before the renewed discussion in 2015 about a potential exit of Greece from
the Eurozone. When perceptions of risk are heightened, a “flight to safety” causes the yield
on some countries’ debt to drop to negligible levels, while other countries can still face very
high yields. At its peak, the yield differential between Greek and German debt exceeded
25 percentage points, effectively shutting Greece out of sovereign debt markets and
jeopardising its ability to engage in counter-cyclical spending (Exhibit 100).
Weak economies
in recession can experience soaring interest rates at exactly the point at which they most
need to be able to borrow.
Mutualising debt would reduce the effect of a flight to safety, enabling peripheral economies
to have a functioning fiscal policy even during difficult times. It would also reduce overall
borrowing costs because the risk of default of the Eurozone as a whole is small. In addition,
Based on the change in structural and total deficit reported by the IMF.
228
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
169
.
the liquidity premium charged by the market would fall, especially in the case of small
economies with less liquid sovereign debt markets.
Exhibit 100
Debt mutualisation reduces pro-cyclical financing effects harmful to economies
when they can least bear the cost
German-Greek spread on long-term bonds1
Real Greek GDP growth2
Interest rate
%
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
-5
-10
2007
08
09
10
11
12
13
2014
1 Difference in yields of long-term government bonds issued by Greece and Germany.
2 Annual real rate of change of GDP in Greece.
SOURCE: Eurostat; S&P; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Mutualisation can occur in many ways. It is possible to issue only part of a government’s
debt as mutual debt and to grant it senior or junior status relative to national debt. For
example, on the one hand, countries could decide to mutualise only the riskiest parts of debt
in order to keep borrowing costs lower. On the other hand, countries might decide not to
put their collective name on debt in jeopardy but to mutualise only the safest debt.
By doing
so, individual countries would remain responsible for high levels of debt while reducing
the borrowing cost of the bulk of their debt. The first approach would do more to protect
weak economies from a flight to safety, but it would increase moral hazard. The exact
details of a “Eurobond” would require extensive negotiation depending on the particular
risk preferences of members of the Eurozone and the political compromises they are willing
to make.
Debt mutualisation would reduce the cost of borrowing.
A range of econometric models
suggest that the cost of mutualised debt would be between 10 and 60 basis points higher
than the rate on a German bund.229 Based on 2013 borrowing rates and taking the interest
rate on ten-year government bonds as representative, governments would have saved
229
170
See Sergio Mayordomo, Juan Ignacio Peña, and Eduardo S. Schwartz, Towards a common European
Monetary Union risk free rate, NBER working paper number 15353, September 2009; Green paper on the
feasibility of introducing stability bonds, European Commission, November 2011; Christian Aßmann and
Jens Boysen-Hogrefe, Determinants of government bond spreads in the Euro area—in good times as in
bad, Kiel working paper number 1548, September 2009; European banks: All eyes on funding: LCR, the next
undiscounted regulatory headwind, JP Morgan, 2011; Patrick Artus, The effect of debt mutualisation in the
euro zone would be more complex than what is usually claimed, Natixis economic research, number 560,
August 2013; Carlo Favero and Alessandro Missale, Sovereign spreads in the euro area: Which prospects
for a Eurobond? presented at an Economic Policy panel meeting in Warsaw, October 27–28, 2011; Séverine
Menguy, “Can Eurobonds save the euro?” in States, banks and the financing of the economy: Monetary
policy and regulatory perspective, Morten Balling, Ernest Gnan, and Patricia Jackson, eds., SUERF, 2013;
Sylvester C. W.
Eijffinger, “Eurobonds—concepts and implications”, in Eurobonds: Concepts and implications:
Compilation of notes for the monetary dialogue of March 2011, European Parliament, March 2011; Rien
Wagenvoort and Sanne Zwart, Uncovering the common risk-free rate in the European Monetary Union,
European Investment Bank economic and financial report number 2010/05, September 2010.
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. €6.4 billion to €8.5 billion every year over the life of the bonds issued that year alone, or
as much as €85 billion in total (although some, such as Germany, would have had to pay
more) (Exhibit 101). Taking into account the fiscal multiplier and assuming that all savings
on interest payments are spent rather than used to reduce deficits, the effect on aggregate
demand would be €30 billion to €65 billion annually.
Debt mutualisation amplifies moral hazard. If borrowing costs are mutualised, the effect
of any one country’s fiscal profligacy on the cost of borrowing will be small, increasing
the incentive to borrow beyond a country’s means. For this reason, debt mutualisation
cannot be safely implemented without extremely robust governance of reliable fiscal rules,
stringent criteria on what parts of debt can be mutualised, or, indeed, full economic and
fiscal integration.
Exhibit 101
Lower interest rates resulting from debt mutualisation could have saved the Eurozone
as much as €85 billion on ten-year maturities alone vs.
2013
Hypothetical mutualised
borrowing, 2013
Actual borrowing, 2013
Borrowing requirement
€ billion
Spain
Interest rate on long-term
debt, average
%
89.3
Italy
2.1
Netherlands
Austria
0.4–0.5
0.1–0.2
2.4
3.2
Cyprus
0–0.7
3.8
21.8
Slovenia
0.9–1.0
2.2
25.0
Belgium
1.0–1.3
6.3
123.0
Ireland
1.9–2.0
4.3
21.2
France
Slovakia
2.1–2.6
10.1
47.9
Portugal
Potential average saving on
cost of borrowing1
€ billion
4.6
23.7
Greece
EXCLUDES
FISCAL MULTIPLIER
~0.1
5.8
~0.1
6.5
21.7
~0.1
2.0
3.0
<1
3.2
12.7
<1
2.0
Latvia
0.5
3.3
<1
Malta
0.3
3.4
<1
Luxembourg
0.1
Germany
<1
1.9
28.6
1.6
<0
1 Reduction in annual cost of debt issued in 2013 if rate went from actual rate to an estimated Eurobond rate with a value 10–60 basis points higher than the
German rate.
2 Countries in EDP might use their savings to reduce borrowing rather than create demand, which would not contribute to closing the output gap in the short
term.
SOURCE: Eurostat; ECB; Mayordomo et al., 2009; European Commission green paper, 2011; Aβmann et al., 2011; JP Morgan, 2011; Artus, 2011; Favero and
Missale, 2011; Menguy, 2013; Eijffinger, 2011; Wagenvoort and Zwart, 2010; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
171
. Expanding fiscal transfer schemes among countries could close the output gap if
Europe were to further integrate fiscal and economic policies
The overall size of the EU budget is small compared with the size of European economies.
In Europe, the average absolute net contribution/receipt of EU member countries was
1.6 percent of GDP in 2013.230 For comparison, the average absolute net contribution/
receipt between US states and the federal government was 8.4 percent.231 Transfers
between European states are far less distributive than they are in the United States. The net
contribution in Europe is only weakly responsive to relative per capita GDP at purchasing
power parity, while the sensitivity in the United States is very strong (Exhibit 102).
Exhibit 102
Transfer payments are much bigger in the United States than they are in Europe
Net contribution, 20131
% of GDP
Europe
8
United States
West North Central
6
4
West
South
Central
East North Central
2
Italy
Mountain
0
France
Middle Atlantic
New England
Germany
Nordics Other
Western
Europe
United Kingdom
and Ireland
Mediterranean
-2
Pacific
Central and
Eastern Europe
-4
-6
South Atlantic
-8
The mean absolute redistribution in Europe
is 1.6% of GDP compared with 8.4% in the
United States. Europe’s transfers are
therefore roughly 19% of the US level
-10
-12
East South Central
-14
60
65
70
75
80
85
90
95
100
105
110
115
120
125
130
Per capita GDP at purchasing power parity, 2013
Index: 100 = EU and the United States, respectively
1 In the United States, total federal spending in state inclusive of all programmes and transfers less total federal tax revenue generated in state including
business, income, employment, estates, railroad, gift, and excise tax. In the EU, total expenditure on all programmes including co-payments less all revenue
generated by nations including traditional own resources (e.g., excise and agricultural tax).
SOURCE: European data: European Commission, and Eurostat; US data: Inland Revenue Service; USASpending.gov, States’ Departments of Labor and
Workforce Development; US Census Bureau; Bureau of Economic Analysis; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
The unweighted average of the absolute value of contribution/receipt for each country.
This figure is somewhat
inflated by the contributions of small countries such as Hungary, which received 5.0 percent of its GDP in net.
231
Based on a refreshed version of the analysis found in Zsolt Darvas, Fiscal federalism in crisis: Lessons for
Europe from the US, Bruegel, July 2010.
230
172
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. The comparison with the United States is useful, not because Europe ought to emulate the
United States, but because it gives a directional illustration of the magnitude of the fiscal
transfers required for a successful monetary union. In the United States, for example, Florida
was hit particularly badly by the recession; its unemployment rate peaked at 11 percent.
If the state had had its own currency, it would have been able to devalue to restore
competitiveness. Instead, Florida received 17.9 percent of its GDP through federal transfers
in 2013. In contrast, unemployment in Spain reached 26 percent as a result of the recent
economic crisis, but it received transfers of only 0.2 percent of GDP.232
The composition of transfers is also relevant.
Most European transfers are linked
to agriculture and do not act as an economic stabiliser. Transfer schemes linked to
unemployment rates would have a strong stabilising effect. Alternatively, fiscal transfers
might redirect public investment to where it is most productive.
For example, a common
European renewables subsidy scheme, coupled with a more integrated power sector, would
promote investment in solar plants in Spain and Italy to produce energy for German and
French consumers.
Although the impact on demand depends heavily on the details of how any expanded
fiscal transfer system is designed, it is possible to get a rough idea of the potential scale of
such approaches (Exhibit 103). Assuming a hypothetical unemployment benefit transfer
programme in which all Europeans pay in according to existing EU funding ratios, the effect
on demand would be between €38 billion and €56 billion, as money would flow from strong
countries to crisis-hit countries with large fiscal multipliers.233 Any such programme would
require further fiscal and economic policy integration in Europe.
Another important protection for Florida was the free movement of labour. Many Floridians moved to other
states with more prosperous economies.
233
This assumes that countries move their entire unemployment benefit through this package, giving a
replacement rate of 50 to 70 percent, as is typical in European economies.
The benefit comes from the fact
that more of the payments come from countries with smaller output gaps where additional fiscal spending is
less effective and go to countries with larger output gaps where it is more effective.
232
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
173
. Exhibit 103
A pan-European transfer programme could benefit from
higher fiscal multipliers in worse-off economies
INCLUDES FISCAL MULTIPLIER—
LOWER BOUND SHOWN
Unemployment benefit programme—implementation example
National net benefit from policy, 20141
€ billion
Gap
Spain
Fiscal
multiplier2
33.1
Additional multiplier effect
possible in 20143
€ billion
1.3–2.5
Greece
4.1
1.1–1.6
Italy
3.7
43.1
4.4
1.6–2.1
6.0
France
1.6
0.2–2.1
0.3
Portugal
1.0
0.8–1.2
0.8
Croatia
0.7
0.5–0.8
0.4
Cyprus
0.4
0.8–1.2
0.3
Slovakia
0.3
1.2–1.7
0.3
Ireland
0.2
0.5–0.8
0.1
Slovenia
0
1.2 –1.6
0
0
Sweden
-0.1
0.6–1.0
Malta
-0.1
0.9–1.3
-0.1
Bulgaria
-0.1
0.9–1.3
-0.1
Latvia
-0.1
0.9–1.2
-0.1
Estonia
-0.2
0.8 –1.2
-0.1
Lithuania
-0.2
0.9–1.3
-0.2
Luxembourg
-0.2
1.1–1.6
-0.2
Finland
-0.2
0.7–1.0
-0.2
Hungary
-0.7
0.1–0.3
-0.1
Czech Republic
-1.2
0.6–0.9
-0.7
Denmark
-1.7
0.7–1.1
-1.2
Romania
-1.8
0.5–0.7
-0.8
Poland
-1.8
0.1–0.3
-0.2
Austria
-2.5
0.6–0.9
Netherlands
-2.9
1.3–1.9
-3.9
Belgium
-3.4
1.1–1.5
-3.6
United Kingdom
-3.9
0.1–1.0
Germany
-24.2
0.2–1.0
-1.5
-0.4
-4.8
Total opportunity =
€37.6–56.0 billion
1 Based on national unemployment figures and a benefit equal to 50–70% of nominal median income in that country (based on typical EU unemployment
replacement rates) and a contribution distribution proportional to current EU contribution.
2 Back-of-the-envelope estimate based on IMF methodology.
3 Based on the assumption that total governmental spending is fixed and just involves spending in more efficient geographies.
NOTE: Assumes a pan-European unemployment benefit of 50–70% of local per capita median income. The scheme is funded proportionally to the current EU
funding formulas.
SOURCE: Eurostat; European Commission; IMF; Salomäki and Munzi, 1999; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
174
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. Measures to unlock financing for companies, as well as increased lending by the
EIB, can help but may prove insufficient on their own
Access to finance, particularly for SMEs, is a hot topic of discussion. SMEs have historically
found it harder to access credit than larger firms.234 While the scope for increasing demand
is likely to be smaller than what can be achieved in the public and household sector, there
is still room to improve access to finance for these firms, particularly in badly affected
parts of the European economy. Proposals include improving liquidity for bank lending via
liquidity facilities or secondary markets, establishing a stronger European capital market
for securitised debt, or improving equity financing through simpler private placements or
removing tax distortions favouring debt financing. Many programmes to improve access to
finance are already under way (Exhibit 104).
Exhibit 104
Several measures have been proposed to strengthen and diversify funding sources,
particularly for SMEs
Measures that have been proposed
Accelerate the
cleanup of bank
balance sheets
NOT EXHAUSTIVE
Suggested by
Increase the incentives for prudent bank provisioning and write-offs and ï‚§ IMF
ensure that overcapitalised banks use their capital buffers to crystallise
losses
Promote a secondary market for non-performing loans; improve the
transparency of bank and corporate balance sheets to enhance market
discipline; reform and resource legal frameworks to facilitate timely
resolution
ï‚§ IMF
Restore integration
and resilience
Revitalise cross-border lending to benefit from imbalances among
deposit-rich and lending-rich countries in Europe while improving
overall resilience by fully implementing the European Banking Union
ï‚§ ECB
ï‚§ European Commission
ï‚§ IMF
Free up bank capital
to support lending,
particularly to small
and medium-sized
enterprises
Increase balance sheet turnover by creating broad-based, plain-vanilla
securitisation markets (with lending standards, skin-in-the game
requirements, and resecuritisation limits) by reviewing regulatory capital
requirements attached to asset-backed securities and by developing
new instruments for SME securitisation
ï‚§
ï‚§
ï‚§
ï‚§
ï‚§
Temporarily support lending to preferred sectors (SMEs and
infrastructure investments) through state credit guarantees or through
expansion of national business-support agencies
ï‚§ AFME
ï‚§ IMF
Promote non-bank credit intermediation (insurance companies, pension
funds) to hard-to-service borrowers such as SMEs by reviewing
regulatory investment restrictions and by improving transparency on
borrowers (e.g., standards for credit-scoring assessments)
ï‚§
ï‚§
ï‚§
ï‚§
Facilitate securities offerings by small enterprises (high-yield bonds,
private placements) by reviewing investment restrictions for large
investors (insurance companies, pension funds)
ï‚§ AFME
ï‚§ IMF
Develop or promote other non-traditional sources of finance (such as
crowd-sourcing, peer-to-peer lending) by providing an appropriate
regulatory framework as well as venture capital markets (e.g., through
fund of guarantees for institutional investors)
ï‚§ AFME
ï‚§ City of London
ï‚§ European Commission
Promote an increase in equity funding by recalibrating the tax bias
against equity, reducing management incentives against equity, and
promoting access to equity for SMEs (“mini-IPOs”)
ï‚§ AFME
ï‚§ City of London
Develop non-bank
sources of funding,
particularly for
SMEs
AFME
City of London
ECB
European Commission
IMF
AFME
City of London
European Commission
IMF
Regulate loss-leading corporate lending to limit bank funding of large
corporates and stimulate the development of corporate bond markets
SOURCE: Global financial stability report, IMF, April 2014; Euro area policies: 2014 Article IV consultation, IMF, July 2014; European Commission green paper,
March 2013; AFME briefing note, June 2013; Unlocking funding for European investment and growth, AFME, 2013; Llewellyn Consulting, June
2014; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Survey on the access to finance of enterprises in the euro area, European Central Bank, November 2014.
234
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
175
.
Increased lending by the EIB, which today is enabled by government capital contributions
outside the Fiscal Compact or through ECB purchases of EIB debt, could help to advance
infrastructure and other projects that are facing capital constraints. The effects will
be contingent, however, on finding ways to structure additional projects that become
economically viable through reduced cost of capital.
We estimate that the effect of resolving any remaining blockages in access to finance
would likely enable €6 billion to €23 billion of additional demand, once multiplier effects are
considered. This is only a fraction of the fall in corporate investment since 2008. A return to
pre-crisis corporate investment trends would yield €227 billion in incremental investment.
But only part of this gap can be closed by improving access to finance—just 12.4 percent
of business leaders say that access to finance is their primary obstacle to investment,
weighted by size.235 If we assume that the share of the investment gap that corresponds to
companies facing problems with access to finance is the same as the weighted proportion
of companies for which it is their primary problem, raising access to finance would mean
an additional €28 billion of investment.
This is, however, a very aggressive assumption.
There will always be some companies that believe that their primary obstacle is finance. For
our lower bound, we assume that Germany—where 9 percent of companies face similar
financing constraints—is the benchmark for normal financing conditions. In this case,
improving access to finance would enable €7.8 billion of additional business investment.
Estimating the true effect of improving access to financing for SMEs is difficult because it
requires making a judgment about when a loan is appropriate.
This is subjective. Neither
the business owner nor the bank can know for certain what the return will be on any
given investment.
~60%
of bank managers
said lending
standards to SMEs
tighter than in
2003–14 survey
Facilitating bank lending
It is harder to obtain credit in Europe today than it was before the crisis. A survey of bank
managers by the ECB in 2014 found that around 60 percent felt that lending standards for
SMEs were considerably or moderately tighter than they were in 2003.236 Although tighter
prudential standards may be a good thing, there are pockets where this creates problems
for growth.
Thirty-two percent of SMEs surveyed in Greece, 17 percent in Spain, and
14 percent in Italy report that access to finance is the most pressing problem their firm is
facing. Rates in other countries, such as Germany, are as low as 9 percent.237 The conditions
for borrowing are dependent on geography because most SME lending is driven by local
banks. Local banks can have very different liquidity provisions, even within Europe.238
Where local banks’ liquidity remains an issue, the ECB is in a position to improve their
liquidity.
However, programmes to offer long-term financing have been available and
under-subscribed. Moreover, the ECB has already waived the credit rating requirement for
banks from the Eurozone periphery that seek refinancing. It is therefore not clear that further
financing for banks will unlock lending.
Ibid.
Euro area bank lending survey, European Central Bank, April 2014.
237
Survey on the access to finance of enterprises in the euro area, European Central Bank, November 2014.
238
Iftekhar Hasan et al., Bank ownership structure, SME lending, and local credit markets, Bank of Finland
research discussion paper number 22/2104, 2014.
235
236
176
McKinsey Global Institute
3.
How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. Banks may be hesitant to lend further because small business loans are illiquid. Europe
has only a very small secondary market for SME loan-backed securities. Creating a large,
liquid, Europe-wide market for such securities could encourage bank managers to increase
lending.239 Regulators and voters are rightly cautious about the regulation required for a
functioning securitisation market for new asset classes given the role mortgage-backed
securities played in the 2008 crisis. However, sensible proposals can address this concern.
The ECB should continue its work by creating clear new securitisation markets built on
transparency—including loan-level visibility of credit risk.
This will allow purchasers of debtbacked securities to build risk models that incorporate the characteristics of individual loans
within the bundle. In addition, “skin-in-the-game” rules that require issuers to maintain a
minimum stake in the security will reduce the risk of using securitisation to hide bad assets.
Restrictions on resecuritisation will make it easier for banks to model the risk of the security
and reduce the complexity of counter-party risk.
Enabling access to debt from the market
Developing Europe’s debt security market might help slightly larger companies to access
lending through capital markets rather than from banks. Although the role of debt securities
has been growing, they remain only about one-third of the European capital market
compared with half in the United States and Japan (Exhibit 105).240
Exhibit 105
European corporations rely relatively heavily on bank intermediation; although the use of securities is growing,
they still have a much smaller share
Capital market composition, 2012
%
Equity1
Debt
securities
(public
and
private)
Bank
assets2
25
12
25
48
26
Corporate balance sheet composition, 2006–133
% of GDP; quarterly3
17
29
34
95
90
85
53
22
Lehman Brothers
bankruptcy
12
48
40
54
55
80
Bank
91
assets
% of GDP
Japan
Canada United
EU
Kingdom
208
212
438
308
Loans
75
15
United
States
-5%
10
Securities
+49%
5
2006 07
08
09
10
11
12 2013
1 Stock market capitalisation.
2 Total assets of domestic commercial banks, including foreign banks’ subsidiaries operated domestically.
3 Excluding Bulgaria, Croatia, Luxembourg, Romania, Switzerland, and Norway
NOTE: Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
SOURCE: Global financial stability report, IMF, April 2014; Eurostat; McKinsey's Global Economics Intelligence analysis; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
See The case for a better functioning securitisation market in the European Union: A discussion paper,
European Central Bank and Bank of England, May 2014, and The impaired EU securitisation market: Causes,
roadblocks and how to deal with them, European Central Bank and Bank of England, May 2014.
240
Global financial stability report: Moving from liquidity- to growth-driven markets, IMF, April 2014.
239
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
177
.
Expanding this channel provides an alternative in case bank lending dries up, increasing
the resilience of the financial system. However, one of the reasons for the high exposure of
European firms to bank lending is the competitive lending rates they find in Europe.241 Unlike
US banks, European banks sometimes regard business lending as a route into cross-selling
higher value-added services. This means it will be more challenging to develop capital
markets on the scale seen in the United States.
Creating a more liquid European capital market for debt securities would, in addition to
bolstering resilience, attract international attention from supply-side investment services
firms. This would increase the visibility to investors of firms seeking debt, which would
reduce borrowing costs and increase the availability of capital.
Ongoing efforts by the
European Commission to reduce the current fragmentation of regulation through a capital
markets union will play a role in building a large liquid European market, although it continues
to be unclear exactly which proposals the EU will incorporate (see Box 8, “The EU’s planned
capital markets union”). Doing so by reducing the competitiveness of bank loans would
increase the cost to business in the short term at the very least.
Box 8. The EU’s planned capital markets union
European capital markets are not as integrated as they could be, and many advantages
would flow from their further integration.
Today, investment in Europe remains heavily
reliant on banks, while equity, debt, and other capital markets play a minor role in financing
growth compared with the case in other economies. The capital market is fragmented
because of different regulations covering such aspects as insolvency, company law,
taxation, and securities law, as well as because of different market practices for products
such as securitised instruments and private placements. As a result, financing conditions
vary significantly among member states, and shareholders and buyers of corporate debt
rarely go beyond their national borders when investing.
Many SMEs still have limited access
to finance.
Building a true single capital market in Europe by removing such barriers to cross-border
investment would improve access to financing for all businesses, in particular for SMEs, in
Europe at a low—and comparable—cost. It would also reduce the cost of raising capital,
allow investors to diversify funding of their investment, and therefore help the EU to attract
investment from all over the world, thereby contributing to economic growth. If European
capital markets were to become more efficient, risk and capital allocation would be
improved.
It also would contribute to stabilising the financial system by improving its ability to
absorb shocks. For the ECB, integrated capital markets would facilitate the implementation
of monetary policy.1
In its green paper presented on February 18, 2015, the European Commission laid out its
vision for step-by-step progress towards achieving a capital markets union in 2019.2 At
the time of writing, the Commission was in discussions about its initial suggestions with
all interested stakeholders with the intention of publishing a more detailed white paper in
summer 2015. The Commission has signalled its desire to start with efforts to encourage
high-quality securitisation across Europe, improve the availability of credit information on
SMEs to provide investors with an improved fact base, put into place a pan-European
private placement regime to encourage cross-border direct investment in smaller
businesses, and support a new European long-term infrastructure investment fund.
Yves Mersch, Capital markets union: The “why” and the “how”, speech at the Joint EIB-IMF High Level
Workshop, Brussels, October 22, 2014.
Breakaway: How leading banks outperform through differentiation: McKinsey global banking annual review
2
2013, McKinsey markets Services Practice, November green
Building a capitalFinancial union, European Commission2013.
paper, February 2015.
1
241
178
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. Enabling access to equity
European SMEs are much more likely to use debt to finance investment than they are to
issue equity. Enabling equity issuance as an alternative channel would improve resilience
much like creating a debt securities market.
There are good reasons that SMEs tend to prefer debt over equity. SMEs often want shortterm or revolving liquidity on a small scale, not suited to the higher transaction costs of
issuing equity. In addition, SMEs tend to have lower standards of accounting, which make
it harder to satisfy regulatory requirements on equity listings.
National governments and the
ECB could take further steps to reduce the impact of the latter hurdle by simplifying and
reducing the reporting requirements for SMEs that are issuing equity, particularly for those
offering private placements to sophisticated investors. Of course, regulatory requirements
on SME equity need to continue to protect unsophisticated investors from fraud.242
However, there are also less justifiable reasons that many SMEs prefer debt over equity. For
instance, systematic tax distortions in many countries encourage this preference.
When
an SME borrows money, interest payments on the debt are treated as a cost of business
and are tax-deductible. In contrast, when SME owners (often founders or entrepreneurs)
sell equity to invest, they have to pay capital-gains tax for the shares sold on the increase in
value since the owner paid in capital originally. This makes debt a much more tax-efficient
instrument for SMEs than equity.
Removing the tax deduction on interest payments would
create a more level playing field, but it would also make it more costly to invest now than
later. An alternative—providing a tax break on capital gains for equity used for investment—
has been implemented in Belgium and proposed in many countries.243 The jury is still out on
whether this approach increases investment rates among SMEs.244
In the Eurozone, there is room for doubt about whether monetary stimulus—
including QE—will be effective in boosting investment and job creation
The evidence suggests that accommodative monetary policy—traditional or nontraditional—has been beneficial to the European economy during a period of stagnation, but
that, by itself, cannot fully resolve Europe’s shortage of investment and job creation. Low
inflation keeps real interest rates fairly high, and companies continue to hold cash despite
ultra-low nominal rates as they rarely adjust their hurdle rates and the macroeconomic
outlook remains fragile.
Low nominal interest rates have not fully translated into real interest rates.
In some countries,
nominal interest rates are near zero, but, because of low inflation or even deflation, the real
cost of borrowing has not fallen significantly and may even be higher than before the crisis
(Exhibit 106). For example, in Spain, the real corporate lending rate at the end of 2007 was
1.5 percent; in 2014, it was around 3 percent.
“Securitisation rules: ‘Significant risk transfer’, retention and due diligence”, fact sheet, De Nederlandsche
Bank, February 2014.
243
Mirrlees Review, Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2010.
244
Geert van Campenhout and Tom Van Caneghem, “How did the notional interest deduction affect Belgian
SMEs’ capital structure?” Small Business Economics, volume 40, issue 2, February 2013.
242
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
179
. Exhibit 106
Although interest rates have fallen, low inflation means that the real cost of borrowing
has not declined significantly
Real corporate lending rates1
%
8
7
Germany
6
Netherlands
5
France
4
Greece
3
Italy
2
1
Spain
0
Portugal
Ireland
-1
-2
2004 05
06
07
08
09
10
11
12
13 2014
1 Annualised agreed rate/narrowly defined effective rate, loans with an original maturity of more than one year to nonfinancial corporations (S.11) sector, less inflation calculated with Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices (HICP) method.
SOURCE: ECB monetary financial institution (MFI) interest-rate data; Eurostat HICP data; McKinsey Global Institute
analysis
And, despite an enormous increase in the ECB’s balance sheet, broad money supply has
grown more slowly than pre-crisis as the money multiplier has broken down (Exhibit 107).
The creation of money happens endogenously when banks lend, and therefore a lack of
demand for loans hampers the transmission of monetary policy. An example of this situation
in action is the very low uptake of the ECB’s offer of €400 billion of low-cost, four-year
financing under the targeted long-term refinancing operation programme. By the end of
2014, only €212 billion of the facility had been used because demand for bank loans is low.
The offering in March 2015 had a significantly higher than expected uptake of €98 billion, but
this success was overshadowed by the fact that QE had been launched two months earlier.
180
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
.
Exhibit 107
Monetary policy has been highly accommodative, but it has not driven money circulation
and inflation up proportionately
Policy interest rates and inflation rate
ECB main refinancing operations; %
Eurozone HICP at constant taxes; monthly figures; % per year
Policy rate
Inflation rate
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
2008
09
10
11
12
13
Money supply and money circulation
Eurosystem total assets/liabilities; base money1 and M2
Index: 100 = January 2006
2014
Balance sheet
Base money
M2
300
250
200
150
100
50
2006
07
08
09
10
11
12
13
Pre-recession
Post-2008
r = 0.99
2014
Correlation between base money and M2 = 0.45
1 Currency in circulation and MFI current accounts (covering minimum and excess reserves).
SOURCE: Eurostat; ECB; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
181
. Why are low interest rates not creating demand for borrowing? In the case of companies,
low interest rates, by definition, reduce the cost of capital, but the lower cost of capital is
not necessarily reflected in the hurdle rate the company uses when deciding whether to
invest.245 The hurdle rate is determined by a number of other factors including the company’s
organisational capacity constraints, uncertainty about potential future returns, a desire for
financial flexibility, and even the fact that managers are biased towards optimism when they
forecast future returns.246 Many companies—especially smaller organisations that may lack
financial sophistication—do not adjust their hurdle rates in line with changes in their cost
of capital.
Indeed, companies adjust their hurdle rates fairly infrequently. A survey carried out in
the United States in 2003 when interest rates were low after the dot-com bubble burst
found that more than half of companies had not changed their hurdle rates in the previous
three years. Most companies fix hurdle rates that are easy to remember—in whole
numbers that cluster on 10 percent, 15 percent, 20 percent, and 25 percent.247 Another
study finds that many companies—especially smaller organisations that may lack financial
sophistication—do not adjust their hurdle rates in line with changes in their cost of capital.248
Whether the ECB should undertake QE has been a topic of intense discussion in Europe
for some time—well before the ECB decided to go ahead. One argument put forward
is that additional monetary easing through the purchase of securities is an indirect way
of financing governments that encourages fiscal profligacy and is therefore against the
mandate of the ECB.
But it may still be necessary in order for the ECB to meet its inflation
target—and therefore to meet its mandate. Another argument is that securities purchases
make taxpayers responsible for any losses—albeit purchases by the ECB (and the Bank of
England) have explicitly been of high-quality assets.
€1.1T
QE programme
announced
January 2015
In January 2015, the ECB announced a €1.1 trillion QE programme planned to add
€60 billion a month to financial markets until September 2016. ECB President Mario
Draghi said that the operation would continue until the central bank observed a sustained
adjustment in the path of inflation.249
But, given that interest rates are already low and that there are several weak transmission
mechanisms in Europe, the effect of QE on investment and job creation might be modest
(see Box 9, “QE”).250
Quantitative Easing and ultra-low interest rates: Distributional effects and risks, McKinsey Global Institute,
November 2013.
246
Ravi Jagannathan et al., Why do firms use high discount rates? Social Science Research Network Electronic
Journal, June 2014.
247
Iwan Meier and Vefa Tarhan, Corporate investment decision practices and the hurdle rate premium puzzle,
SSRN Electronic Journal, January 2007.
248
Tor Brunzell, Eva Liljeblom, and Mika Vaihekoski, “Determinants of capital budgeting methods and hurdle rates
in Nordic firms”, Accounting & Finance, volume 53, issue 1, March 2013.
249
“ECB announces expanded asset purchase programme”, press release, ECB, January 22, 2015.
250
H.
Woody Brock, Quantitative easing: Myths and half-truths, Strategic Economic Decisions, October 2012.
245
182
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. Box 9. QE
Quantitative easing by a central bank is the purchase
of securities in the open market against central-bank
reserves.1 It has been used by the US Federal Reserve,
the Bank of England, the Bank of Japan, and now the ECB
and the Riksbank.2
QE can play a role in providing banks and financial markets
with reserves and liquidity, especially when the usual
mechanisms of financial and interbank markets are not
working. QE should not be confused with creating money
because central banks do not directly affect the supply
of broad money through QE. They merely provide the
contingent liquidity for banks to create money by lending
more.
This is not currently happening on pre-crisis scale,
and it can be controlled via capitalisation rules and interest
payments on reserves when needed.3
The impact of QE on economic activity is not clear, and
the effect of different transmission mechanisms depends
on the state of the economy. When there is an acute
shortage of liquidity, even solvent companies could be
at risk of bankruptcy for cash-flow reasons, and the
purchase of assets by central banks helps both banks and
companies access cash quickly. The US Federal Reserve
System resorted to QE when illiquidity on mortgage and
interbank markets threatened to cause a chain reaction of
bankruptcies.
It bought $1.25 trillion in mortgage-backed
securities between 2008 and 2010 as well as US Treasury
securities and agency debt worth hundreds of billions of
dollars. The combined actions of the Federal Reserve and
US Treasury were able to stabilise financial markets and
the banking sector. They did not create strong lending, nor
have they created inflation.
The ECB faced a different situation, because mortgagebacked securities markets are less developed in Europe.
It reacted to the credit squeeze following the bankruptcy
of Lehman Brothers by offering long-term refinancing
operations that gave banks access to long-term liquidity.
It also reduced requirements for how much collateral a
bank needed to hold for a given amount of loans.
Unlike
the Federal Reserve, it did not engage in a large asset
purchase programme.4 Eurozone banks took longer to
stabilise. This was partly because of a less aggressive
response on the part of the ECB, but more so because
of the relative size of the banking sector, the speed of
response of national governments, and the time it took
European banks to recognise and dispose of bad assets.5
Once the immediate liquidity challenge was resolved,
further asset purchases by central banks such as
the Federal Reserve’s QE2 and QE3 programmes or
the announced ECB programme can have several
transmission channels, but the jury is still out on their
effectiveness: wealth effects from increased asset prices,
reduced long-term interest rates, higher fiscal spending
capacity, and weakened currencies.
By buying assets, the central bank changes asset prices.
If asset prices go up, a wealth effect can be created in
which people feel wealthier and therefore spend more—
which in turn can lead to higher domestic investment and
consumption. The segments of the population affected,
however, have the lowest marginal propensity to consume,
particularly in Europe where household stock holdings
are modest.
Asset purchases can also reduce interest rates on specific
asset classes, but this effect depends a great deal on
other market participants.
Purchasing Treasuries ought
to increase demand, reducing yields and bringing down
interest rates.6 This could encourage investment. However,
if central-bank purchases raise fears of inflation, it could
result in higher yields on sovereign debt. For example,
interest rates rose following the Federal Reserve’s QE2
and QE3 programmes.7 Establishing clear causation
either way is all but impossible.8 As a result, the debate
remains inconclusive.
If QE reduces real interest rates, it
may trigger investment in those pockets where credit is
a constraint—but it may not address the weak demand
for credit in the current environment of tepid growth
prospects. And the liquid assets of European households
in countries such as Germany and France tend to be
much larger than total household debt, so total household
spending may be negatively affected by low policy rates.9
QE may also weaken the euro and even further boost
net exports. This seems currently to be happening,
but the effects could also be undone by other central
banks’ efforts.
QE in Europe today could potentially support government
spending by returning the dividends of purchases to ECB
shareholders.10
Banking structures report, European Central Bank,
November 2013.
6
George Kapetanios et al., Assessing the economy-wide effects of
quantitative easing, Bank of England working paper number 443,
January 2012.
7
US Department of the Treasury.
8
M.
Hashem Pesaran and Ron P. Smith, Counterfactual analysis in
macroeconometrics: An empirical investigation into the effects of
quantitative easing, IZA discussion paper number 6618, June 2012.
9
John Muellbauer, Combatting Eurozone deflation: QE for the
people, Vox, December 23, 2014.
10
QE and ultra-low interest rates: Distributional effects and risks,
McKinsey Global Institute, November 2013.
183
5
QE is also sometimes used to include lending programmes, too,
such as those used by the ECB to improve banking liquidity. Here,
we focus on the role of asset purchases.
2
Brett W.
Fawley and Christopher J. Neely, “Four stories of
quantitative easing”, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review,
volume 95, number 1, January/February 2013; Sweden cuts rates
below zero and starts QE, BBC, February 12, 2015.
3
H.
Woody Brock, Quantitative easing: Myths and half-truths,
Strategic Economic Decisions, October 2012.
4
Brett W. Fawley and Christopher J. Neely, “Four stories
of quantitative easing”, Federal Reserve Bank of St.
Louis
Review, 2013.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
1
. New ideas should now be debated to widen the range of potential investment and
job creation measures
The debate on demand-side measures—focused on QE and the appropriate degree of
retrenchment in countries’ budget deficits—has become stale. New ideas that open up
new possibilities deserve more debate. Europe now needs to consider what could be the
next wave of bold action that helps to restore growth without undermining confidence
in government solvency and, in the Eurozone, confidence in the euro. In this section
we highlight four options: accounting for public investments as they depreciate; careful
adjustment of taxation and wage structures; unleashing the silver economy; and issuing
vouchers to households redeemable with the ECB.
Account for public investments as they depreciate
Since the crisis, governments have cut public investment.
Treating such investment as an
asset on a public balance sheet and accounting for the related expenditure only during
depreciation, often over many decades, could avoid the bias against investment and unlock
sufficient spending to almost close the output gap. A strong supervisory body would need
to ensure productivity of that spending or test the impairment of assets.
Public investment is typically a very small share of overall government budgets, but arguably
more discretionary in nature than many ongoing expenses or transfer payments. In Europe,
net public capital investment fell by around two-thirds, from 0.9 percent of GDP in 2007 to
only 0.3 percent of GDP in 2013.
This implies that governments were barely maintaining
their depreciating assets. Indeed, since the crisis, spending has increasingly focused on
past obligations such as debt service and pensions rather than investing in future growth
(Exhibit 108).
Exhibit 108
Since the recession, governments have de-prioritised investment for today and the future
In order to repay unavoidable liabilities
Time orientation of government expenditure1
% of GDP
Index: 100 = 2008
115
â–ª Interest and pension liabilities
Past
110
â–ª Future spending has a planning
105
lag but was cut
100
Future
95
Present
90
2008
were growing and almost
impossible to avoid
09
10
â–ª Present spending went sharply
up as unemployment costs
rose and fell as discretionary
budgets were slashed
2011
1 Expenditure is calculated as “past-oriented” when it is servicing liabilities incurred by previous commitments (interest payments, pensions), “future-oriented”
when it builds up human or physical capital (gross fixed-capital formation, education, R&D), and “present-oriented” in all other cases.
SOURCE: Eurostat; AMECO database; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
184
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
.
In the Eurozone, the Fiscal Compact treats investment spending the same as consumption
spending.251 This is not a universal norm. Most US states, for example, have rules that
require balanced budgets on operating expenses but allow for debt to be used to fund
public investment.252
As a modest step towards such an approach, the European Parliament recommended
in October 2013 that all investments in projects co-funded by the EU be excluded from
calculations under the EDP.253 In addition, it recommended that separate deficits should
be calculated and reported for operating and capital expenditure—although these would
not be used for the EDP.254 While this suggestion was rejected by the European Council,
the European Commission announced in November 2014 that capital contributions to the
new European Fund for Strategic Investments (also known as the “Juncker Plan”) would be
treated favourably during assessments of country finances under the Fiscal Compact.255
One approach that would reorient incentives without undermining the Fiscal Compact
would be to adjust the calculation of the capital component of government spending.256
Currently, capital spending is calculated on an accruals basis with the expenditure booked
at the time that the building work on the project is carried out. This is in keeping with ESA
2010 standards of accounting that costs should be booked when the economic activity
associated with them takes place.257
A different way would be to calculate expenditure during the consumption, rather than
the creation, of an infrastructure asset, as companies do. Suppose a three-year, €6 billion
road project is contracted out to a private construction firm and the government pays
half of that amount up-front and the second half on completion to the required standard.
Today, although the government is actually paying money only in years one and three, for
instance, it books spending of €2 billion in each of the three years.
However, the roads will
be operational for the next 20 years. It would make just as much sense for the government
to book an expense of €300 million every year for 20 years as the public asset is consumed.
Many public assets are unlike private assets in that they do not have corresponding revenue
streams attached to them. However, socioeconomic rates of return on public investment
can far exceed the government’s cost of capital—and substantially increase the future tax
base in a way that makes it self-funding over the long run.258 This makes it appropriate to
treat such investments as assets from a fiscal as well as a social point of view.
The effect of this proposal would vary by country.
The impact on the size of deficits that are
reported under current spending would be small. For most countries, the rate of capital
consumption is quite similar to the rate of capital investment. For countries that are bound
by the Fiscal Compact, these changes would require a total cut in government consumption
When it is making a decision about whether a country should be placed in the EDP, the European Council may
take into account the fact that investments were being made as part of structural reform.
However, no criteria
are given for when this condition may be in effect, and it is not in regular use. Similarly, there is an exemption
for gross capital formation expenditure as part of deficit limits. However, it is applicable only if a country is still
meeting the 3 percent limit, is not in the EDP, the country is in recession, and the expenditure in question is the
national contribution to a project partially financed by the EU.
252
Capital budgeting in the states, National Association of State Budget Officers, spring 2014.
253
“Resolution of 8 October 2013 on effects of budgetary constraints for regional and local authorities regarding
the EU’s Structural Funds expenditure in the member states”, European Parliament, October 2013.
254
Francesca Barbiero and Zsolt Darvas, “In sickness and in health: Protecting and supporting public investment
in Europe”, Bruegel Policy Contribution, issue 2014/02, February 2014.
255
“Factsheet 2: Where does the money come from?” European Commission and European Investment Bank,
November 2014.
256
Olivier J.
Blanchard and Francesco Giavazzi, Improving the SGP through a proper accounting of public
investment, Centre for Economic Policy Research discussion paper number 4220, February 2004.
257
European system of accounts 2010, Eurostat, June 2013.
258
Infrastructure productivity: How to save $1 trillion a year, McKinsey Global Institute and the McKinsey
Infrastructure Practice, January 2013.
251
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
185
. of €9 billion. But it would enable governments to invest into the future. Estimating the level
of investment required in public infrastructure, affordable housing, and R&D spending
suggests an unmet investment need of around €140 billion to €152 billion a year among
countries signed up for the Fiscal Compact. This total comprises €34 billion of additional
infrastructure spending, €59 billion of additional R&D spending, and €47 billion of additional
spending on affordable housing.259 If governments were to address this entire investment
shortfall under the suggested accounting standard, this option could create aggregate
demand between €90 billion and €220 billion after fiscal multipliers are taken into account.
This one accounting adjustment would nearly be sufficient to close the output gap
(Exhibit 109).
An important caveat is that this accounting approach could undermine the productivity of
public investment.
There is a risk that government leaders, freed from the responsibility of
having projects appear in their fiscal expenses during their tenure, might decide to spend
ineffectually on white elephants. This may be politically useful in the short term—boosting
particular constituencies such as construction workers and the unemployed—but the costs
would be borne by future generations. In order to address this risk, a powerful oversight
body would be required to stress-test the productivity of investment programmes and
advise on the depreciation schedules of projects and a mechanism for impairment.
Carefully adjust taxation and wage structures to redirect resources to households
with the greatest pent-up demand
Changes to taxation and wage structures have the potential to redirect resources to
households with the greatest pent-up demand, which will be critical to stimulating European
investment and job creation overall.
The marginal propensity to consume of higher-net-worth households is only about one-third
that of lower-wealth households, and capital income is less likely to be spent than labour
income (see Box 10, “Marginal propensity to consume”).
Box 10.
Marginal propensity to consume
The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is a measure of the likelihood that extra income
will translate into additional spending. Typically the MPC of low-income households is
greater than that of high-income households. For example, a household earning €20,000
a year might spend, say, 90 percent of any extra income due to pent-up demand for things
that are outside its budget.
Meanwhile, a household earning €1 million a year may have
only marginal unmet demands and would spend only 10 percent of any extra income. Thus
giving a euro to the first household would result in an increase in consumption of €0.90,
while doing the same for the second household would lead to extra consumption of €0.10.
Factors that result in a high MPC include having a low income, having little wealth, being able
to access only low interest rates on savings, having low consumption taxes, and having high
wealth taxes. Of these effects, the income and wealth effects are very large.
The wealthiest
20 percent of households have a marginal propensity to consume in the order of 10 percent,
259
The need for
while the lessinfrastructure investment is basedhas one in the order of 60 percent.1 levels of GDP
wealthy half of households on the rate of investment associated with the
growth to which Europe aspires. The need for R&D investment is based on the gap between European R&D
expenditure and best-in-class countries such as South Korea, assuming that half of the difference must be
1
borne by the public sector in the form of subsidies. The affordable housing estimate is based on the cost of
Christopher D.
Carroll, Jiri Slacalek and Kiichi Tokuoka, The distribution of wealth and the marginal propensity
replacing substandard Central in major cities by 2025.
to consume, European housing Bank working paper number 1655, March 2014.
186
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. Exhibit 109
Accounting for investments as they depreciate would enable more public investment
Within 3% limit
Above 3% limit
Existing view
Capital consumption view
Government deficit,
20141,2
% of GDP
New deficit value,
20141,3
% of GDP
Germany
0.2
Luxembourg
Change to base
deficit capacity,
20141,3
€ billion
0.2
Estonia
0.3
1.0
1.2
4.7
-2.4
0.3
-2.5
2.3
0.2
-2.9
-2.5
Netherlands
0.3
-0.1
-2.1
Malta
0.5
-0.7
-1.6
Romania
0.6
1.3
-1.1
Greece
27.8
1.5
-1.0
Latvia
-3.8
0.1
-0.4
Denmark
3.7
0.1
-1.8
2.5
-2.1
Finland
-2.9
Austria
-2.9
-3.1
-0.7
Belgium
-3.0
-3.3
-1.2
Cyprus
-3.0
Slovakia
-3.0
Italy
-3.0
Ireland
-3.9
-3.4
Portugal
Spain
-4.9
-5.6
1.5
0.3
1.7
38.0
0.3
0.7
-4.2
-6.4
4.1
-6.3
-2.5
-5.5
0.1
4.7
-0.7
-3.5
-4.4
15.1
1.6
0.2
-1.8
-4.4
France
1.2
-2.3
-3.7
Slovenia
Infrastructure, housing,
and R&D spending
increase needed4
€ billion
1.9
0.5
4.2
-1.1
29.9
2.7
-7.8
13.3
Total opportunity
€ billion
-9.0
152.1
1 Eurostat forecast, winter 2014.
2 Based on a deficit calculated with gross capital formation on an accruals production basis.
3 Based on a deficit calculated with gross capital consumption on an accruals lifetime use basis. New capacity is given by the current maximum capacity as
calculated previously with adjustment to figures caused by the new accounting rule.
4 Assumes that all countries that are currently underspending relative to the levels expected of their GDP growth increase to the appropriate level, while those
that are overspending do not change their behaviour in light of a new fiscal rule. Infrastructure gap is based on GDP modelling from Chapter 2, and R&D
need is calculated relative to total R&D gap to Japan assuming 50% of the gap needs to be closed by the public sector. Affordable-housing infrastructure
estimate based on extrapolation of MGI’s affordable housing analysis of replacing substandard housing stock by 2025.
Extrapolated based on the population
in each country with severe housing deprivation. Lower estimate shown.
SOURCE Eurostat; OECD growth forecast 2014; EU-SILC; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
. Meanwhile, the labour share of national income has declined, and wealth concentration has
increased (Exhibit 110). For all the current discussion about the high levels of household debt
and slow deleveraging, the fact remains that the value of European households’ net financial
assets is approximately 140 percent of GDP—for every debt, there is an asset to match.
Exhibit 110
Skewed distribution of income and wealth may have contributed to increased
household debt by sustaining consumption growth to 2008
Capital and labour shares in national income, United Kingdom, 1970–2010
% of national income
80
75
70
65
Labour share
Capital share
25
20
15
10
1975
80
85
90
95
2000
05
2010
SOURCE: Thomas Piketty database; Kumhof and Rancière, 2010; Rajan, 2010; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Capital income is highly concentrated, so if it plays a bigger role in determining income,
income inequality is increased. Richer households that are less likely to consume “recycle”
their excess income by lending through financial intermediaries.260 Households at the
bottom of the income distribution compensate for stagnant real wages by increasing
leverage. In some cases, commentators have argued that governments encouraged debt
as a substitute for redistribution to address growing inequality, most notably in the US
mortgage sector.261
This situation is not dissimilar to the circumstances that occurred in the run-up to the Great
Depression in the 1930s.
Franklin D. Roosevelt said on May 22, 1932: "... No, our basic
trouble was not an insufficiency of capital.
It was an insufficient distribution of buying power
coupled with an over-sufficient speculation in production. While wages rose in many of our
industries, they did not as a whole rise proportionately to the reward to capital, and at the
same time the purchasing power of other great groups of our population was permitted to
shrink. We accumulated such a superabundance of capital that our great bankers were
vying with each other, some of them employing questionable methods, in their efforts to
lend this capital at home and abroad”.
Michael Kumhof and Romain Rancière, Inequality, leverage and crises, IMF working paper number 10/268,
November 2010.
261
Raghuram G.
Rajan, Fault lines: How hidden fractures still threaten the world economy, Princeton University
Press, 2011.
260
188
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. Options for Europe today include the reduction of labour tax wedges, favourable wage
rounds in the Eurozone “core” countries, and judicious land, property, wealth, or capitalgains taxation. As a first approximation, MGI estimates a redistribution equivalent to
1 percent of GDP could trigger additional spending of €95 billion to €273 billion.
Great care in designing policy is critical. A poorly conceived measure could harm growth
by promoting capital flight or a decline in investment.262 Progressive taxation may reduce
growth by reducing the incentives to work and take risks.263 However, inequality also
reduces growth by decreasing the development of skills and access to opportunities of
talented individuals from disadvantaged backgrounds.264 Empirical estimates of the sizes
of each effect on growth are inconclusive but suggest that the detail of how inequality
reduction measures are implemented is important.
55+ age group
makes up
45%
of Europe's
households but
has nearly
60%
of wealth
Unleash the silver economy
In common with many other economies, Europe’s population is projected to age at an
increasing pace and eventually decline. This report outlines numerous options for offsetting
these trends through increased productivity and labour-force participation, but ageing
demographic trends also offer new opportunities.
European countries can turn ageing into
an advantage by offering services and experiences focused on older generations. These
could include high-quality leisure activities and destinations, advanced health-care options,
and unique cultural experiences. The fact is that, in the Eurozone, those aged 55 and older
make up around 45 percent of households but hold almost 60 percent of household wealth
(Exhibit 111).265 They typically have stronger balance sheets than younger generations,
having saved at an increasing rate throughout their prime working years and having
benefited from favourable asset-price developments in the decades prior to the crisis.
Encouraging increased spending of this demographic’s accumulated wealth could be
a significant lever for boosting investment and job creation and improving the economy
for all generations.
Simultaneously, European governments might consider addressing
intergenerational equality through other means, such as adjusting capital transfer taxes, or
increasing the stock of affordable housing stock, whose current shortage has been a major
source of disparity in wealth between the millennial and silver generations. As an example,
Japan, which has one of the oldest populations in the world, recently changed its taxation
policies to incentivise the transfer of accumulated savings from seniors to their descendants
and increased inheritance taxes to increase the redistribution of wealth. Unlocking just
1 percent of the silver age group’s saved wealth as new consumption could offer a stimulus
to the European economy of approximately 0.3 to 0.6 percent of GDP.
With its excellent
health-care system, its innumerable and highly developed tourism destinations, and strong
cultural heritage, Europe is well placed to take advantage of the silver economy.
Martin Paldam, “Safe havens in Europe: Switzerland and the ten dwarfs”, European Journal of Comparative
Economics, volume 10, number 3, December 2013.
263
Tax systems must balance many societal objectives, including economic growth, wealth equality, and
perceived fairness. Property taxes are the most favourable to growth, especially those on immovable fixed
property, because its supply is relatively inelastic. Consumption taxes are the next least detrimental to
growth, distorting saving, work, and leisure decisions less strongly than income taxes (except where “‘sin’”
taxes are deliberately distorting).
Income and corporate taxes have the strongest negative impact on growth
because they affect short-term decisions about the supply of labour. Corporate taxes, if not internationally
coordinated, are particularly likely to create capital flight for purpose of tax avoidance. See Jens M.
Arnold, Do
tax structures affect aggregate economic growth? Empirical evidence from a panel of OECD countries, OECD
economics department working paper number 643, October 2008.
264
Federico Cingano, Trends in income inequality and its impact on economic growth, OECD social, employment
and migration working paper number 163, December 2014.
265
A household is defined as a person living alone or a group of people who live together and share expenditure.
262
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
189
. Exhibit 111
Unleashing the silver economy can stimulate household demand
People aged 55+ command
nearly 60% of wealth …
… save more rather than
consuming …
… and make up an increasing
share of the population
Distribution of wealth by age
demographic group, Euro area
%
Savings rate by age demographic
% of disposable income2
People aged 55+ are set to
make up more than 40% of
Europe’s population by 2050,
up from 30% today
100%
16–34
16
35–44
20
45–54
20
55–64
17
65–74
15
13
15
18
75+
15
13
Share of
households
5
13
16
23
8
26
2050
Share of total
net wealth
16–34
35–44
45–44
55+
1 Includes housing.
2 Based on a weighted average of historical data from France, Germany, and Italy.
NOTE: Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
SOURCE: The Eurosystem Household Finance and Consumption Survey, April 2013; Wall Street Journal; Antonin & Piketty, 2009; Aging, Savings, and
Financial Markets (World Bank); McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Issue vouchers redeemable with the ECB to householders
Issuing vouchers to households that are redeemable with the ECB could stimulate
incremental spending, accelerate household deleveraging, and raise inflation closer to
the ECB’s target level. The central bank would effectively credit households with a certain
amount of money through time-limited spending vouchers, redeemable with the central
bank. This would be the equivalent of printing money, but it would ensure that the newly
minted money was used for spending in the near term. An equitable distribution of vouchers
across the Eurozone would avoid the need for lengthy discussions about redistribution
between countries, moral hazard, or implicit liabilities.
MGI’s first-order estimate is that crediting citizens with around €650 billion through such
an approach could close the demand gap in Europe.
While people are concerned about
the inflationary effects of such an approach, escaping deflation and restoring an inflation
rate close to 2 percent would be the explicit goal of the policy. As such, it may also well
be within the ECB’s mandate, although this position could be challenged and the policy
regarded as a hidden form of fiscal policy. The target inflation rate could be kept well under
control because directly crediting households minimises the money multiplier effect, and the
balance sheet expansion for a given increase in aggregate demand would likely be smaller
than is the case with QE.
Some commentators are concerned about setting a precedent
for future calls on the ECB to print money repeatedly, but as long as its independence is
assured, the central bank could do so only if the other monetary-policy tools at its disposal
failed to satisfy its mandate, which would typically happen only in as severe an economic
turbulence and deflationary environment as today's.
190
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. The measure remains risky, however, as it is conceivable that low growth and low inflation or
even deflation could continue for longer than desired, as happened in Japan. Moreover, it is
difficult to predict what impact deploying this option could have on the perception of citizens
and their trust in the common currency.
•••
Faced with the immediate pressures of the Eurozone crisis, European government leaders
have been able to coordinate policy and take bold decisions to stabilise financial markets at
least to a degree. But the fact remains that Europe still has a very significant output gap and
a large deficit in investment and job creation. Many approaches—some entirely practical,
others more radical—could help to alleviate this situation.
Now is the time to consider all the
available options. The next question is how feasible a programme of change is, both on the
supply side and on investment and job creation. We explore this question in the next, and
final, chapter.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
191
.
Chapter photo
Chapter 4: Cashier
© Getty Images
192
McKinsey Global Institute
3. How Europe can reignite investment and job creation
. 4. EUROPE CAN OVERCOME
BARRIERS TO ACTION
Europe’s economic future depends on whether the continent moves forward on broadranging reform on the supply side, backed by decisive action on investment and job
creation. The question is whether—and how—Europe now moves forward on this
sweeping agenda.
This analysis suggests several powerful sources of optimism. Best practice already exists
across Europe.
Three-quarters of all the ideas discussed on the 11 competitiveness growth
drivers can be implemented by national governments, potentially bypassing the more
complex and lengthy decision making that happens at the European level. According to the
results of the MGI survey, Europeans are willing to play their part in unlocking change by
making tough trade-offs. And there are, in fact, mechanisms that can help Europe overcome
the stalemate in the debate of investment vs.
stimulus, and establish the governance that
enables both—even absent a move to a more federal economic and fiscal European system.
European decision makers now need to move beyond pure crisis management, articulate
a longer-term vision for Europe based on simultaneous action on supply and investment
and job creation, and take bold action. If they do not—if the status quo remains—there is
a distinct risk that Europe will continue to face a long period of stagnation and instability
as unemployment remains endemic and debt burdens stay high. Youth unemployment in
particular is associated with increased crime and social disruption.266
Denis Fougère, Francis Kramarz, and Julien Pouget, Youth unemployment and crime in France, IZA
discussion paper number 2009, March 2006.
266
.
We broadly see four possible futures for Europe, and in only one of these is greater
prosperity highly probable (Exhibit 112). Sustainable growth and prosperity will likely
be obtained only when both far-reaching structural reforms implemented mostly at the
national level and investment and job creation enabled at the European level are carried
out in concert. They are mutually reinforcing, amplifying each other’s impact, and together
they have a strong likelihood of returning Europe to a growth trajectory that can meet
the aspirations of its population. Should Europe embark on a fiscal spending spree
without accelerating reforms to boost competitiveness, the resulting growth will not prove
sustainable as increasing debt burdens become unbearable.
Conversely, pushing through
reform at all costs in the absence of measures to support investment and job creation risks
continued deflation, high unemployment, increasing political instability, and even, potentially,
the breakup of the Eurozone.
Exhibit 112
MGI has identified four potential scenarios for Europe—only reform, investment, and job creation combined
will deliver prosperity
<1% growth scenario
Yes
Running out of steam and political capital
â–ª Short-term recession particularly in France
â–ª
Structural reform
—mostly at the
national level
and Italy; medium-term stagnation in
Europe, followed by sluggish growth
Risk of populist parties gaining power,
calling for dissolution of the European
Union as unemployment and debt increase
Gridlock
â–ª Status quo: Slow growth and significant
volatility due to uncertainty on future
direction
â–ª Japan-style deflationary spiral and risk of
need to restructure public debt
High-risk scenario
>2% growth scenario
Lockstep to prosperity
â–ª Higher GDP growth (2–3% in the medium
term)
European shot in the arm
â–ª Short-term GDP boost could end in
financial collapse
No
No
Yes
Reigniting investment and job creation—enabled at the European level
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Europe has significant challenges to overcome. On the structural side, there will be
opposition to the short-term effects of reform. There also will be significant fiscal constraints,
and the ever-present issues of fragmented decision making and strong vested interests.
For
reform on investment and job creation, huge issues of trust and questions of governance
must be worked through, along with genuine disagreement over the right economic path.
But the inertia of these challenges can be overcome if Europe’s leaders take the opportunity
to build on popular sentiment and work towards packaged deals that combine reform and
job creation, leverage existing EU investment programmes, and strengthen key institutions
to avoid moral hazard (Exhibit 113).
194
McKinsey Global Institute
4. Europe can overcome barriers to action
. Exhibit 113
Europe will need to work in tandem on reform and support for investment
and job creation
Challenges
Reform to boost competitiveness,
mostly at national level (75% impact),
supported at European level
â–ª Opposition to short-term
fallout of reform
â–ª Fiscal constraints
â–ª Fragmented decision making
â–ª Vested interests
â–ª Lack of trust and battles on
who picks up the tab
Investment and job creation,
enabled mostly at the
European level
â–ª Insufficient institutions and
governance
Mechanisms to
overcome inertia
â–ª Demand support
mechanisms that avoid
moral hazard
â–ª Package deals combining
reform and job creation
â–ª EU investment
programme
â–ª Genuine disagreement on
the economics
â–ª Complexity of implementation
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Three-quarters of competitiveness growth drivers can happen nationally with
European action to boost investment and job creation
The fact that three-quarters of the competitiveness growth drivers discussed in this report
can be implemented by national governments is an important key to unlocking change.
Nevertheless, meaningful progress on accelerating reform will require visionary political
leadership and, importantly, as we have stressed, simultaneous consensus and action at
the European level to shore up investment and job creation.
There are many institutional and political barriers to implementing competitiveness reforms
that political leaders need to tackle (Exhibit 114). Together, the 11 competitiveness growth
drivers amount to sweeping and radical change—and change is often hard. For some,
willingness to implement the growth drivers may be weak because they are unpopular,
require considerable time to take effect, and are subject to disagreement among experts.
Immigration may be a powerful part of the answer to shrinking labour pools, but it is
generally unpopular among citizens who worry that there will be more competition for jobs,
housing, and even social benefits. Improving infrastructure is complicated by the fact that
these projects are long term and therefore have to outlast any political cycle.
Innovation
policy is an example where most people would be in favour, but there is disagreement about
the nuance of how to improve outcomes in the most effective way. Other growth drivers
are difficult to implement. In an era of rapid technological change, more flexible labour
markets are necessary, but they face resistance from groups with vested interests that may
feel negative effects from reform.
Openness to more trade is another such issue. Budget
limitations stand in the way of improved education. And decision making on completing the
Single Market can be fragmented and difficult.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
195
.
Exhibit 114
Europe needs to overcome many institutional and political obstacles to change
Significant obstacle
Moderate obstacle
Willingness to implement
Growth driver
Ability to implement
Fragmented
Perceived
Expert
Time lag
Budget
decision
unpopu- disagree- until benefits
materialise constraints
making
larity
ment
Vested
interests
Complex
implementation
Nurturing
ecosystem for
innovation



Effective education
to employment




























Reduced energy
burden

Productive
infrastructure
investment
Supporting urban
development

Competitive and
integrated markets
in services/digital
Public-sector
productivity

Further openness
to trade


Pro-growth
immigration



Investment and
job creation
stimulation






SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute analysis
196




Enhanced labourmarket flexibility


Grey and female
labour-force
participation

McKinsey Global Institute
4. Europe can overcome barriers to action

. Europeans tend to be sceptical about the ability of the politicians who represent them to
move forward decisively. But crises often create strong incentives to take action. In the teeth
of a severe financial and economic crisis in the 1990s and despite a very weak economy,
Sweden boldly undertook sweeping structural reforms, transformed its public finances,
and revamped productivity growth in many sectors. In the first decade of this millennium,
Germany undertook radical reform of its labour market, thereby reducing unemployment,
holding down unit labour costs, and improving the economy’s overall competitiveness.
More recently, Spain’s labour-market reforms are projected to increase that economy’s
productivity growth by an estimated 0.25 percent a year.
Effective reform depends on
building an appetite for change, demonstrable government commitment, and the careful
management of interest groups (Exhibit 115).
Exhibit 115
Successful economic reforms managed to translate an appetite for change into concrete reforms,
while managing opposing interests
â–ª A popular sentiment that “things need
â–ª
to change”, often triggered by exogenous
events or crises
Shaping the terms of the debate on the
need and proposals for economic reform
Appetite for change
â–ª A concrete reform plan,
â–ª
Government
commitment
â–ª Selecting, scoping,
â–ª
sequencing, and bundling
reform steps to impact
incentive structures and
distributional effects
Strategic consensus and
trust building with
stakeholders
â–ª
Interest group
management1
developed with the involvement of
experts and stakeholders
A high degree of government
commitment with respect to the
reforms, based on strong cohesion
within the entire government
and/or across parties
Effective communication of the
reform efforts to the public and
active involvement of stakeholders;
no “reform by stealth”
1 Mancur Olson’s Logic of collective action (1965) implies that small, organized groups have incentives to influence policies in their favor—usually, these
interests are protectionist and thus counter to many economic reforms; Alesina and Drazen (1991) hypothesized that the more unequal the distribution of the
costs of reform, and the more polarized the society is, the longer it takes to be adopted (see also Alesina and Rodrik, 1994.
SOURCE: Tompson and Price, 2009; literature review; Lora and Olivera, 2004; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
197
. There are ways to unlock European action on investment and job creation
despite governance, moral hazard, and distributional issues
Agreeing to investment and job creation measures at the European level is difficult—as we
know from the fact that debate on the best path forward has been going on for six years.
Most of the barriers relate to governance and a lack of trust among European partners and
a fear of creating moral hazard. However, most of these issues can be overcome within
Europe’s—specifically the Eurozone’s—current institutional framework. Without moving to
a full federal system of economic and fiscal governance, there is scope to use levers that
don’t cause moral hazard and to design “package” deals in which national-level supply-side
reform is coupled with European action on investment and job creation. It is in the interests
of all to move forward given the strong economic ties that bind all parts of Europe together.
Investment and job creation measures face many tangible barriers.
Many measures,
including debt restructuring and transfer payments, have explicit distributional
consequences. In some cases, there is genuine disagreement about the economics and
what is the most effective path ahead. Examples where there is disagreement include
the capacity of economies to raise more public debt and whether crisis economies are
sufficiently small and open to export their way out of recession.
There are formidable
institutional barriers, too. National leaders and sometimes their parliaments and even
the constitutional courts of 28 EU member states need to agree on the path ahead. The
ECB has a mandate to control Eurozone inflation but not to target employment as the
US Federal Reserve does.
In the long term, Eurozone economies, in particular, need to
address even more fundamental questions about the institutional design of economic and
fiscal governance.
In the absence of a move to greater fiscal and economic integration, designing stimulus in a
way that minimises moral hazard has to be an important part of the mix. Changes in national
accounting rules, or adjustment of taxation structures, could be as viable as elevating
large-scale investment programmes to the European level. Ideally, the types of investments
selected would be large scale, and in the interest of all Europeans, such as in coordinating
pan-European energy grids and production facilities, upgrading the continent’s security and
defence capabilities, or implementing multinational R&D and education programmes.
Crafting package deals of measures designed to boost competitiveness and stimulate
investment and job creation may serve as a viable approach, too.
We have already seen
agreements that combine action on the supply side—a commitment to detailed reform—
with financial support for those economies that were bailed out by the ECB, the European
Commission, and the IMF. There could now be scope for other economies, including
large ones that have not been subject to such bailout conditions, to make a commitment
to comprehensive reform in exchange for decisive action at the European level to reignite
investment and job creation beyond bare-minimum credit programmes. This could be
coupled with multiple topic-focused pairings of reform and investment, such as an energy
union that combined investment with reform of national regulation like market access
and competition barriers.
For such package deals to be successful, it is imperative that
European leaders work towards restoring trust among individual states. Today, there is a
lack of trust that countries will spend wisely and follow through with difficult reform, rather
than later seeking a bailout from their peers, which is a barrier to action.
It is understandable that people living in areas that have felt relatively less economic
pressure feel less of an imperative to act beyond a broad sense of solidarity and that these
people regard the burden of resuming growth as lying squarely on the shoulders of more
affected regions. But the reality is that all European countries have specific needs for
reform (Exhibit 116).
All European economies have been through periods of both strength
and weakness.
198
McKinsey Global Institute
4. Europe can overcome barriers to action
. Exhibit 116
Each country has different relative priorities for structural reform and investment and job creation measures
Relative importance of structural reforms and demand-side measures
Nordics
Continental Europe
United Kingdom
and Ireland
Southern Europe
Baltics
Central and
Eastern Europe
Need for structural reform
Inverse average country z-score for competitiveness growth drivers
Higher
0.8
Bulgaria
0.7
0.6
Romania
0.5
Croatia
Poland
0.4
Italy
Slovakia
Greece
Malta
0.3
Latvia
0.2
0.1
Europe-30
average = 0
-0.1
Czech Republic
Lithuania
Austria
Norway
Estonia
-0.3
-0.4
France
Belgium
Germany
Finland
Switzerland
Ireland
United Kingdom
-0.5
Portugal
Slovenia
Hungary
-0.2
Cyprus
Spain
-0.6
Netherlands
Denmark
Sweden
Luxembourg
Lower -0.7
-2
-1
0
1
2
Lower need
3
4
5
6
7
10
11
Higher need
Need for investment and job creation
Output gap (inverse) as % of GDP1
1 Positive values indicate an economy running below potential.
SOURCE: European Commission; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Europeans are willing to play their part in their region’s economic renaissance
Many politicians may fear that reform will not find favour with voters, and they therefore
opt for inertia. But the evidence suggests that perceptions of electoral risk from voters
who do not support the case for reform are not justified. First, research suggests that the
probability of being re-elected is approximately the same for a reforming government as for
a government that does not embark on reforms.267 Second, the results of the MGI survey
suggest that, far from being anti-reform, Europeans actually want their leaders to act
decisively in favour of growth.
Marco Buti, Alessandro Turrini, and Paul van den Noord, Reform and be re-elected: Evidence from the postcrisis period, Vox, Centre for Economic Policy Research, July 2014.
267
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
199
. 87%
of respondents in
8 countries would
make trade-offs for
higher social
standards and
incomes
Europeans do not expect to live in a permanent state of economic underperformance and
eroding social provision. The MGI survey offers new evidence that they are willing to make
trade-offs to secure meaningful change, and it even suggests the broad parameters of
reform that could win the hearts and minds of the European population. The majority in the
survey did not opt for the status quo but for a new combination of improved health care,
living environment, buying power, education, and public safety, and significant compromises
to achieve that (expressed in the survey as working longer and harder or somewhat
reducing social protection). Support for this combination is, as we have discussed,
remarkably consistent across countries, ranging from 87 percent support in Germany to as
high as 98 percent support in Spain (Exhibit 117).
Exhibit 117
Appetite for change in Europe may be greater than often believed
Share of respondents who prefer the average scenario over the status quo
% (weighted)
98
96
Spain
Poland
95
Italy
95
93
Romania Sweden
91
Europe
91
90
United
France
Kingdom
87
Germany
Alignment on direction of change desired for each societal priority
Share of respondents whose optimal scores for each dimension indicate the same direction of
change as the European average scenario
Direction
of change
Priority
Degree of alignment1
Health care
95
Living
environment
93
89
Education
Buying
power
84
Work-life
balance2
84
Public safety
84
Social
protection
58
1 Respondents who desire no change from the status quo for a given dimension are considered to be non-aligned with the
direction of change.
2 Calculated as average of working hours and productivity scores from conjoint survey.
SOURCE: MGI European Aspirations Conjoint Survey, August 2014; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
200
McKinsey Global Institute
4.
Europe can overcome barriers to action
. •••
Europe has fundamental strengths on which to build. The question is how to use those
strengths as a platform for a return to robust growth. There are solid grounds for optimism
that a better European society is possible. Importantly, policy makers, business people, and
civil society leaders should be emboldened by the fact that the solutions to Europe’s current
underperformance do not need to be “imported” from the rest of the world; they are already
in place elsewhere on the continent.
Europe can largely boost its competitiveness through
action on the national level, obviating the need for complex decision making at the European
level. MGI’s survey indicates that citizens are willing to make a contribution to Europe’s longterm recovery.
There is a genuine opportunity for real change and a positive narrative for Europe, building
on the continent's undoubted strengths and seizing the current window of opportunity
created by the confluence of a number of positive trends observed in 2015. Now is the time
for Europe’s leaders to shift focus from crisis management and towards framing a broad
programme of supply-side and investment and job creation that can put Europe’s economy
on a healthier footing for the long term.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
201
.
Chapter photo
Appendix: Health care
© Getty Images
202
McKinsey Global Institute
4. Europe can overcome barriers to action
. APPENDIX
This appendix provides details on the MGI survey, and the data sources and methodologies
used in this report in the following sections:
1. The MGI European Aspirations Conjoint Survey
2. Growth scenarios and GDP growth impact sizing for competitiveness growth drivers
3. Investment-requirement sizing for competitiveness growth drivers
4. Aggregate impact sizing for investment and job creation options
1. The MGI European Aspirations Conjoint Survey
Aim, scope, and overview of instruments and limitations
The purpose of the MGI European Aspirations Conjoint Survey was to reach an
understanding of Europeans’ aspirations regarding various societal outcomes underpinned
by economic prosperity, as well as their own economic situation, for the coming decade. As
such, the survey provides an empirical contribution to the ongoing debate about whether
Europe has evolved into a “post-growth society” or whether there is still a desire for, and
commitment to, elements of economic growth among European citizens. It also aims to
understand whether citizens are prepared to personally contribute to such growth and make
the kind of trade-offs that it involves.
The survey, undertaken between August 13, 2014 and August 22, 2014, by SKIM of the
Netherlands using online panels of Global Market Insite, covered eight European countries:
France, Germany, Italy, Poland, Romania, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom.
Together, these countries make up about three-quarters of the Europe-30 population and
represent the five European regions this report considers.
Two thousand people were
included in the survey in each of the eight countries, giving a total sample of 16,000 people.
A conjoint methodology was chosen as primary instrument to allow us to account for the
trade-offs Europeans may have to make in order to achieve desired improvements, and to
avoid establishing a “wish list” of priorities that does not properly take cost into account.
The survey also comprised a number of regular polling questions that were asked after the
conjoint was completed (listed below) in order to (1) deep-dive into important elements of the
conjoint such as the willingness to work; (2) test further attributes and attitudes like current
satisfaction levels; and (3) provide the socio-demographic background of respondents for
sample weighting and analysis of results by demographic grouping.
Like any field research, this survey had a number of limitations and biases. Details of these
can be found in the following methodology sections. However, the largest limitations and
biased we would note include (1) the fact that online polling creates a bias towards Internet
users: (2) the use of professional panels, as well as drop-out rates during the survey, creates
a certain self-selection bias; (3) cross-cultural differences; (4) the choice of conjoint variables
limits trade-offs to the variables presented; (5) the use of qualitative description of attributes
and levels in the conjoint presentation, in conjunction with the quantitative model lying in the
background to balance scenarios in terms of cost and GDP impact, introduces a degree of
subjectivity in how respondents interpret attribute descriptions and whether they perceive
.
scenarios as balanced; (6) post-processing techniques and estimation of utility values can
introduce additional bias from weighting and extrapolating partial responses; and (7) in this
pure cross-sectional study, we gain no data with which to assess variations over time.
Sampling and recruitment of participants
We used professional online panels of individuals in each country who are rewarded
for their participation in surveys. Within the panel population, the panel provider sought
to obtain 2,000 respondents for each country, and sent out invitations to participate in
random batches of approximately 200. The socioeconomic distribution of respondents
after each batch was carefully monitored and the next batches geared towards randomly
selected participants of underrepresented groups where needed. As the survey panels
were recruited online, there may be a bias in the results towards individuals who are active
Internet users.
Fielding
Respondents received an invite, along with a short description, via email.
The questionnaire
itself was conducted online in a web browser. During the process, some respondents
finished the survey, some stopped and later resumed, and some dropped out completely.
Invitations were sent until 2,000 completed surveys were reached for each country. We saw
very typical dropout rates for the survey.
By country, these were 20 percent in the United
Kingdom, 19 percent in France, 14 percent in Germany, 12 percent in Italy, 11 percent in
Poland, 13 percent in Romania, 10 percent in Spain, and 18 percent in Sweden.
Country-specific adaptation and quality assurance
The MGI survey covered eight different countries and as many languages, each with a
distinct culture. As such, survey respondents may have interpreted the questions and
attributes they were presented with in different ways. Any cross-country comparisons need
to be interpreted in that context.
Score results observed in cross-cultural comparisons
may have a different meaning than those derived from intercultural comparisons. The
equivalence of concepts, and the similarity in meanings attached to a behaviour or concept,
can vary significantly among cultures. Linguistic equivalence, the wording of items (in terms
of form, meaning, and structure) can also vary across the different language versions of a
document, including the reading complexity of the items presented, and how natural the text
may sound to a native speaker.268
We used a professional translation firm to translate the survey from English into national
languages and test semantic equivalence.
We also tested the survey translation with a
native speaker per country who also spoke English and was familiar with the objective of the
survey. Finally, we provided respondents with definitions of the terms and concepts used in
each question to help moderate the impact of cross-cultural differences.
The same conjoint design was used for all eight countries.
Post-processing: RIM-weighting procedure
The responses were weighted to match national distributions for each country individually,
according to gender, age, income, education levels, employment (both status and
occupation), country of birth, and household composition. Using demographic data
obtained from Eurostat, deviations in the sample from the national average were measured.
Using a technique called RIM weighting (Random Iterative Method, also known as raking),
we applied weights to individual respondents to match demographic distributions.
For
See Fons van de Vijver and Norbert K. Tanzer, “Bias and equivalence in cross-cultural assessment: An
overview”, Revue européenne de psychologie appliquée, volume 54, issue 2, 2004, and StefaniÌa Ægisdóttir,
Lawrence H. Gerstein, and Deniz Canel Çinarbas, “Methodological Issues in cross-cultural counseling
research: Equivalence, bias, and translations”, The Counseling Psychologist, volume 36, March 2008.
268
204
McKinsey Global Institute Appendix
.
example, if we surveyed more males than represented in the national population, we would
adjust the weight of males downwards.
Instrument 1: Conjoint—methodology, variables, attributes, and presentation of
trade-offs
We used a conjoint methodology to uncover the preferences of the respondents when
faced with different scenarios, each consisting of a combination of outcomes for several
interdependent dimensions or variables.
Choice of variables
The variables included in the conjoint were chosen to reflect on the one hand the
dimensions that citizens typically value in their lives, and on the other hand the key drivers of
(public) expenditure as well as, in turn, income generation.
To capture what people value, we base the choice of variables on the OECD Better Life
Index, a widely recognised instrument for grasping and comparing social progress and
quality of life, as a starting point. Attributes from the OECD Better Life Index such as
“civic engagement” and “life satisfaction” were, however, excluded from the conjoint as
our focus was on attributes whose quality could clearly be linked to the availability of
economic resources (such as public or private spending). For the same reason, we chose
to consider “social protection” rather than the Better Life Index attribute “community”, and
we disaggregated the attribute “work-life balance” into “working hours” and “productivity” in
order to provide respondents with a more tangible understanding of what an improvement
or sacrifice in this dimension would entail, and to be able to estimate economic impact.
Correspondingly, we included the following eight variables in the conjoint scenarios, and
provided the ensuing definitions to ensure that respondents had a clear and common
understanding of these variables:
ƒƒ Health care. The quality of health care involves, for example, longer life expectancy,
higher quality of life, better technologies and treatments, and shorter waiting lists.
It also
includes care for the elderly.
ƒƒ Education. The quality of education relates to all types (primary, secondary and
higher education).
ƒƒ Living environment. Environment and public space involves protecting the environment
(like forests and lakes) and the quality and appearance of public spaces (for example,
parks, roads, and stations).
ƒƒ Public safety.
Safety involves more police officers on the street, more prisons, and more
traffic checks. It also includes national defence.
ƒƒ Social protection. Social protection could involve the level of, and entitlement to,
allowances in case of unemployment and/or disability.
This also includes welfare.
ƒƒ Buying power. This refers to income from work and/or allowances and benefits
effectively available to spend each month (after paying tax, social protection costs, and
health-care premiums).
ƒƒ Working hours. Work time refers to actually worked hours in a working week.
It does not
include unpaid work, such as volunteer work.
ƒƒ Productivity. Investment in productivity could include extra training, re-training,
improved effort, and being more ambitious when looking for a job.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
205
. The overall number of variables was limited to eight to keep the complexity of the survey
manageable. We would, of course, have liked to decompose buying power into typical
personal expenditure items, fully cover all elements of public spending also including, for
instance, general administration, or test each of the specific trade-offs involved in the 11
growth drivers described in our report (e.g., a later retirement age), but this would have led to
unmanageable complexity of the conjoint scenarios.
Choice of attribute levels
To limit the cognitive load of respondents when considering scenarios, we used quantitative
specifications of the levels only for two variables, namely disposable income due to its
high weight in GDP and working hours as our key balancing variable. We used simpler
standardized qualitative levels for the remaining six variables.
For disposable income, the levels were 20 percent lower, 10 percent lower, the same,
10 percent higher, and 20 percent higher. For working hours, the levels were six hours less,
three hours less, the same, three hours more, and six hours more per week.
For health care,
education, the living environment, social protection, public safety, and productivity, the levels
were much lower, lower, the same, higher, much higher.
Balancing the conjoint scenarios in a GDP model
To balance the scenarios and to assess the economic implications, we translated the levels
described above into additional or reduced spending or income generation. We based this
calculation on the current share of GDP of the eight variables in base case, using a GDPweighted average (2012) of the eight countries for each of the topics addressed in the survey
(Exhibit A1). If one variable was improved in a scenario, other variables had to be reduced
by collectively an equivalent monetary amount—or working hours or productivity had to
increase to generate the equivalent higher income.
Exhibit A1
Survey: GDP model
Theme
Description
Europe-8 value1
Source
Health care
Cure and care; public and private
expenditure (% of GDP)
10.22%
World Bank
Education
Total expenditure (% of GDP)
6.03%
Eurostat
Living
environment
Total expenditure on environmental
protection (% of GDP)
1.21%
Eurostat
Social security Public expenditure on social protection
against the risks related to unemployment,
sickness and disability, and old age (% of
GDP)
15.16%
Eurostat
Public safety
Public expenditure on defence, public
order, and safety (% of GDP)
3.44%
Eurostat
Buying power
Share of GDP not attributable to
46.83%
government expenditure and not committed
to private expenditure on health care,
education, and environmental protection
Eurostat
1 Does not sum to 100% as not all dimensions of non-disposable expenditure were considered.
SOURCE: MGI European Aspirations Conjoint Survey, 2014; Eurostat; World Bank; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
206
McKinsey Global Institute Appendix
.
We applied the following translations from scenario descriptions and attribute levels
to spending:
ƒƒ For disposable income, working hours, and productivity, we assumed increases or
decreases of zero, 10, or 20 percent relative to the current level as a percentage of GDP.
For disposable income, this corresponds exactly to the levels shown to respondents in
the survey. For working hours, this corresponds roughly to the 3 or 6 hours more/less
shown in the survey, slightly less to reflect declining marginal productivity of additional
hours worked. For productivity, we chose the same changes as for hours worked, as
productivity also directly affects the entire economy in terms of additional (or lower)
output generated.
ƒƒ For health care, we assumed an increase in spending even when respondents chose
“the same” level due to increasing health care cost in line with demographics. We used
the European Commission’s 2012 report on ageing as basis for this.269 “Much lower”
health care was assumed to correspond to no increase in health-care expenditure,
resulting in a negative effect of 42 percent due to GDP growth and ageing.
We assumed
that “lower” corresponds to compensating for demographic shifts but not GDP
growth; building on the European Commission’s “demographic scenario”, we arrive
at a reduction of 29 percent of health care spend as share of GDP. Compensating for
demographics plus the assumed growth in GDP yield “the same” quality of health care
as today—entailing an increase of 8 percent of health care spend as a share of GDP. The
“income elasticity” and the “non-demographic determinants” scenarios defined by the
European Commission were used for “better” and “much better” health care, entailing
increases in health care spend as a share of GDP of 28 and 39 percent, respectively.
ƒƒ For education, the living environment, social protection, and public safety, we assumed
that the options “much lower”, “lower”, “higher”, and “much higher” corresponded to
a 50 percent and 100 percent decrease or increase in expenditure as a percentage of
GDP, respectively (for example, current spending on education is about 6 percent of
GDP and therefore “higher” spending would imply about an extra 3 percent of GDP).
“The same” level for a given attribute implied a constant GDP share of spending.
We
chose these large increments between options to ensure that the scenario choices
would entail discernible trade-offs and therefore reveal respondents’ priorities.
Exhibit A2 summarises the additional/lower cost or reduction/increase in available
resources by variable and level.
There is necessarily a degree of subjectivity involved in assigning quantitative spending
values to qualitative levels. This caveat should be taken into account when interpreting the
quantitative results of the conjoint analysis.
The 2012 ageing report: Underlying assumptions and projection methodologies, European Commission,
April 2011.
269
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
207
. Exhibit A2
Additional/reduced cost and lower/higher resources available
by conjoint variable and level
% of GDP, Europe
1
2
3
4
5
Health care
-4.2
-2.9
0.8
2.8
4.0
Education
-6.0
-3.0
0.0
3.0
6.0
Living environment
-1.2
-0.6
0.0
0.6
1.2
-15.2
-7.6
0.0
7.6
15.2
Public safety
-3.4
-1.7
0.0
1.7
3.4
Buying Power
-10.2
-5.1
0.0
5.1
10.2
Working hours
-20.0
-10.0
0.0
10.0
20.0
Productivity
-20.0
-10.0
0.0
10.0
20.0
Social Security
SOURCE: McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Presentation of the conjoint scenarios
The conjoint approach consisted of two stages—an introductory stage and the conjoint
exercises or scenario choices.
In the introductory stage, a respondent was able to build a personal ideal scenario using
seven of the eight variables (excluding productivity) (Exhibit A3). This initial step of the survey
gave respondents the opportunity to rank the variables and to express the intensity of their
preference for one variable over another. A GDP model (described above) balanced the cost
of the selected attributes by automatically increasing or decreasing working hours as much
as needed to generate the additional economic resources. This exercise served two goals.
First, it provided the respondent with a general understanding of the components and tradeoff principle of the conjoint.
Second, it also revealed whether there was a desire to improve
spending on health care, education, the living environment, social protection, and safety,
given the constraints on each individual’s buying power and free time. This also served as
input for the second stage, the conjoint trade-offs (see explanation below).
The second stage was the conjoint exercise during which each respondent was presented
with ten sets of two alternative GDP-balanced scenarios at a time, and then asked to
choose between them (Exhibit A4). The scenarios each specified a combination of variables
at five different levels denoting spending and/or quality.
The conjoint technique we used was a Partial Profile Conjoint.
In each trade-off exercise we
randomly showed only four out of eight possible variables per scenario. The main reason for
this approach is to prevent information overload, while still generating accurate outcomes
thanks to our big samples.
To ensure a more realistic and accurate trade-off exercise, the conjoint scenario choices
were tailored to the preferences of individual respondents from the introductory stage. We
picked the two themes for which the respondent indicated the strongest preference to
spend more, and, for these themes, we did not show any of the lower—unfavourable—levels
in the conjoint scenarios.
This adaptive phase increased the accuracy of our preference
estimations (utilities) and prevented respondent fatigue and frustration. Each scenario
208
McKinsey Global Institute Appendix
. shown is designed in such a way that it is roughly GDP-neutral so that respondents are
offered realistic choices. Each respondent is shown ten sets of scenarios to trade off.
Exhibit A3
Building an ideal personal scenario
SOURCE: The MGI European Aspirations Conjoint Survey, 2014; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
Exhibit A4
Choosing between scenarios
SOURCE: The MGI European Aspirations Conjoint Survey, 2014; McKinsey Global Institute analysis
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
209
. Estimating optimal and average scenarios
We estimated the relative preferences each individual has for each of the eight attributes
based on the choices each respondent made in the ten conjoint exercises presented.
For example, if someone consistently chooses a scenario with much higher spend on
education, then the estimated preference score for much higher education spend will be
high. We applied a Hierarchical Bayes (HB) technique (using the industry standard Sawtooth
software) to calculate these preferences or utility scores. The HB method enables relatively
stable estimators of preferences at individual level, which allows analysis at subgroup level
(unlike logit models or LC). HB is an iterative approach that seeks to optimize the utility
scores for each individual and variable such that they best predict the actual choices a
respondent makes in the conjoint exercises.
For example, assume a respondent chooses
between scenario A and B, each containing four variables and levels, and he selects A. Then
the HB method estimates utility scores so that the total estimated preference score—the
sum of the estimated utility scores for the four variables and levels presented—is higher
for scenario A than for scenario B. The HB method tries to estimate utility scores in order
to maximize the instances where prediction and actual choice match across all scenario
choices presented to a respondent.
We estimated an average scenario by calculating the average of all respondent-level
optimum scenarios.
Based on the GDP model, each possible GDP-balanced scenario was
determined—in other words, all combinations of more or less education, social protection,
working hours, etc., which matched economic spend and available resources. Note that
these scenarios were full-profile and contained all eight variables and respective levels
and not only four, which we had in the partial-profile conjoint exercises. Also note that for
this processing step, we applied country-specific adaptations of the European shares of
GDP listed in Exhibit A1, based on the same sources.
For all these full-profile scenarios we
calculated the total preference score for each individual respondent as the sum of utilities of
the associated levels. On this basis, we identified the most preferred balanced scenario per
individual. For optimum scenarios per country, we chose the scenario that maximises total
preference score for the entire sample of respondents.
To determine a country-specific or European-average scenario, we took the average level
of each variable among all the optimal scenarios of individual respondents.
For instance,
if 50 percent of respondents had education “much higher”—translated for averaging to a
numeric level 5 on a scale of 1 (much lower) to 5 (much higher)—as most preferred, and
the other 50 percent had “higher” (level 4) as most preferred, then the average scenario
was set to 4.5. In practice, the difference between optimum and average scenarios
was small. Average scenarios have the advantage vis-à-vis optimum ones that we can
determine more granular values in between the discrete choices of 1, 2, 3, 4, and 5 as in an
optimum scenario.
We calculated how many people preferred the country-specific average (or European
average) scenario over the current status-quo scenario (nothing lower or higher) by
calculating total preference scores for each respondent and comparing how many times the
average scenario has a higher preference compared to status quo.
The level of preference
was similar as for the optimum scenario.
Based on the differing preferences amongst individuals (e.g., some people prefer higher
education, whereas others opt for more income) we ran a cluster analysis to identify different
segments of respondents. We tested several clustering techniques and applied a hybrid of
SPSS Two-step and K-Means, which generated the most discriminating clusters. The inputs
for the cluster algorithm were the respondent level optimal scenario levels for each of the
eight attributes (e.g., one respondent could have had health care at level 4, education at level
5, etc., and another respondent could have had health care at level 2 and education at level
210
McKinsey Global Institute Appendix
.
4). The cluster algorithm then looked for groups of people with very similar optimal scenarios
whereas between different groups the typical scenarios were truly different.
Instrument 2: Traditional survey questions
Besides the conjoint exercises, the survey also posed a number of other questions. The
goals of asking further survey questions were to obtain socio-demographic profiling
information and deepen our understanding of respondents’ values and attitudes as
well as their more specific preferences regarding some of the issues raised by the
conjoint exercises.
Not all respondents received all of the additional questions; they were randomly assigned a
selection, except for the socio-demographic profiling. In this report, we evaluate only a few
aspects most related to the conjoint trade-offs, but list the full set of questions for reference.
Socio-demographic profiling:
ƒƒ Are you…? Female or male.
ƒƒ How old are you? Under 15, 15–19, 20–24, 25–29, 30–34, 35–39, 40–44, 45–49,
50–54, 55–59, 60–64, 65–69, or 70 years or older.
ƒƒ What is the highest level of education you have successfully completed? Preprimary, primary, and lower secondary education (ISCED 0–2), upper secondary and
post-secondary non-tertiary education (ISCED 3–4), or first and second stage of tertiary
education (ISCED 5–6).
ƒƒ Which of the following situations is most applicable to you? I am self-employed,
I am employed (not by the government), I am employed (by the government), I am
occupationally disabled, I am unemployed and looking for work or on social welfare, I
am in early retirement, I am retired or am a renter, I am a student or go to school, I am a
housewife or househusband, I work as a volunteer, or other.
ƒƒ In which sector do you work? Agriculture, forestry and fishery, mineral mining, industry,
energy, water companies and waste management, construction sector, trade, transport
and storage, hospitality, information and communication, financial services, real-estate
letting and sales, special commercial services, letting and other commercial services,
public administration and government services, education, health and welfare, culture,
sport and well-being, other services, household, extraterritorial organisations, or other.
ƒƒ For how many hours a week are you contracted? Full-time, part-time, varies, I do not
have a fixed contract, or none of the above.
ƒƒ On average, how many hours a week do you spend on your work? (This question
was followed by a free text box).
ƒƒ Where were you and your parents born? You, your mother, your father (these
questions were followed by drop-down boxes of country names).
ƒƒ What is your net monthly income? £799, £800 to £1,099, £1,100 to £1,499, £1,500 to
£1,999, £2,000, prefer not to say, or don’t know (UK survey example shown only).
ƒƒ What is the composition of your household? Single without children living at home,
single with children living at home, co-habiting/married without children living at home,
co-habiting/married with children living at home, living at home with parents/family,
residential group/student house, or other.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
211
.
Further attitudes and level of satisfaction
ƒƒ How would you describe [country] society today? Please select from the following
characteristics (maximum three: individualistic, shows solidarity, assertive, humble,
entrepreneurial, risk-averse, rewarding of risk-taking, conservative, well-behaved,
progressive, values individual responsibility, social, rewarding of performance, values
equality, respect for authority, nationally orientated, internationally orientated, tolerant,
strives for the best, satisfied with just having enough, and values personal freedom.
ƒƒ What would you like [country] society to be like in ten years’ time? Please select
from the following characteristics (maximum three): individualistic, shows solidarity,
assertive, humble, entrepreneurial, risk-averse, rewarding of risk-taking, conservative,
well-behaved, progressive, values individual responsibility, social, rewarding of
performance, values equality, respect for authority, nationally orientated, internationally
orientated, tolerant, strives for the best, satisfied with just having enough, and values
personal freedom.
ƒƒ In which three areas do you think [country] should stand out? Choose from the
following areas (maximum three): poverty reduction, European integration, behaviour of
decision makers, health care, green living environment, infrastructure and accessibility,
income equality, innovation, integration of immigrants, dealing with climate change, arts
and culture, treatment of foreign workers, manners and morality, entrepreneurial climate,
education, development aid, level and certainty of pensions, recreational facilities,
social protection, sports facilities, safety, employment, availability of housing, healthy
government finances, democracy, the justice system, economic growth, and other.
ƒƒ Which areas are you most concerned about when you think about [country]?
Choose from the following areas (maximum three): poverty reduction, European
integration, behaviour of decision makers, health care, green living environment,
infrastructure and accessibility, income equality, innovation, integration of immigrants,
dealing with climate change, arts and culture, treatment of foreign workers, manners
and morality, entrepreneurial climate, education, development aid, level and certainty of
pensions, recreational facilities, social protection, sports facilities, safety, employment,
availability of housing, healthy government finances, democracy, the justice system,
economic growth, and other.
ƒƒ All in all, how happy have you felt lately? Very unhappy, unhappy, neutral, happy, or
very happy.
ƒƒ How happy are you with [country]? Very unhappy, unhappy, neutral, happy, or
very happy.
ƒƒ How happy do you expect the next generation will be with [country]? Very unhappy,
unhappy, neutral, happy, or very happy.
ƒƒ To what extent are you interested in politics? Very uninterested, uninterested,
interested, and very interested.
ƒƒ To what extent do you follow national political news in the media? Not at all, rarely,
in general, intensively, and very intensively.
212
McKinsey Global Institute Appendix
. Details on the conjoint trade-offs regarding working hours and productivity
ƒƒ Imagine you had to work more. How would you prefer to do this? Rank the
following aspects, where 1 indicates you would prefer it most. If this situation
does not apply to you, do your best to put yourself in the situation: If I have
to work longer, I would prefer to retire at a later age, work more hours a week, or
sacrifice holidays.
ƒƒ Imagine you can work as many hours a week as you like and your net income
increases accordingly; what is the maximum number of hours you would work in
this case? You can enter a number between 0 and 100. (This question was followed
by a free text box).
ƒƒ To what extent do you think a person’s salary in [country] should reflect their
performance? A lot less than now, less than now, the same as now, more than now, or a
lot more than now.
ƒƒ To what extent are you prepared to accept a performance-based salary? I already
have one, I am prepared to make my whole salary performance-based, I am prepared to
make part of my salary performance-based, or I am not prepared to do so.
ƒƒ Would you be prepared to work more hours a week if working times were more
flexible? No, yes (up to two extra hours), yes (up to four extra hours, yes (up to six extra
hours), yes (up to eight extra hours), yes (up to ten extra hours), or yes (more than ten
extra hours).
Testing further trade-offs related to the conjoint analysis (not used in analyses, but
listed here for reference)
ƒƒ Which statement do you agree with most when considering [country] in ten years’
time? I want to pay more taxes so that government can perform more tasks than it
currently does, I want to pay the same amount of taxes so that government can perform
the same tasks as it currently does, or I want to pay less taxes so that government
performs fewer tasks than it currently does.
ƒƒ If you think about [country] in ten years’ time and have to choose from the
following scenarios, which scenario would you favour most (or oppose least)? If
a situation does not apply to you, do your best to put yourself in the situation in
question: Slower growth in welfare and lower purchasing power, and I receive more
holidays each year, or faster growth in wellbeing and higher purchasing power, and I
receive fewer holidays each year.
ƒƒ If you think about [country] in ten years’ time and have to choose from the
following scenarios, which scenario would you favour most (or oppose least)? If
a situation does not apply to you, do your best to put yourself in the situation in
question: Slower growth in welfare and lower purchasing power… and I have more free
time, or faster growth in wellbeing and higher purchasing power…and I work more hours
a week.
ƒƒ If you think about [country] in ten years’ time and have to choose from the
following scenarios, which scenario would you favour most (or oppose least)? If
a situation does not apply to you, do your best to put yourself in the situation in
question: Slower growth in welfare and lower purchasing power, and my retirement
age decreases, or faster growth in wellbeing and higher purchasing power, and my
retirement age increases.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
213
.
ƒƒ If you think about [country] in ten years’ time and have to choose from the
following scenarios, which scenario would you favour most (or oppose least)? If
a situation does not apply to you, do your best to put yourself in the situation in
question: Slower growth in welfare and lower purchasing power, and women work more
part-time, or faster growth in wellbeing and higher purchasing power, and women work
more full-time.
ƒƒ If you think about [country] in ten years’ time and have to choose from the
following scenarios, which scenario would you favour most (or oppose least)? If
a situation does not apply to you, do your best to put yourself in the situation in
question: Slower growth in welfare and lower purchasing power, and people over 55
stop working before reaching the retirement age more often, or faster growth in wellbeing
and higher purchasing power, and more people over 55 work up to the retirement age.
ƒƒ If you think about [country] in ten years’ time, and have to choose from the
scenarios below, which scenario would you favour most (or oppose least)? If a
situation does not apply to you, do your best to put yourself in the situation in
question: More immigrants and a higher disposable income, or fewer immigrants and a
lower disposable income.
ƒƒ If you think about [country] in ten years’ time, and have to choose from the
scenarios below, which scenario would you favour most (or oppose least)? If a
situation does not apply to you, do your best to put yourself in the situation in
question: More qualified/educated immigrants and a higher disposable income, or
fewer qualified/educated immigrants and a higher disposable income.
ƒƒ If you think about [country] in ten years’ time, and have to choose from the
scenarios below, which scenario would you favour most (or oppose least)? If a
situation does not apply to you, do your best to put yourself in the situation in
question: It is easier for me to find a job, and the minimum wage is reduced, or it is more
difficult for me to find a job, and the minimum wage is increased.
ƒƒ If you think about [country] in ten years’ time, and have to choose from the
scenarios below, which scenario would you favour most (or oppose least)? If a
situation does not apply to you, do your best to put yourself in the situation in
question: It is easier for me to find a job, and I do not automatically receive annual wage
increases, or it is more difficult for me to find a job, and I automatically receive annual
wage increases.
ƒƒ If you think about [country] in ten years’ time, and have to choose from the
scenarios below, which scenario would you favour most (or oppose least)? If
a situation does not apply to you, do your best to put yourself in the situation
in question: My disposable income decreases, and I have more job security, or my
disposable income increases, and I have less job security.
ƒƒ If you think about [country] in ten years’ time, and have to choose from the
scenarios below, which scenario would you favour most (or oppose least)? If a
situation does not apply to you, do your best to put yourself in the situation in
question: My disposable income decreases, and I invest less time and/or money in my
training, or my disposable income increases, and I invest more time and/or money in
my training.
214
McKinsey Global Institute Appendix
. ƒƒ If you think about [country] in ten years’ time, and have to choose from the
scenarios below, which scenario would you favour most (or oppose least)? If a
situation does not apply to you, do your best to put yourself in the situation in
question: My disposable income decreases, and I work longer for the same employer,
or my disposable income increases, and I change jobs more often.
ƒƒ If you think about [country] in ten years’ time, and have to choose from the
scenarios below, which scenario would you favour most (or oppose least)? If a
situation does not apply to you, do your best to put yourself in the situation in
question: My disposable income decreases, and I do not have to relocate for a better
job, or my disposable income increases, and I have to relocate for a better job.
ƒƒ For which of the goals below are you prepared to work two extra hours per
week, work an extra two years, have four days less holiday, or have 10 percent
less disposable income?270 Longer parental leave, better elderly care, a more
comprehensive health-insurance package, more opportunities for personal
development, better education, a cleaner environment, a higher pension, more police on
the street, higher benefits for people who are unemployed, suffer from a disability or rely
on social welfare, higher disposable income, or none of the above.
ƒƒ The government makes a financial contribution in various situations. Indicate
which of these situations you would prioritise. Rank the following situations,
where one indicates your highest priority. If this situation does not apply to you,
do your best to put yourself in the situation: Having children (e.g., child support),
becoming unemployed (e.g., unemployment benefits/welfare), suffering from a disability
(e.g., disability benefits), ageing (e.g., retirement and pensions), death of a working
partner, or becoming ill (e.g., health/medical insurance).
2.
Growth scenarios and GDP-growth impact sizing for competitiveness
growth drivers
Growth scenarios
External forecasts
The Economist Intelligence Unit, IHS, and the Conference Board all provide country-level
GDP-growth forecasts up to 2025. We calculated the simple average of these three external
benchmarks for each country, and calculated a GDP-weighted average to arrive at the
Europe-30 level forecast figure.
To disaggregate the real GDP-growth figure into the two drivers of labour and productivity,
we used the United Nations Population Division forecast of the change in the workingage population between 2013 and 2025 and assumed this is equal to the change in the
labour component. The labour productivity-growth rate up to 2025 was then calculated by
subtracting the labour growth number from the real GDP-growth number.
2015 growth
The early 2015 European Commission forecast predicts real GDP growth of approximately
1.8 percent across the EU.
For the so-called “boom factors”, we used a number of methods
to estimate the impact of various trends on GDP growth. For lower oil prices, we assessed
the impact of a relative shift in imports and exports after multipliers of petroleum-related
products across the European economy, and cross-referenced this with academic
benchmarks to obtain an estimated range of 0.3 to 1.0 percent impact on real GDP across
Europe. The impact of a depreciated euro and QE are likely to be interrelated.
Taking this
Respondents were offered one of these four options at random. Options 1 to 3 would be offered only if the
respondent was currently in employment.
270
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
215
. into consideration, we based our estimate on an early 2015 European Commission estimate
of the impact on real GDP across the Eurozone. We assumed a conservative mediumterm decrease in the euro’s nominal effective exchange rate of 10 percent and applied our
sizing of the impact across Europe. This exercise gave us a estimate of around 0.3 percent
of GDP. For the impact of QE, we assessed the post-multiplier impact of ECB remittances
from sovereign bond purchases, using a GDP-weighted interest rate across the Eurozone
countries.
This resulted in an estimated impact on real GDP of up to 0.2 percent, assuming
the ECB front-loads its QE programme in 2015. We assumed a GDP-weighted bond rate of
between 1.3 and 2.2 percent.
Official forecast
The European Commission provides a projection of real GDP growth for the EU, as well
as for productivity per hour and the number of hours worked, up to 2025. It expects
productivity to grow at 1.4 percent annually and the number of hours worked to grow by 0.1
percentage points.
For Norway and Switzerland, we assumed the same growth trends hold
as for the EU.
The European Commission expects the EU population to increase up to 2042, due to
convergence of fertility rates across the member states and increasing life expectancy
for both men and women. However, the working-age population is expected to decline,
dropping by 14 percent by 2060 from its 2012 peak, implying there will be a larger number
of persons aged 65 and older. The participation rate in EU-27 is projected to increase by
3.2 percentage points between 2010 and 2060, reaching a level of 78.8 percentage points
in 2060.
Employment rates in the EU are assumed to converge to structural unemployment
rates, and in EU-27 this rate is expected to decline by 3.2 percentage points from 2010 to
2060. Finally, while the total number of hours worked is set to increase in the short run, it is
expected to decline overall by 2060, due to a rising share of part-time workers.271
Catching up with best-practice scenario
In this scenario all Europe-30 countries are assumed to close 50 percent of the gap
between their 2012 labour and labour productivity performance levels and the respective
top-quartile performance seen in Europe-30 in the period from 2007 to 2012.
We measured performance in labour as the number of employees as a share of workingage population and in labour productivity by the amount of GDP generated by an employee
in the respective country. The top-quartile performance for labour-force participation is a
rate of 0.71 employees per working-age population and for labour productivity $96,000 of
GDP (2005 dollars) per employee.
If the 2012 performance of a country on a metric is not
top quartile, we assumed that, by 2025, 50 percent of the gap would be closed. If a country
is already in the top quartile for labour, we assumed that the level remains constant, and if
a country’s performance on labour productivity is already in the top quartile, we assumed
annual growth of 1.4 percentage points to 2025 in line with the long-term average of
productivity growth.
We then calculated the GDP impact by multiplying the 2025 projected percentage of labourforce activation and the expected size of the working-age population, as projected by the
United Nations, to arrive at an expectation of the number of employees, which we then
multiplied by projected labour productivity.
The 2012 ageing report: Economic and budgetary projections for the 27 EU member states (2010–2060),
European Commission, 2012
271
216
McKinsey Global Institute Appendix
. Realising impact from growth drivers
1. Nurturing ecosystem for innovation
If the richest 15 European countries were to take action to increase innovation—measured
by R&D expenditure—to current levels observed in the United States and South Korea, we
estimate that overall European GDP growth could be accelerated by up to 0.26 percentage
points. This estimate is based on historic correlations between R&D expenditure and total
factor productivity growth. For the 15 richest Europe-30 countries, the average annual R&D
spending in 1995 to 2012 and the average annual total factor productivity growth over the
same period are correlated with a correlation coefficient of 0.6 (R²: 0.34); the correlation
coefficient for the 15 poorer countries is zero.
Since the correlation was zero for the poorer
15 countries over the past two decades, no impact has been estimated for these countries.
In the longer run, however, reliance on innovation will increase even in these parts of Europe.
2. Effective education to employment
If European countries were to take action to improve mechanisms between education and
employment, this could increase overall European GDP growth by 0.24 percentage points.
The impact assessment is the cumulative effect of increasing the tertiary graduate share,
reducing vertical mismatch, and reducing the share of the population not in employment,
education, or training (NEETs). The tertiary graduate share is projected to increase to
41.4 percent (EU 2020 target) from the current share of 37.0 percent.
This increase was
multiplied by 0.35, the elasticity of productivity from tertiary education.272 This was, in turn,
multiplied by 0.87, the cross-country correlation between total factor productivity and GDP
growth. Regarding the vertical mismatch, we assumed that European countries close half
the gap to the average vertical mismatch of the five best-practice countries and multiply this
reduction by country-specific estimates of the short-term effect of a 1 percent decrease in
vertical mismatch on the change in per capita GDP.273 The impact of a reduction of NEETs
was calculated by assuming that all Europe-30 countries reach their country-specific EU
2020 targets, and then multiplying the change in the number of NEETs by country-specific
resource costs per NEET.274
3. Productive infrastructure investment
The impact of additional infrastructure spending was assessed for a scenario in which
the Europe-30 increased infrastructure spending by 0.9 percent of GDP per year (from
2.6 percent in 2002 to 2011 to 3.5 percent for the next decade), the additional amount
that our analysis suggests would be required in order to support an overall GDP-growth
rate of 2.5 percent per year.
With an assumed rate of return of 20 percent on additional
infrastructure stock, real GDP growth will increase by 0.14 percent on an annualised basis.
Our estimate did not assume any additional growth impact from improved infrastructure
productivity nor demand side effects.
4. Reduced energy burden
The impact of the reduced energy burden growth driver is based on two primary
components: improved energy efficiency, and liberalised gas and electricity markets. For
the improved energy-efficiency component, a range of energy-use scenarios sourced from
the European Commission, the International Energy Agency, and other academic literature
were analysed to give a baseline view on the incremental improvements to energy efficiency
possible over ten years, and the corresponding annualised impact on GDP growth.
The
incremental annual GDP growth from this component was determined to be 0.05 percent.
For the second component, liberalising gas and electricity markets, the incremental
Dawn Holland et al., The relationship between graduates and growth across countries, Bank for International
Settlements research paper number 110, August 2013.
273
António Morgado et al., Measuring labour mismatch in Europe, CEFAGE-UE working paper number 2014/13,
Center for Advanced Studies in Management and Economics, Universidade de Évora, 2014. .
274
Based on NEETS. See Massimiliano Mascherini et al., NEETS: Young people not in employment, education or
training: Characteristics, costs and policy responses in Europe, Eurofound, October 2012.
272
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
217
.
annual GDP impact, estimated at 0.08 percent, was taken from an EAVA (European Added
Value Unit) report.275 Combined, this gives an annual GDP impact of .13 percent for this
growth driver.
5. Supporting urban development
In aggregate, supporting urban development could boost overall European GDP growth
by 0.09 percentage points. The impact of accelerated urbanisation was calculated by
comparing a scenario in which all Europe-30 countries improve their urbanisation rate at the
rate of the fastest-urbanising country in the period from 2000 to 2012 to a baseline scenario
where urbanisation is assumed to grow at the same rate as in the 2000 to 2012 period in
all countries. The economic benefit stems from the additional number of urban employees
compared with the baseline scenario for each country, multiplied by country-specific
productivity gaps between urban and rural employees.
Historical urbanisation growth rates as well as forecasts of overall population size are
based on data provided by the United Nations.
We calculated the productivity gap between
urban and rural workers using data from MGI’s Cityscope 2.55 and Eurostat, assuming
that the distribution of the working-age population between urban and rural areas is
similar to the distribution of the overall population. For both urban and rural workers, we
assumed that productivity grows at a rate of 1.4 percent per year, in line with the long-term
historical average.
6. Competitive and integrated markets in services and digital
The potential impact of further deepening the Single Market and boosting competition in
the service sector, was projected to be up to 0.43 percentage points.
According to the
European Commission, if all countries implemented the Services Directive to the level of the
five best-performing countries per sector, this could add 0.14 percent to annual GDP growth
between 2015 and 2025.276 Adopting best practice in competition and market integration for
the regulated professions and other local service sectors could add a further 0.29 percent in
annual growth. Creating a truly integrated European digital market could boost annual GDP
growth by 0.4 percent, according to estimates by the European Parliamentary Research
Service.277 We did not include this estimate in our overall estimate, however, because
considerable uncertainty is associated with the digital economy. In transport, the direct
impact is projected to be lower, with most gains from the creation of an integrated transport
network coming from its enabling effect on productivity growth in other areas.
Since these
gains are not quantified, we believe that our overall estimate for growth generated from this
growth driver is conservative.
7. Public-sector productivity
The potential impact of initiatives to improve public-sector productivity was calculated by
assessing the extent to which different areas of public-sector consumption and investment
are amenable to competition-like mechanisms, and by applying the long-term average
productivity-growth rate of the private sector (1.4 percent per year) to a corresponding
share of the spending on these areas. We assumed that 41 percent of total government
final expenditure is amenable to competition-like mechanisms (41 percent represents the
share of compensation in public-sector final expenditure).
Since Europe-30 total publicsector final consumption in 2012 equals 26.4 percent of GDP, this implies that 10.7 percent
of Europe-30 2012 GDP can benefit from acceleration in productivity growth to 1.4 percent
Micaela Del Monte, Cost of non-Europe in the Single Market for energy, European Added Value Unit,
European Parliamentary Research Service, June 2013.
276
Josefa Monteagudo, Aleksander Rutkowski, and Dimitri Lorenzani, The economic impact of the Services
Directive: A first assessment following implementation, European Commission economic paper number 456,
June 2012.
277
Joseph Dunne, Mapping the costs of non-Europe, 2014–19, European Parliament, March 2014.
275
218
McKinsey Global Institute Appendix
. per annum from the current rate of approximately zero percent per annum. This results in
incremental real GDP growth of 0.15 percent annually.
8. Further openness to trade
The impact from this growth driver is assessed as the benefit the Europe-30 could achieve
as by setting up trade agreements with the United States, China, and India. The European
Commission estimates a benefit of $119 billion for the EU resulting from the realisation of
the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership with the United States.
This would be
equivalent to incremental GDP growth of 0.05 percentage points in the EU in the period to
2025. Using export volumes in 2012 to China and India, respectively, as a ratio of Europe’s
2012 exports to the United States, we extrapolated the potential benefit for China and India.
In total, establishing trade agreements with all three countries yields a projected increase in
Europe’s annual real GDP of 0.08 percentage points to 2025.
9. Grey and female labour-force participation
Improved grey and female labour-force participation could add 0.39 percentage points to
Europe’s overall GDP-growth rate.
The impact of improved grey and female labour-force
participation was assessed by comparing a scenario in which all Europe-30 countries
increased participation rates to 2013 best-practice levels in Europe to a base-case scenario
in which rates grow in line with historical experience from countries that have developed
from similar participation rates as the European averages of 2013. For female participation
(25 to 54 years old), the 2013 best-practice level of male participation is found in Slovenia,
translating into a general female participation rate of 89 percent in 2015 compared with
79 percent today. For grey participation (55 to 74 years old), the 2013 best-practice level of
the participation rate of the 25 to 54 age group is found in Hungary, translating to a general
grey participation rate of 49 percent in 2015 compared with 35 percent today.
The impact
estimate was based purely on increased activity rates, keeping employment rates, average
weekly hours worked, and productivity constant.
10. Pro-growth immigration
Strengthening pro-growth immigration systems could boost overall European GDP growth
by 0.26 percentage points. In order to stabilise the prime working-age population over the
next decade exclusively through increased immigration, 11.2 million additional immigrants
to the continent would be required.
We assumed that these additional incoming immigrants
would have a participation rate of 72.2 percent, an employment rate of 90 percent, and
output per worker equal to that of the native population.
11. Enhanced labour-market flexibility
Reforming Europe’s labour markets could increase GDP growth between 0.1 and
0.2 percent a year. The IMF and the ECB estimate that growth would increase by 0.1 percent
per year if Europe were to close half of the gap with the respective “best-in-class” OECD
countries in terms of looser employment protection legislation, moderate unemployment
benefits, and more assertive active labour-market policies.278 Of this total, 0.04 percent
would come from each of employment protection legislation and unemployment benefits,
and 0.01 percent from active labour-market policies.
Other estimates point towards a higher
impact from labour-market flexibility. The OECD has estimated that a one percentage
point reduction in the employment protection legislation score could result in a 0.3 percent
The assumptions behind this calculation are as follows: reduction of half the gap on employment protection
legislation to the average of the three lowest levels in the OECD (Canada, the United Kingdom, and the United
States); reduction in half of the gap in the average replacement rate of unemployment benefits relative to the
average within a set of countries with low replacement rates (Australia, Canada, Japan, New Zealand, the
United Kingdom, and the United States); increase in the ratio of spending on active labour-market policies
relative to six OECD countries with high spending (Austria, Denmark, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden,
and Switzerland). We assume that 80 percent of the long-term potential (to 2060) is realised by 2025.
See
Derek Anderson et al., “Assessing the gains from structural reforms for jobs and growth”, in Jobs and growth:
Supporting the European recovery Martin Schindler et al., eds., IMF, 2014.
278
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
219
. productivity increase.279 This would imply an impact on growth of between 0.1 and
0.2 percent for the same change in employment protection legislation.
3. Investment-requirement sizing for competitiveness growth drivers
In this section, we detail the sources and methodologies used for calculating the costs of
some of the growth drivers discussed in Chapter 3.
Nurturing ecosystem for innovation
Data on GDP and the proportion of GDP spent on R&D were taken from Eurostat.
Each country was benchmarked to a best-practice country on combined private- and
public-sector research spending. The upper-bound benchmark is South Korea, which
spends 3.6 percent of GDP on R&D. The lower bound is the United States, which
spends 2.7 percent of GDP on R&D.
If each country were to increase its R&D to meet
the benchmarks, an increase in spending on R&D of 0.6 to 1.6 percent of EU GDP would
be required. Because data were available only for the share of GDP going to R&D until
2012, where we discuss R&D as a share of GDP, we used 2012 figures. Where values are
expressed in euros, the share applies to 2014 GDP.
Effective education to employment
Data on average spending on education as a proportion of GDP were taken from
Eurostat.
We used a weighted average of the top-scoring countries on the education-toemployment index discussed in Chapter 3, corrected for the size of the student population
in each country.280 For those countries whose z-score is greater than zero, the average is
5.6 percent of GDP. For those with z-scores greater than 0.5, the average is 6.1 percent of
GDP. Raising all countries’ spending on education to the best-practice average (corrected
for the relative proportion of students by country) would require an increase in expenditure
equal to 0.4 to 0.7 percent of EU GDP.
Supporting urban development
Data on the burden of replacing housing in Europe to meet minimum standards were
taken from A blueprint for addressing the global affordable housing challenge, McKinsey
Global Institute, October 2014.
This research estimated the cost in 2012 of replacing all
substandard housing units and the incremental cost of providing housing for new residents
by 2025. Spread over the period from 2012 to 2025, this would require 0.4 to 0.5 percent of
GDP to be invested in improving the housing stock.
Productive infrastructure and energy
We calculated the level of infrastructure investment required to support future growth using
projections of GDP growth. Controlling for asset depreciation, we assumed that countries
sustain a stock of infrastructure equivalent to 70 percent of GDP, in line with global averages.
Using this rule indicates that between 2.9 and 3.5 percent of future GDP would need to be
spent on infrastructure (including power infrastructure) to cover depreciation and keep pace
with growth.
The GDP-weighted average of historical investment stands at 2.6 percent of
GDP based on data from Eurostat. This indicates a spending gap of 0.3 to 0.9 percent.
The 2012 labour market reform in Spain: A preliminary assessment, OECD, December 2013.
The index aggregates each country’s average PISA score, preschool enrolment rate, population in tertiary
education, and research publications.
279
280
220
McKinsey Global Institute Appendix
. 4. Aggregate impact sizing for investment and job creation options
In this section, we discuss our estimates for the size of the impact from different options.
We used annual corporate gross capital formation and GDP data from AMECO for the
EU-28 plus Norway and Switzerland. Data were not available for Bulgaria, Croatia, Ireland,
Luxembourg, or Romania. We found that the average ratio of corporate gross capital
formation over GDP was 12.1 percent between 1998 and 2008, compared with 10.5 percent
in 2015.
This gap, applied to the GDP of the 30 European countries, gives a total corporate
investment gap of €227 billion in 2014 at current market prices.
Maximise spending within the Fiscal Compact
We took data on annual deficits, GDP, and debt levels at market prices from AMECO.
Countries that are not bound by the requirements of the Stability and Growth Pact were
excluded. For each country, we calculated the gap between deficits forecast for 2014 and
the deficit limit. Where there was a gap—and therefore capacity for additional spending—
we calculated this for 2014.
In cases where countries had exceeded their deficit limits, we
assumed that they were already reaching their medium-term budgetary objective set by the
European Commission as fast as appropriate and that no further adjustment was possible.
We made a separate calculation for the capacity for additional spending by Germany, the
only country whose deficit stands below the limit but whose debt reduction obligation allows
additional capacity. Based on a 2013 debt-to-GDP ratio, we calculated a target for the
debt-to-GDP ratio for 2014 following the rule that 1/20th of the gap to the 60 percent target
must be closed. We then compared the target with the forecast 2014 debt level.
The gap
between this forecast and the target represented the additional capacity of 1.3 percent of
GDP in 2014. In euros, the total gap across all countries equals €47.8 billion. Applying fiscal
multipliers for each country (as discussed in the section on fiscal multipliers) results in an
impact on demand of €15 billion to €49 billion.
Match the US post-crisis fiscal impulse
We calculated the structural fiscal impulse using International Monetary Fund data on
deficits as a percentage of GDP for the EU-28 and the United States.
The fiscal impulse is
the previous year’s budget deficit minus the current year’s deficit. The largest gap in the
period from 2008 to 2014 between these two regions was 2.2 percentage points in 2010,
when the United States increased its deficit by 1.9 percentage points while the EU reduced
its deficit by 0.3 percentage points. The average size of the gap was 0.2 percentage points.
The United States had a larger impulse than the EU from 2008 to 2010 and a smaller impulse
from 2011 to 2014.
We modelled the effect in 2014 of an increase in the budget deficit of 0.2 percentage points
and 1.9 percentage points, from the above, to simulate the impact of a strong fiscal impulse.
Assuming the lower impulse of 0.2 percentage points and applying the lower-bound
estimate of fiscal multipliers, we estimated that the impact on demand is €18 billion.
Assuming a larger impulse of 2.2 percentage points and applying the upper bound of
fiscal multipliers, we estimated an impact of €440 billion (to two significant figures) but
acknowledge that this calculation is less accurate and is probably an overestimate.
This is
because the size of the impulse is large relative to the size of the output gap, so the fiscal
multiplier is likely to change significantly as a result of the impulse.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
221
. Introduce partial debt mutualisation
We took data on the actual borrowing requirement and interest rates in 2013 from the
ECB as borrowing requirements for 2014 were not available at the time of writing.281 We
excluded countries that do not use the euro as their currency. We used an average of the
long-term interest rates on representative EMU convergence criteria bonds over the year as
a representative borrowing rate.282 Based on a review of external estimates, we estimated
that the rate for a mutualised Eurobond was 10 basis points to 60 basis points above the
German bund.283 This rate of 1.67 to 2.17 percent on average in 2013 was then applied to the
total borrowing requirement. This resulted in a total net annual saving on borrowing in 2013
of between €6.4 billion and €8.5 billion.
These savings would occur for each year of the maturity of the bond issue. Data on the
specific maturities of bonds issued were not available across the Eurozone.
Assuming
an average maturity of ten years, the total saving on the first year’s issuance would be
€64 billion to €85 billion. It would also be possible to borrow more at new rates to repay
or purchase old bonds, potentially allowing greater savings. We note, however, that not
all countries would choose to use these savings to finance additional spending; some
countries would opt to reduce deficits instead.
Expand the fiscal transfer schemes between countries
We took data on unemployment, GDP, population, and median income from AMECO in
current prices.
We modelled a programme in which each country received payment for each
unemployed citizen equal to between 50 and 70 percent of the national median wage. We
assumed that the cost of this programme is paid in proportion to the current contribution
made by each country to the EU (including traditional own resources) published by the
European Commission. The net effect on each country is multiplied by a range of fiscal
multipliers and added up.
The net effect including multipliers lies between €38 billion and
€56 billion.
Improve access to finance
Data on access to finance were taken from the SAFE survey carried out by the ECB using
first-half 2014 figures. The potential for improvement in each of four categories of company
size was calculated between the overall data relative to Germany’s scores, which we took to
be best practice.284 The difference between the two was weighted by the percentage of the
workforce in each category of firm. We assumed that the resulting gap of 3.4 percent is the
share of the investment gap addressable through financing.
This gap was multiplied by an
estimated one-year multiplier for corporate investment spending between 0.8 and 2.9 based
on economic modelling of a similar effect in the United States. The final effect on output in
Europe is between €6.2 billion and €22.6 billion.
The amount each country borrowed in a year, which can differ from the deficit when, for example, the
government sells or purchases assets.
282
As defined by the ECB, a bundle of bonds with maturities of roughly ten years.
283
See Sergio Mayordomo, Juan Ignacio Peña, and Eduardo S. Schwartz, Towards a common European
Monetary Union risk free rate, NBER working paper number 15353, September 2009; Green paper on the
feasibility of introducing stability bonds, European Commission, November 2011; Christian Aßmann and
Jens Boysen-Hogrefe, Determinants of government bond spreads in the Euro area—in good times as in bad,
Kiel working paper number 1548, September 2009; Patrick Artus, The effect of debt mutualisation in the
euro zone would be more complex than what is usually claimed, Natixis economic research, number 560,
August 2013; Carlo Favero and Alessandro Missale, Sovereign spreads in the euro area: Which prospects
for a Eurobond? presented at an Economic Policy panel meeting in Warsaw, October 27–28, 2011; Séverine
Menguy, “Can Eurobonds save the euro?” in States, banks and the financing of the economy: Monetary
policy and regulatory perspective, Morten Balling, Ernest Gnan, and Patricia Jackson, eds., SUERF, 2013;
Sylvester C.
W. Eijffinger, “Eurobonds—concepts and implications”, in Eurobonds: Concepts and implications:
Compilation of notes for the monetary dialogue of March 2011, European Parliament, March 2011; Rien
Wagenvoort and Sanne Zwart, Uncovering the common risk free rate in the European Monetary Union,
European Investment Bank economic and financial report number 2010/05, September 2010.
284
Large companies are those with 250 employees or more; medium are those with 50 to 249 employees; small
are those with ten to 49 employees; and micro are those with fewer than ten employees.
281
222
McKinsey Global Institute Appendix
. Account for public investments as they depreciate
We took data on annual deficits, GDP, gross capital formation, gross capital consumption,
and all-sector R&D spending at market prices for each country from AMECO. Countries that
are not bound by the requirements of the Stability and Growth Pact were excluded.
For each country, we calculated an infrastructure investment need using the methodology
discussed in Chapter 3.285 This produced an estimate for 2011 as a share of GDP that we
then applied to 2014 GDP, an approach that was not ideal but was necessary because of
limits to the availability of data. Where the investment need was positive, it was treated as
room for additional spending. Where it was negative, we assumed that the presence of
the deficit rule was not the cause of overspending and therefore that spending would not
be affected.
For each country, we calculated an R&D investment need by comparing each nation’s R&D
spending as a proportion of GDP with the investment spending of Japan, the second best
globally in R&D spending at 3.3 percent of GDP.
Where the investment need was positive,
we assumed that half of the gap would require either direct public spending or public
subsidy of private work. Because of limits on the availability of data, we calculated this gap
as a percentage of 2012 GDP and then applied it to 2014 GDP.
We calculated the need for investment in affordable housing for each country with the
methodology used in the October 2014 MGI report on affordable housing.286 Where data
were not available for a particular country, we extrapolated investment need based on the
prevalence of unsuitable housing. We used the “severe deprivation” category in the EU’s
Statistics on Income and Living Conditions database as a proxy, weighted by population
size.
Because of limits on available data, we calculated this gap as a percentage of 2012
GDP and applied it to 2014 GDP.
We then added the need for investment in these three categories—infrastructure, R&D, and
affordable housing—to arrive at a total figure for new spending that would be enabled. The
total figure is €140.4 billion, made up of €34.4 billion on infrastructure, €59.2 billion on R&D,
and €46.8 billion on affordable housing.
In addition, we adjusted the deficit forecast for 2014 by the difference between gross capital
formation and consumption for each country bound by the Fiscal Compact. This increased
the size of deficits, resulting in a €9.0 billion reduction in spending capacity across Europe.
Applying fiscal multipliers for each country (as discussed in the section on fiscal multipliers)
results in an impact on demand of €95 billion to €228 billion.
Carefully adjust taxation and wage structure
We took the marginal propensity to consume for different wealth bands from the ECB’s
2014 report The distribution of wealth and the marginal propensity to consume.
We took the
distribution of net wealth from the ECB’s 2013 Household consumption survey.
We model redistribution as proportional to the store of wealth, calculated using Eurostat’s
household consumption survey and population data. For each wealth quintile, we assumed
a contribution equivalent to 1 percent of wealth, although this need not be in the form of a
tax on the wealth itself. For the bottom quintile, which has negative wealth (net debt), we
did not model a contribution.
We then redistributed the flow to the bottom half of the wealth
distribution and treated it as fresh permanent income. Based on the marginal propensity
to consume of each quintile, this gives us an estimate of the loss of consumption and the
We assume a long-term trend of 70 percent of GDP in infrastructure, and calculate the amount of investment
required to make up for depreciation and growth of GDP.
286
A blueprint for addressing the global affordable housing challenge, McKinsey Global Institute, October 2014.
285
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
223
. increase in consumption that accompanies the redistribution. The net size of this effect is
€189 billion to €206 billion.
Household consumption multipliers were estimated within a model provided by Oxford
Economics to be between 0.50 and 1.32 by applying a shock to household consumption
through government redistribution funded by an increase in corporate taxes. After
multipliers, the output effect is €95 billion to €273 billion.
Unleash the silver economy
Using Eurosystem reports, we estimated the approximate wealth of Eurozone households,
broken out by age category. When using an upper and lower bound of the proportion of
wealth that is liquid (such as deposits, and other non-housing-type assets), we estimate
that converting 1 percent of this wealth into consumption could provide a spending boost of
between 0.3 and 0.6 percent of Eurozone GDP, using a fiscal multiplier of 1.0.
Issue vouchers to households redeemable with the ECB
We derived the marginal propensity to consume and the distribution of wealth the same
way as we did in the case of wealth redistribution.
Here, however, the programme is funded
through the creation of new money rather than through taxation. In addition, the funds are
distributed evenly across the population rather than being targeted at the bottom half. This
programme would be slightly smaller than proposed “QE-lite” programmes to purchase
covered bonds and asset-backed securities announced by the ECB in late 2014 and slightly
larger than tax breaks given in the United States in 2008.
The size of this effect would be
€246 billion to €272 billion of additional direct consumption. After multipliers, this rises to
between €207 billion and €395 billion, which could be sufficient to close the Eurozone’s
output gap.
Fiscal multipliers
We drew on econometric analyses where possible to arrive at fiscal multipliers that
represent the effect in a single year of a change in government spending on demand.
However, these estimates were available for both recessionary and non-recessionary
periods only for France, Germany, Italy, Spain, and the United Kingdom. For these countries,
where possible, we used a range of multiple sources for recessionary fiscal multipliers (and
non-recessionary multipliers for Germany).
Where econometric analysis was not available for smaller economies, we used the
approach advocated in the 2014 IMF report Fiscal multipliers: Size, determinants and use
in macroeconomic projections.
This requires the assessment of a national economy on six
dimensions, with adjustments for the business cycle and monetary-policy conditions:
1. We assessed low openness to trade as being cases where the ratio of imports to GDP
was less than 30 percent.
2. We assessed high labour-market rigidities using the OECD Employment Protection
Legislation Index, using the central point of the index as the threshold value.
3. We defined low automatic stabilisers as being when the level of public spending as a
share of GDP was below 40 percent, as suggested by the IMF.
4. We assessed fixed or quasi-fixed exchange rates for Eurozone members and countries
with a currency pegged to the euro or as part of the exchange rate mechanism (ERM-II)
to reduce exchange rate variability.287
The ERM-II maintains currency exchange rates within a band of a central rate with the euro. It currently applies
only to Lithuania and Denmark.
287
224
McKinsey Global Institute Appendix
. 5. We assessed “safe” public debt as being below 100 percent of GDP, as suggested by
the IMF.
6. We assessed the effectiveness of public expenditure management using the World
Bank Worldwide Governance Indicators, choosing the central value of the index as the
threshold value.
We then assigned countries a basic multiplier of 0.1 to 0.3 if they met up to two of the six
criteria, 0.4 to 0.6 if they met three, and 0.7 to 1.0 if they met more than three (Exhibit A5).
Where a country was borderline on three or more criteria, we adjusted the country up or
down to reflect this. The adjustment affected only Greece.
We then corrected for the stage of the business cycle. As recommended by the IMF, we
estimated this as a 60 percent increase in the fiscal multiplier at the peak of recession. We
determined the stage of the recession using output gaps as calculated by the European
Commission and taken from AMECO.
For each country, we found a historical maximum and
minimum output gap. We then averaged these across countries with a separate category
for large (GDP greater than €1 trillion), medium (GDP €300 billion to €1 trillion), and small
(GDP less than €300 million) economies. We then determined the position of each country
relative to this average maximum and used the ratio used as a factor for judging the severity
of the recession.
Using this approach, it was possible for a country to have a modifier greater
than 60 percent. For example, Greece’s output gap is estimated to be 10.9 percent, while
the average maximum output gap for a small economy was 6.1 percent. The ratio of those
figures is greater than one, so the business cycle adjustment for Greece is 107 percent,
greater than the IMF’s upper estimate.
We also applied monetary-policy corrections.
We took Eurozone countries, countries with
a euro peg, and countries that are part of an ERM-II arrangement as being at the zero lower
bound and applied a correction of an additional 30 percent to the fiscal impulse. The United
Kingdom and Sweden were also taken to be at the lower bound, while Romania, Hungary,
Poland, and Croatia were not.
Total impact
In total, we estimate that Europe could unleash investment in innovation, education,
infrastructure, and energy of €250 billion to €550 billion a year and, by closing its output
gap and mobilising the workforce, create more than 20 million new jobs. To derive the
€250 billion to €550 billion range for investment, we took the 1.7 to 3.7 percent estimate for
the annual investment required for the growth drivers and applied it to Europe-30 GDP.
We
obtained the figure for new jobs created through the cumulative addition of new jobs through
several sources. First, we assume that closing the European output gap of 2.4 percent
would create approximately 2.4 percent new jobs, assuming constant productivity. We
then add the number of incremental jobs created by the grey and female labour-force
participation and immigration growth drivers to obtain the cumulative figure of 20 million
incremental jobs by 2025.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
225
.
Exhibit A5
Fiscal multipliers
Output gap
%
Lower-bound
multiplier1
Upper-bound
multiplier1
Austria
-1.1
0.6
0.9
Belgium
-1.1
1.1
1.5
Bulgaria
-0.1
0.9
1.3
Croatia
-3.4
0.5
0.8
Cyprus
-6.1
0.8
1.2
Czech Republic
-2.0
0.6
0.9
Denmark
-3.8
0.7
1.1
Estonia
1.4
0.8
1.2
Finland
-3.1
0.7
1.0
France
-2.3
0.2
2.1
Germany
-0.8
0.2
1.0
Greece
-10.9
1.1
1.6
Hungary
-0.7
0.1
0.3
Ireland
-0.2
0.5
0.8
Italy
-4.5
1.6
2.1
Latvia
1.0
0.9
1.2
Lithuania
0.2
0.9
1.3
-2.1
1.1
1.6
0.1
0.9
1.3
Netherlands
-3.0
1.3
1.9
Poland
-0.8
0.1
0.3
Portugal
-5.0
0.8
1.2
Romania
-1.3
0.5
0.7
Slovakia
-3.3
1.2
1.7
Slovenia
-2.7
1.2
1.6
Spain
-6.0
1.3
2.5
Sweden
-1.6
0.6
1.0
United Kingdom
-0.8
0.1
1.0
Country
Luxembourg
Malta
Estimates
taken from
empirical
studies
1 Multiplier is an estimated one-year fiscal multiplier for increase in government expenditure in country's current
circumstances.
SOURCE: Batini, IMF, 2014; Batini, IMF, 2012; Baum, 2012; Hernández de Cos and Moral-Benito, 2013; McKinsey Global
Institute analysis
226
McKinsey Global Institute Appendix
. Chapter end photo: Tulips
© Getty Images
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
227
. Chapter photo
Biblio: Flags
© Getty Images
228
McKinsey Global Institute Appendix
. BIBLIOGRAPHY
A
Ægisdóttir, StefaniÌa, Lawrence H. Gerstein, and Deniz Canel Çinarbas, “Methodological
Issues in cross-cultural counseling research: Equivalence, bias, and translations”, The
Counseling Psychologist, volume 36, March 2008.
Afxentiou, Panos C., “Convergence, the Maastricht criteria, and their benefits”, The Brown
Journal of World Affairs, volume VII, issue 1, winter-spring 2000.
Agency for the Cooperation of Energy Regulators and Council of European Energy
Regulators, ACER/CEER annual report on the results of monitoring the internal electricity
and natural gas markets in 2011, November 2012.
Agency for the Cooperation of Energy Regulators and Council of European Energy
Regulators, ACER/CEER annual report on the results of monitoring the internal electricity
and natural gas markets in 2013, October 2014.
Alesina, Alberto, and Dani Rodrik, “Distributive policies and economic growth”, The
Quarterly Journal of Economics, volume 109, number 2, 1994.
Amorós, José Ernesto, and Neils Bosma, Global Entrepreneurship Monitor 2013
global report: Fifteen years of assessing entrepreneurship across the globe, Global
Entrepreneurship Research Association, 2014.
Anderson, Derek, Bergljot Barkbu, Lusine Lusinyan, and Dirk Muir, “Assessing the gains
from structural reforms for jobs and growth”, in Jobs and growth: Supporting the European
recovery, Martin Schindler, Helge Berger, Bas B. Bakker, and Antonio Spilimbergo, eds.,
IMF, 2014.
Aranki, Ted, and Corrado Macchiarelli, Employment duration and shifts into retirement in
the EU, London School of Economics Europe in Question discussion paper number 58,
February 2013.
Ardagna, Silvia, Francesco Caselli, and Timothy Lane, Fiscal discipline and the cost of public
debt service: Some estimates for OECD countries, NBER working paper number 10788,
September 2004.
Arnold, Jens, Do tax structures affect aggregate economic growth? Empirical evidence
from a panel of OECD countries, OECD economics department working paper number 643,
October 2008.
Artus, Patrick, The effect of debt mutualisation in the euro zone would be more complex
than what is usually claimed, Natixis economic research, number 560, August 2013.
Aßmann, Christian, and Jens Boysen-Hogrefe, Determinants of government bond
spreads in the Euro area—in good times as in bad, Kiel working paper number 1548,
September 2009.
. Association for Financial Markets in Europe, Unlocking funding for European investment
and growth: An industry survey of obstacles in the European funding markets and potential
solutions, 2013.
Association for Financial Markets in Europe, The role of secondary markets and market
making in the long-term financing of the European economy, AFME briefing note, June 2013.
Ayres, Robert U., and Benjamin Warr, “Accounting for growth: The role of physical work”,
Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, volume 16, issue 2, June 2005.
B
Bairoch, Paul, The economic development of the third world since 1900, University of
California Press, 1975.
Barbiero, Francesca, and Zsolt Darvas, “In sickness and in health: Protecting and
supporting public investment in Europe”, Bruegel Policy Contribution, issue 2014/02,
February 2014.
Bassanini, Andrea, and Romain Duval, “The determinants of unemployment across OECD
countries: Reassessing the role of policies and institutions”, OECD Economic Studies,
number 42, issue 1, 2006.
Batini, Nicoletta, Luc Eyraud, Lorenzo Forni, and Anke Weber, Fiscal multipliers: Size,
determinants and use in macroeconomic projections, IMF, September 2014.
Batini, Nicoletta, Giovanni Callegari, and Giovanni Melina, Successful austerity in the United
States, Europe and Japan, IMF working paper 12/190, July 2012.
Baum, Anja, Marcos Poplawski-Ribeiro, and Anke Weber, Fiscal multipliers and the state of
the economy, IMF working paper 12/286, December 2012.
BBC, Sweden cuts rates below zero and starts QE, February 12, 2015.
Beach, R., M. Webster, and K. M. Campbell, “An evaluation of partnership development in
the construction industry”, International Journal of Project Management, volume 23, issue 8,
November 2005.
Beardsley, Scott C., Luis Enriquez, Sheila Bonini, Sergio Sandoval, and Noëmie Brun,
“Fostering the economic and social benefits of ICT”, in Global information technology report
2009–2010, Soumitra Dutta and Irene Mia, eds., World Economic Forum, March 2010.
Beltramello, Andrea, Koen De Backer, and Laurent Moussiegt, The export performance
of countries within global value chains (GVCs), OECD science, technology, and industry
working paper number 2012/02, April 2012.
Berthou, Antoine, and Guillaume Gaulier, “Wage dynamics and current account rebalancing
in the euro area”, Bulletin de la Banque de France, issue 30, 2013.
Blanchard, Olivier J., and Francesco Giavazzi, Improving the SGP through a proper
accounting of public investment, Centre for Economic Policy Research discussion paper
number 4220, February 2004.
Böckers, Veit, Justus Haucap, and Ulrich Heimeshoff, Benefits of an integrated European
electricity market, Düsseldorfer Institut für Wettberwerbsökonomie discussion paper
number 109, September 2013.
230
McKinsey Global Institute Bibliography
.
Boeri, Tito, Michael Burda, and Francis Kramarz, eds., Working hours and job sharing in the
EU and USA: Are Europeans lazy? Or Americans crazy? Oxford University Press, 2008.
Bond, Ian, The EU and defence procurement, Centre for European Reform, January 2014.
Braga, Michela, Daniele Checchi, and Elena Meschi, Institutional reforms and educational
attainment in Europe: A long run perspective, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) discussion
paper number 6190, December 2011.
Bravo-Ortega, Claudio, and Álvaro García Marin, “R&D and productivity: A two way
avenue?” World Development, volume 39, issue 7, July 2011.
Brock, H. Woody, Quantitative easing: Myths and half-truths, Strategic Economic Decisions,
October 2012.
Brunzell, Tor, Eva Liljeblom, and Mika Vaihekoski, “Determinants of capital budgeting
methods and hurdle rates in Nordic firms”, Accounting & Finance, volume 53, issue 1,
March 2013.
Bryant, Chris, “BASF to focus investments outside Europe”, The Financial Times, February
25, 2014.
Buiter, Willem H., Helicopter money: Irredeemable fiat money and the liquidity trap, NBER
working paper number 10163, December 2003.
Buiter, Willem H., “The ‘sense and nonsense of Maastricht’ revisited: What have we learnt
about stabilization in EMU?” Journal of Common Market Studies, volume 44, issue 4,
November 2006.
Buiter, Willem H., The simple analytics of helicopter money: Why it works—always, Kiel
Institute for the World Economy economics discussion paper number 2014–24, 2014.
Burger, Bruno, Electricity production from solar and wind in Germany in 2014, Fraunhofer
ISE (Institut für Solare Energiesysteme), December 2014.
Buti, Marco, Alessandro Turrini, and Paul van den Noord, Reform and be re-elected:
Evidence from the post-crisis period, Vox, Centre for Economic Policy Research, July 2014.
C
Carroll, Christopher D., Jiri Slacalek, and Kiichi Tokuoka, The distribution of wealth and the
marginal propensity to consume, European Central Bank working paper number 1655,
March 2014.
Ceci-Renaud, Nila, and Paul-Antoine Chevalier, “L’impact des seuils de 10, 20 et 50 salariés
sur la taille des entreprises françaises”, Économie et Statistique, number 437, March 2011.
Chawla, Mukesh, Gordon Betcherman, and Arup Banerji, “Aging, savings, and financial
markets”, in From red to gray: The “third transition” of aging populations in Eastern Europe
and the former Soviet Union, World Bank, 2007.
Checherita-Westphal, Cristina D., and Philipp Rother, The impact of high and growing
government debt on economic growth: An empirical investigation for the euro area,
European Central Bank working paper number 1237, August 2010.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
231
. Chen, Natalie, and Dennis Novy, International trade integration: A disaggregated approach,
CEP discussion paper number dp0908, Centre for Economic Performance, London School
of Economics, 2009.
Cingano, Federico, Trends in income inequality and its impact on economic growth, OECD
social, employment and migration working paper number 163, December 2014.
Coeuré, Benoit, Structural reforms: Learning the right lessons from the crisis, presented at
an economic conference in Latvijas Banka, Riga, October 17, 2014.
D
Darvas, Zsolt, Fiscal federalism in crisis: Lessons for Europe from the US, Bruegel,
July 2010.
De Bonis, Riccardo, and Andrea Silvestrini, “The effects of financial and real wealth on
consumption: New evidence from OECD countries”, Applied Financial Economics, volume
22, issue 5, March 2012.
De Nederlandsche Bank, “Securitisation rules: ‘Significant risk transfer’, retention and due
diligence”, fact sheet, February 2014.
Del Monte, Micaela, Cost of non-Europe in the Single Market for energy, European Added
Value Unit, European Parliamentary Research Service, June 2013.
Deloitte, Comparative immigration study 2013–2014: Migration formalities for third-country
nationals in 26 European countries, November 2013.
Dullien, Sebastian, and Ferdinand Fichtner, “A common unemployment insurance system
for the euro area”, DIW Economic Bulletin, volume 3, issue 1, January 2013.
Dunne, Joseph, Mapping the cost of non-Europe, 2014–19, European Parliament,
March 2014.
Duval, Romain, The retirement effects of old-age pension and early retirement schemes
in OECD countries, OECD Economics Department working paper number 370,
November 2003.
Dynan, Karen, “Is a household debt overhang holding back consumption?” Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, spring 2012.
E
ECDL Foundation, Digital literacy report—2009, 2009.
The Economist, “Why Swedish men take so much paternity leave”, July 22, 2014.
Edelman, 2015 Edelman trust barometer, January 2015.
Eijffinger, Sylvester C. W., “Eurobonds—concepts and implications”, in Eurobonds:
Concepts and implications: Compilation of notes for the monetary dialogue of March 2011,
European Parliament, March 2011.
Elekdag, Selim, and Dirk Muir, Das Public Kapital: How much would higher German public
investment help Germany and the euro area? IMF working paper number 14/227, 2014.
232
McKinsey Global Institute Bibliography
. Ellis, Mark, Experience with energy efficiency regulations for electrical equipment, OECD/
International Energy Agency, August 2007.
Enderlein, Henrik, and Jean Pisani-Ferry, Reforms, investment and growth: An agenda for
France, Germany, and Europe, Hertie School of Governance, November 2014.
Escribano, Alvaro, Andrea Fosfuri, and Josep A. Tribó, “Managing external knowledge
flows: The moderating role of absorptive capacity”, Research Policy, volume 38, issue 1,
February 2009.
European Central Bank, Banking structures report, November 2013.
European Central Bank, “ECB announces expanded asset purchase programme”, press
release, January 22, 2015.
European Central Bank, Euro area bank lending survey, April 2014.
European Central Bank, The eurosystem household finance and consumption survey:
Results from the first wave, statistics paper series number 2, April 2013.
European Central Bank, Survey on the access to finance of enterprises in the euro area,
November 2014.
European Central Bank, Survey on the access to finance of small- and medium-sized
enterprises, November 2013.
European Central Bank and Bank of England, The case for a better functioning securitisation
market in the European Union: A discussion paper, May 2014.
European Central Bank and Bank of England, The impaired EU securitisation market:
Causes, roadblocks and how to deal with them, April 2014.
European Commission, Building a capital markets union, green paper, February 2015.
European Commission, Energy economic developments in Europe, January 2014.
European Commission, “The EU’s bilateral trade and investment agreements: Where are
we?” press release, December 3, 2013.
European Commission, EEO review: Employment policies to promote active ageing
2012, 2012.
European Commission, European energy security strategy, 2014.
European Commission, European system of accounts 2010, Eurostat, June 2013.
European Commission, Europeans’ satisfaction with urban transport, Flash Eurobarometer
382b, June 2014.
European Commission, Green paper on the feasibility of introducing stability bonds,
November 2011.
European Commission, Innovation Union scoreboard 2014, March 2014.
European Commission, Internal market, Special Eurobarometer 398, October 2013.
European Commission, Key data on early childhood education and care in Europe, 2014
edition, Eurydice and Eurostat report, 2014.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
233
. European Commission, Long-term financing of the European economy, green paper,
March 2013.
European Commission, Monitoring consumer markets in the European Union 2013, Part I,
August 2013.
European Commission, “Public opinion in the European Union”, Standard Eurobarometer
82, December 2014.
European Commission, A single market for growth and jobs: An analysis of progress made
and remaining obstacles in the member states, November 2013.
European Commission, The 2012 ageing report: Economic and budgetary projections for
the 27 EU member states (2010–2060), 2012.
European Commission, The 2012 ageing report: Underlying assumptions and projection
methodologies, 2011.
European Commission and European Investment Bank, “Factsheet 2: Where does the
money come from?” November 2014.
European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions, Employment
trends and policies for older workers in the recession, 2012.
European Global Navigation Satellite Systems Agency, GNSS Market Report, issue 3,
October 2013.
European Parliament, Better governance of the Single Market: An assessment
accompanying the European Parliament’s legislative own-initiative report (rapporteur
Andreas Schwab, MEP), European Added Value Assessment number 2, 2013.
European Parliament, “Resolution of 8 October 2013 on effects of budgetary constraints for
regional and local authorities regarding the EU’s structural funds expenditure in the member
states”, October 2013.
European Union, “Directive on services in the internal market”, Directive 2006/123/EC, 2006.
European Union, “774% difference in phone call prices across the EU”, press release,
August 6, 2013.
European Union and OECD, Matching economic migration with labour market needs,
September 2014.
European Venture Capital Association, European Private Equity Activity Data 2007–2013,
May 2014.
F
Favero, Carlo, and Alessandro Missale, Sovereign spreads in the euro area: Which
prospects for a eurobond? presented at an Economic Policy panel meeting in Warsaw,
October 27–28, 2011.
Fawley, Brett W., and Christopher J. Neely, “Four stories of quantitative easing”, Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, volume 95, number 1, January/February 2013.
234
McKinsey Global Institute Bibliography
. Forbes, “The world’s most innovative companies”, August 2014.
Fougère, Denis, Francis Kramarz, and Julien Pouget, Youth unemployment and crime in
France, IZA discussion paper number 2009, March 2006.
Frankel, Jeffrey, and Jesse Schreger, “Over-optimistic official forecasts and fiscal rules in the
Eurozone”, Review of World Economics, volume 149, issue 2, June 2013.
G
Gardiner and Theobald, International construction cost survey, December 2011.
Garicano, Luis, Claire LeLarge, and John Van Reenen, Firm size distortions and the
productivity distribution: Evidence from France, NBER working paper number 18841,
February 2013.
Gas infrastructure Europe, LNG import potential to Europe, presentation at Ifri Energy
roundtable in Brussels, April 29, 2014.
Geier, Alain, The debt brake: The Swiss fiscal rule at the federal level, Swiss Federal Finance
Administration working paper number 15, February 2011.
Gill, Indermit S., and Chor-Ching Goh, “Scale economies and cities”, World Bank Research
Observer, volume 25, number 2, August 2010.
Gill, Indermit S., and Martin Raiser, Golden growth: Restoring the lustre of the European
economic model, World Bank, January 2012.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Joshua D. Gottlieb, The wealth of cities: Agglomeration economies
and spatial equilibrium in the United States, NBER working paper number 14806,
March 2009.
Global Commission on the Economy and Climate, Better growth, better climate: The new
climate economy report, September 2014.
Goldin, Claudia, “The U-shaped female labor force function in economic development and
economic history”, in Investment in women’s human capital, T. Paul Schultz, ed., University
of Chicago Press, 1995.
Gordon, Robert J., Is US economic growth over? Faltering innovation confronts the six
headwinds, NBER working paper number 18315, August 2012.
Gregory, Robert G., The two-step Australian immigration policy and its impact on immigrant
employment outcomes, IZA discussion paper number 8061, March 2014.
H
Hairault, Jean-Olivier, Thepthida Sopraseuth, and François Langot, “Distance to retirement
and older workers’ employment: The case for delaying the retirement age”, Journal of the
European Economic Association, volume 8, issue 5, September 2010.
Hall, Peter A., and David Soskice, eds., Varieties of capitalism: The institutional foundations
of comparative advantage, Oxford University Press, 2001.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
235
. Hasan, Iftekhar, Krzysztof Jackowicz, Oskar Kowalewski, and Åukasz KozÅ‚owski, Bank
ownership structure, SME lending and local credit markets, Bank of Finland research
discussion paper number 22/2014, 2014.
Havik, Karel, Kieran Mc Morrow, Fabrice Orlandi, Christophe Planas, Rafal Raciborski,
Werner Röger, et al., The production function methodology for calculating potential
growth rates and output gaps, European Commission economic paper number 535,
November 2014.
Hendeliowitz, Jan, Danish employment policy: National target setting, regional performance
management and local delivery, Danish National Labour Market Authority, February 2008.
Hernández de Cos, Pablo, and Enrique Moral-Benito, Fiscal multipliers in turbulent times:
The case of Spain, Banco de España working paper number 1309, 2013.
Hirt, Martin, and Paul Wilmott, “Strategic principles for competing in the digital age”,
McKinsey Quarterly, May 2014.
Holland, Dawn, Iana Liadze, Cinzia Rienzo, and David Wilkinson, The relationship between
graduates and economic growth across countries, Bank for International Settlements
research paper number 110, August 2013.
Honda, Gail, “Differential structure, differential health: Industrialization in Japan 1868–1940”,
in Health and welfare during industrialization, Richard Steckel and Roderick Floud, eds.,
University of Chicago Press, 1997.
Hufbauer, Gary Clyde, Jeffrey J. Schott, and Woan Foong Wong, “Figuring out the Doha
Round”, Policy Analyses in International Economics, number 91, July 2010.
Huxley, Joe, Value capture finance: Making urban development pay its way, Urban Land
Institute, 2009.
I
Infrastructure UK, Infrastructure cost review, July 2014.
Infrastructure UK, Infrastructure cost review: Technical report, December 2010.
Institute for Fiscal Studies, Mirrlees Review, 2010.
International Council on Clean Transportation, European vehicle market statistics, 2013,
October 2013.
International Energy Agency, Capturing the multiple benefits of energy efficiency,
September 2014.
International Energy Agency, Energy efficiency market report 2013: Market trends and
medium-term prospects, 2013.
International Energy Agency, Medium-term gas market report 2013: Market trends and
projections to 2018, June 2013.
IMF, Euro area policies: 2014 Article IV consultation, selected issues, IMF Country Report
number 14/1999, July 2014.
IMF, Global financial stability report: Moving from liquidity- to growth-driven markets,
April 2014.
236
McKinsey Global Institute Bibliography
. IMF, World economic outlook: Legacies, clouds, uncertainties, October 2014.
IMF, World economic outlook: Recovery strengthens, remains uneven, April 2014.
J
Jagannathan, Ravi, David A. Matsa, Iwan Meier, and Vefa Tarhan, Why do firms use high
discount rates? Social Science Research Network (SSRN) Electronic Journal, June 2014.
Jensen, J. Bradford, Global trade in services: Fear, facts, and offshoring, Peterson Institute
for International Economics, 2011.
Jousten, Alain, M. Lefèbvre, S.
Perelman, and P. Pestieau, The effects of early retirement
on youth unemployment: The case of Belgium, IMF working paper number 08/30,
February 2008.
JP Morgan, European banks: All eyes on funding: LCR, the next undiscounted regulatory
headwind, 2011.
K
Kapetanios, George, Haroon Mumtaz, Ibrahim Stevens, and Konstantinos Theodoridis,
Assessing the economy-wide effects of quantitative easing, Bank of England working paper
number 443, January 2012.
Kapteyn, Arie, Adriaan S. Kalwij, and Asghar Zaidi, The myth of worksharing, IZA discussion
paper number 188, August 2000.
Kawaguchi, Daiji, and Tetsushi Murao, Labor market institutions and long-term effects of
youth unemployment, IZA discussion paper number 8156, April 2014.
Kingfisher, European home report 2014, 2014.
Koo, Richard C., “The world in balance sheet recession: Causes, cure, and politics”, RealWorld Economics Review, issue number 58, 2011.
Kowalski, Przemyslaw, Comparative advantage and trade performance: Policy implications,
OECD trade policy paper number 121, October 2011.
KPMG International, KPMG’s individual income tax and social security rate survey 2012,
October 2012.
Krebs, Tom, and Martin Scheffel, “Macroeconomic evaluation of labor market reform in
Germany”, IMF Economic Review, volume 61, number 4, December 2013.
Kumhof, Michael, and Romain Rancière, Inequality, leverage and crises, IMF working paper
number 10/268, November 2010.
L
Llewellyn Consulting, Financing Europe’s investment and economic growth, June 2014.
Lora, Eduardo, and Mauricio Olivera, “What makes reforms likely: political economy
determinants of reforms in Latin America”, Journal of Applied Economics, volume VII,
number 1, May 2004.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
237
.
M
Mammen, Kristin, and Christina Paxson, “Women’s work and economic development”,
Journal of Economic Perspectives, volume 14, number 4, fall 2000.
Mascherini, Massimiliano, Lidia Salvatore, Anja Meierkord, and Jean-Marie Jungblut,
NEETs: Young people not in employment, education or training: Characteristics, costs and
policy responses in Europe, Eurofound, October 2012.
Mayordomo, Sergio, Juan Ignacio Peña, and Eduardo S. Schwartz, Towards a
common European Monetary Union risk free rate, NBER working paper number 15353,
September 2009.
McKinsey & Company, Better for less: Improving public sector performance on a tight
budget, July 2011.
McKinsey & Company, “The energy advantage: How Germany can benefit in energy
efficiency”, in Energy efficiency: A compelling global resource, 2010.
McKinsey & Company, McKinsey-Studie zu Industrie 4.0: Deutsche Unternehmen trotz
wachsender Konkurrenz zuversichtlich, 2015.
McKinsey Center for Government, Education to employment: Getting Europe’s youth into
work, January 2014.
McKinsey Center for Government, Transforming government performance through lean
management, December 2012.
McKinsey Financial Services Practice, Breakaway: How leading banks outperform through
differentiation: McKinsey global banking annual review 2013, November 2013.
McKinsey Global Institute, Beyond austerity: A path to economic growth and renewal in
Europe, October 2010.
McKinsey Global Institute, A blueprint for addressing the global affordable housing
challenge, October 2014.
McKinsey Global Institute, Building globally competitive cities: The key to Latin American
growth, August 2011.
McKinsey Global Institute, Creating economic growth in Denmark through competition,
November 2010.
McKinsey Global Institute, Debt and deleveraging: Uneven progress on the path to growth,
January 2012.
McKinsey Global Institute, Debt and (not much) deleveraging, February 2015.
McKinsey Global Institute, Disruptive technologies: Advances that will transform life,
business, and the global economy, May 2013.
McKinsey Global Institute, From poverty to empowerment: India’s imperative for jobs,
growth, and effective basic services, February 2014.
McKinsey Global Institute, Global flows in a digital age: How trade, finance, people, and data
connect the world economy, April 2014.
238
McKinsey Global Institute Bibliography
. McKinsey Global Institute, Global growth: Can productivity save the day in an aging world?
January 2015.
McKinsey Global Institute, Growth and renewal in the Swedish economy: Development,
current situation and priorities for the future, May 2012.
McKinsey Global Institute, India’s urban awakening: Building inclusive cities, sustaining
economic growth, April 2010.
McKinsey Global Institute, Internet matters: The Net’s sweeping impact on growth, jobs,
and prosperity, May 2011.
McKinsey Global Institute, Investing in growth: Europe’s next challenge, December 2012.
McKinsey Global Institute, Lions go global: Deepening Africa’s ties to the United States,
August 2014.
McKinsey Global Institute, Manufacturing the future: The next era of global growth and
innovation, November 2012.
McKinsey Global Institute, A new dawn: Reigniting growth in Central and Eastern Europe,
December 2013.
McKinsey Global Institute, Open data: Unlocking innovation and performance with liquid
information, October 2013.
McKinsey Global Institute, Preparing for China’s urban billion, March 2009.
McKinsey Global Institute, QE and ultra-low interest rates: Distributional effects and risks,
November 2013.
McKinsey Global Institute, Resource revolution: Meeting the world’s energy, materials, food,
and water needs, November 2011.
McKinsey Global Institute, Trading myths: Addressing misconceptions about trade, jobs,
and competitiveness, May 2012.
McKinsey Global Institute, Urban America: US cities in the world economy, April 2012.
McKinsey Global Institute, Urban world: Cities and the rise of the consuming class,
June 2012.
McKinsey Global Institute, Urban world: Mapping the economic power of cities, March 2011.
McKinsey Global Institute, Urban world: The shifting global business landscape,
October 2013.
McKinsey Global Institute, The world at work: Jobs, pay, and skills for 3.5 billion people,
June 2012.
McKinsey Global Institute and McKinsey Infrastructure Practice, Infrastructure productivity:
How to save $1 trillion a year, January 2013.
McKinsey on Society, How the world’s best-performing school systems come out on top,
September 2007.
McKinsey Public Sector Practice, The public-sector productivity imperative, March 2011.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
239
. Meier, Iwan, and Vefa Tarhan, Corporate investment decision practices and the hurdle rate
premium puzzle, SSRN Electronic Journal, January 2007.
Menguy, Séverine, “Can eurobonds save the euro?” in States, banks, and the financing of
the economy: Monetary policy and regulatory perspective, Morten Balling, Ernest Gnan, and
Patricia Jackson, eds., SUERF, 2013.
Mersch, Yves, Capital markets union: The “why” and the “how”, speech at the Joint EIB-IMF
High Level Workshop in Brussels, October 22, 2014.
Monteagudo, Josefa, Aleksander Rutkowski, and Dimitri Lorenzani, The economic impact of
the Services Directive: A first assessment following implementation, European Commission
economic paper number 456, June 2012.
Morgado, António, Tiago Neves Sequeira, Marcelo Santos, Alexandra Ferreira-Lopes,
and Ana Balcão Reis, Measuring labour mismatch in Europe, CEFAGE-UE working
paper number 2014/13, Center for Advanced Studies in Management and Economics,
Universidade de Évora, 2014.
Mosca, Ilaria, “Evaluating reforms in the Netherlands’ competitive health insurance system”,
Eurohealth, volume 18, number 3, January 2012.
Muellbauer, John, Combatting Eurozone deflation: QE for the people, Vox, December
23, 2014.
Muller, Patrice, Dimitri Gagliardi, Cecilia Caliandro, Nuray Unlu Bohn, and Demetrius Klitou,
Annual report on European SMEs 2013/2014: A partial and fragile recovery, Final report,
European Commission, July 2014.
N
Nath, Chandrika, Autonomous road vehicles, Houses of Parliament PostNote number 443,
September 2013, amended April 2014.
National Association of State Budget Officers, Capital budgeting in the states, spring 2014.
Navaretti, Giorgio Barba, Matteo Bugamelli, Fabiano Schivardi, Carlo Altomonte, Daniel
Horgos, and Daniela Maggioni, The global operations of European firms: The second EFIGE
policy report, Breugel Blueprint Series, volume XII, July 2011.
O
Olson, Mancur, The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups,
Harvard University Press, 1965.
Onaran, Özlem, and Giorgos Galanis, Is aggregate demand wage-led or profit-led? National
and global effects, Conditions of work and employment series number 40, International
Labour Organisation, 2012.
OECD, Ageing and employment policies: Norway 2013: Working better with age, June 2013.
OECD, Better Life Index, 2014.
OECD, Demand-side innovation policies, May 2011.
240
McKinsey Global Institute Bibliography
. OECD, Economic policy reforms: Going for growth 2013, 2013.
OECD, Economic policy reforms: Going for growth 2015, 2015
OECD, Employment outlook 2013, 2013.
OECD, Entrepreneurship at a glance 2013, July 2013.
OECD, International migration outlook 2011, July 2011.
OECD, “Mobility and migration in Europe”, in OECD Economic Surveys: European Union
2012, March 2012.
OECD, OECD Pensions outlook 2012, 2012.
OECD, Pensions at a glance, 2011.
OECD, Pensions at a glance, 2012.
OECD, Recruiting immigrant workers: Germany 2013, February 2013.
OECD, Recruiting immigrant workers: Sweden 2011, December 2011.
OECD, Reviews of innovation policy: Korea, 2009.
OECD, The 2012 labour market reform in Spain: A preliminary assessment, December 2013.
OECD Committee of Fiscal Affairs Forum on Strategic Management, Principles of good
tax administration—practice note, Centre for Tax Policy and Administration, amended
May 2001.
P
Pace, Scott, Gerald P. Frost, Irving Lachow, David R. Frelinger, Donna Fossum, Don
Wassem, and Monica M. Pinto, The Global Positioning System: Assessing national policies,
Rand Corporation, 1995.
Paldam, Martin, “Safe havens in Europe: Switzerland and the ten dwarfs”, European Journal
of Comparative Economics, volume 10, number 3, December 2013.
Panayotou, Theodore, “Economic growth and the environment”, presented at the spring
seminar of the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe in Geneva, March 3, 2003.
Pasquier, Sara, and Aurelien Saussay, Progress implementing the IEA 25 energy efficiency
policy recommendations: 2011 evaluation, International Energy Agency, March 2012.
Pelkmans, Jacques, “The economics of Single Market regulation”, Bruges European
Economic Policy Briefings, number 25, College of Europe, 2012.
Pelkmans, Jacques, and Andrea Renda, “Does EU regulation hinder or stimulate
innovation?” Regulatory Policy, Centre for European Policy Studies special report number
96, November 2014.
Pesaran, M.
Hashem, and Ron P. Smith, Counterfactual analysis in macroeconometrics: An
empirical investigation into the effects of quantitative easing, IZA discussion paper number
6618, June 2012.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
241
. Peterson, George E., Unlocking land values to finance urban infrastructure, World
Bank, 2009.
Petrella, Andrea, Fostering innovation through public procurement: Rationale,
implementation and best practice in Italy and Europe, Bank of Italy Regional Economic
Research Department, 2013.
PricewaterhouseCoopers and the World Bank/International Finance Corporation, Paying
taxes 2013: The global picture, November 2013.
R
Rajan, Raghuram G., Fault lines: How hidden fractures still threaten the world economy,
Princeton University Press, 2010.
Rincon-Aznar, Ana, and W. S. Siebert, Employment protection, productivity, wages and jobs
in Europe, INDICSER discussion paper number 36, December 2012.
Rogers, Howard, The impact of a globalising market on future European gas supply and
pricing: The importance of Asian demand and North American supply, Oxford Institute for
Energy Studies, January 2012.
Rubini, Loris, Klaus Desmet, Facundo Piguillem, and Aránzazu Crespo, Breaking down the
barriers to firm growth in Europe: The fourth EFIGE policy report, Bruegel Blueprint Series,
volume XVIII, August 2012.
S
Salomäki, Aino, and Teresa Munzi, Net replacement rate of the unemployed: Comparisons
of various approaches, European Union economic paper number 133, February 1999.
Sapir, André, “Globalization and the reform of European social models”, Journal of Common
Market Studies, volume 44, number 2, June 2006.
Sinclair, David, Jessica Watson, and Brian Beach, Working longer: An EU perspective,
International Longevity Centre, September 2013.
Statistics Finland, Special education 2013: Share of students having received special
support diminished, June 2014.
Stern, David I., “The rise and fall of the environmental Kuznets curve”, World Development,
volume 32, issue 8, August 2004.
Sykes, Brooke, Mobile talent? The staying intentions of international students in five EU
countries, Migration Policy Group, April 2012.
T
Tadjeddine, Karim, “‘A duty to modernize’: Reforming the French civil service”, McKinsey
Quarterly, April 2011.
Tereanu, Eugen, Anita Tuladhar, and Alejandro Simone, Structural balance targeting and
output gap uncertainty, IMF working paper number 14/107, June 2014.
242
McKinsey Global Institute Bibliography
. Teulings, Coen, and Richard Baldwin, eds., Secular stagnation: Facts, causes and cures,
Centre for Economic Policy Research, August 2014.
Thévenon, Olivier, Policy drivers of female labour force participation in OECD countries,
presented at Seminar on Early Childhood Education and Care in Brussels, December
4, 2013.
Tilford, Simon, and Philip Whyte, eds., Innovation: How Europe can take off, Centre for
European Reform, July 2011.
Tompson, William, and Robert Price, The political economy of reform: Lessons from
pensions, product markets and labour markets in ten OECD countries, OECD, 2009.
Turner, Adair, “Population ageing: What should we worry about?” Philosophical Transactions
of the Royal Society, volume 364, issue 1532, October 2009.
U
United Kingdom Office for National Statistics, Public service productivity estimates: Total
public services, 2010, April 2013.
US Energy Information Administration, “Figure MT-46: U.S. exports of liquefied natural gas in
five cases, 2005–40”, in Annual Energy Outlook 2014, April 2014.
US White House, Executive order: Making open and machine readable the new default for
government information, May 9, 2013.
V
Van Campenhout, Geert, and Tom Van Caneghem, “How did the notional interest deduction
affect Belgian SMEs’ capital structure?” Small Business Economics, volume 40, issue 2,
February 2013.
Van der Ende, Martin, Peter Donker van Heel, Kenneth Walsh, Jena de Wit, and Natalija
Ziminiene, European vacancy and recruitment report 2012, European Commission,
November 2012.
Van de Vijver, Fons, and Norbert K. Tanzer, “Bias and equivalence in cross-cultural
assessment: An overview”, Revue européenne de psychologie appliquée, volume 54, issue
2, 2004.
VTT Technical Research Centre of Finland, “Smoother passenger traffic across the FinnishRussian border”, press release, April 15, 2014.
W
Wagenvoort, Rien, and Sanne Zwart, Uncovering the common risk free rate in the European
Monetary Union, European Investment Bank economic and financial report number
2010/05, September 2010.
Walker, Tom, “Why economists dislike a lump of labor”, Review of Social Economy, volume
65, issue 3, September 2007.
World Bank, World development report 2009: Reshaping economic geography, 2008.
McKinsey Global Institute
A window of opportunity for Europe
243
. World Economic Forum, The competitiveness of cities, August 2014.
World Economic Forum, Enhancing Europe’s competitiveness: Fostering innovation-driven
entrepreneurship in Europe, June 2014.
World Economic Forum, Global competitiveness report 2013–2014, September 2013.
World Economic Forum, Global competiveness report 2014–2015, September 2014.
Z
Zachmann, Georg, and Valeria Cipollone, “Energy competitiveness”, in Manufacturing
Europe’s future, Reinhilde Veugelers, ed., Breugel Blueprint Series, volume XXI, 2013.
Zipfel, Frank, and Caroline Heinrichs, The impact of tax systems on economic growth in
Europe: An overview, DB Research, Deutsche Bank, October 2012.
244
McKinsey Global Institute Bibliography
. RELATED MGI
AND MCKINSEY RESEARCH
Global growth: Can productivity save the day
in an aging world? (January 2015)
Without action, global economic growth
will almost halve in the next 50 years. A new
McKinsey Global Institute report offers a solution:
a dramatic improvement in productivity.
Game changers: Five opportunities for US
growth and renewal (July 2013)
Five “growth drivers” have the potential to add
hundreds of billions of dollars to annual GDP and
create millions of new jobs by 2020.
Global flows in a digital age: How trade,
finance, people, and data connect the world
economy (April 2014)
The movement of goods and services, finance,
and people has reached previously unimagined
levels. Global flows are creating new degrees
of connectedness among economies—and
playing an ever-larger role in determining the fate
of nations, companies, and individuals. To be
unconnected is to fall behind.
McKinsey Insights app
Explore insights from McKinsey, MGI, and
McKinsey Quarterly—all delivered seamlessly to
your mobile devices.
Broaden your knowledge
and widen your perspective on our latest thinking
on issues facing senior leaders and spanning all
industries, functions, and geographies.
A new dawn: Reigniting growth in Central and
Eastern Europe (December 2013)
The nations of Central and Eastern Europe
were among the fastest growing in the world
before the global financial crisis. Restoring
that kind of growth will require a strategy that
raises investment, expands high-value exports,
unleashes productivity in domestic sectors,
revives foreign direct investment, and increases
domestic savings.
www.mckinsey.com/mgi
E-book versions of selected MGI reports are available at MGI’s website,
Amazon’s Kindle bookstore, and Apple’s iBooks Store.
Download and listen to MGI podcasts on iTunes or at
www.mckinsey.com/mgi/publications/multimedia/
Cover image: Thumbs up © iStockphoto.
Contents page images: Woodworkers © Getty Images; .scientists
© Getty Images; writers © Corbis.
Infographic by Darby Films.
. McKinsey Global Institute
June 2015
Copyright © McKinsey & Company
www.mckinsey.com/mgi
@McKinsey_MGI
McKinseyGlobalInstitute
.