Playing it Safe?
Managerial Preferences, Risk, and Agency Conflicts*
Todd A. Gormley† and David A. Matsa‡
June 6, 2014
Abstract
This paper examines risk-averse managers’ incentive to “play it safe” by taking valuedestroying actions that reduce their firms’ risk of distress. We find that, after managers
are insulated by the passage of an antitakeover law, firms increase diversifying
acquisitions by about a third relative to firms that operate in the same state and industry
but are not affected by the law.
These acquisitions target “cash cows,” are funded largely
with equity, and are concentrated among firms with a greater risk of distress. Consistent
with a reduction firm-level risk, we also find that affected firms’ stock volatility
decreases and their cash holdings increase. Our findings suggest that shareholders face
governance challenges beyond motivating managerial effort.
(JEL D22, D81, G32, G34, K22)
Keywords: risk aversion, managerial preferences, agency conflicts
*
For helpful comments, we thank seminar participants at Pennsylvania State University Harrisburg, University of
Melbourne, University of New South Wales, University of Pennsylvania (Wharton), University of Sydney,
University of Technology Sydney, and University of Virginia (Darden),.
Matthew Denes and Christine Dobridge
provided research assistance. Gormley thanks the Rodney L. White Center for Financial Research Brandywine
Global Investment Management Research Fellowship for financial support.
†
The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 3620 Locust Walk, Suite 2400, Philadelphia, PA, 19104.
Phone:
(215) 746-0496. Fax: (215) 898-6200. E-mail: tgormley@wharton.upenn.edu
‡
Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University, and NBER, 2001 Sheridan Road, Evanston, IL 60208.
Phone: (847) 491-8337.
Fax: (847) 491-5719. E-mail: dmatsa@kellogg.northwestern.edu
. “The dangers of taking too much risk are very clear. We’re reminded of
them in the news every day…Unfortunately, we rarely hear any warnings
about playing it safe…The dangers of playing it safe aren’t sudden,
obvious, and dramatic. They don’t make headlines…The dangers of
playing it safe are hidden, silent killers.”
— Taking Smart Risks, by Doug Sundheim
Managers of publicly held corporations do not always act in the best interests of their
shareholders. Agency theories of the firm tend to focus on three aspects of managerial preferences
causing these conflicts: private benefits, costly effort, and risk aversion.
First, managers have an incentive
to undertake value-destroying activities that create private benefits for themselves, such as in “empire
building” (Baumol, 1959; Marris, 1964; Williamson, 1964). Second, managers might exert less effort
than what shareholders desire, so as to “enjoy the quiet life” (Holmström, 1979; Grossman and Hart,
1983; Bertrand and Mullainathan, 2003). Whereas existing empirical studies mostly focus on these two
agency conflicts, this paper aims to shed light on the third: a risk-averse manager has the incentive to take
on less risk than desired by a diversified shareholder or may even undertake value-destroying actions that
reduce the firm’s risk (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Amihud and Lev, 1981; Smith and Stulz, 1985;
Holmstrom, 1999).
This “playing it safe,” as its described in Doug Sundheim’s business book Taking
Smart Risks (see above), reduces the incidence of negative corporate outcomes that are personally costly
to the manager, both financially and in terms of reputation and future career prospects. Although
managerial risk aversion is pervasive in agency theory, the empirical importance of risk-related conflicts
is less clear. This paper examines the empirical relevance of such conflicts.
Agency conflicts arising from managers’ risk aversion have implications for both economic
outcomes and optimal corporate policy.
Taking on risk is almost always a prerequisite for creating
shareholder value, so failing to take risks can hamper long-term economic growth.1 Managerial risk
aversion also implies that agency problems might also play out differently in normal times than when
times are tough. Although managers may exert too little effort in normal times, they may be overly active
1
For example, observers have argued that an increasingly risk-averse culture among U.S. workers, entrepreneurs,
and firms contributes to the long-term slowing of the U.S.
economy (Casselman, 2013).
1
. in trying to reduce risk in periods of distress. The corporate policies and compensation structures that
maximize shareholder value are also quite different if risk-aversion, rather than costly effort, is a
fundamental driver of managerial preferences. For example, while increasing firm leverage can induce a
manager to exert greater effort (Jensen, 1986), it can amplify conflicts arising from managers’ risk
aversion by increasing the firm’s (and manager’s) exposure to risk. Likewise, an increase in a manager’s
ownership stake might exacerbate, rather than reduce, agency conflicts because the ownership interest
increases a manager’s incentive to reduce the firm’s risk.
To assess the importance of agency conflicts arising from managers’ risk aversion, we exploit
state anti-takeover laws in the United States as a source of variation in external shareholder governance.
During 1980s, many states passed “business combination” (BC) laws that made it more difficult to
complete a hostile takeover of firms incorporated in the state.
Because hostile takeovers usually involve
replacing the manager, an active market for corporate control is thought to play an important role in
corporate governance (Manne, 1965; Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Scharfstein, 1988). By making it more
difficult to remove a manager who engages in value-destroying activities, BC laws weaken external
shareholder governance and increase the scope for managerial agency conflicts. To examine the
importance of motives to play it safe, we exploit the BC laws’ staggered adoption across states and
employ a difference-in-difference strategy, similar to that of Bertrand and Mullainathan (2003) and
others, that compares changes in the behavior of firms incorporated in states that enact BC laws to that of
firms incorporated elsewhere.
We control for both unobserved heterogeneity across firms and timevarying, unobserved heterogeneity across industries; and because many firms are incorporated in a
different state than they are located, we are able to further control for unobserved time-varying, state-level
economic conditions in our analysis.
We find that firms reduce their risk when the threat of a hostile takeover declines. Relative to
firms headquartered in the same state and operating in the same 4-digit SIC industry, stock volatility
declines by 2.3 percentage points, on average, after passage of a BC law for firms incorporated in that
state. This corresponds to a roughly 5 percent drop in firms’ volatility.
We also find that affected firms
2
. increase their holdings of cash; average cash holdings increase by 13 percent after a BC law is adopted,
and firms’ cash to asset ratio increases by about 10 percent.
Although these results imply that agency costs lead managers to reduce their firms’ risk, it does
not clarify the source of this conflict. In principle, the results may reflect either managers’ risk aversion or
their reluctance to exert effort. Managers’ risk aversion could be motivating them to play it safe and work
explicitly to reduce their firms’ risk. Alternatively, a reluctance to exert costly managerial effort could
lead to fewer risky investments, which could inflate a firm’s cash holdings and reduce stock volatility.
To
investigate the nature of the relevant agency conflict, we analyze firms’ acquisition activity. We focus on
acquisitions for two reasons. First, prior evidence suggests that managers use diversifying acquisitions as
a way to reduce their firms’ risk (Amihud and Lev, 1981; Gormley and Matsa, 2011).
Second, any
observed increase in acquisitions would be inconsistent with managers simply exerting less effort when
governance is weakened.2
Consistent with managers exerting more effort to reduce their firms’ risk, we find that firms
sharply increase their diversifying acquisitions. Firms affected by the reduced threat of a takeover are, on
average, 15 percent more likely to undertake an acquisition after the law is passed relative to unaffected
firms operating in the same 4-digit SIC industry and state. The timing of this increase coincides with the
passage of a BC law; there is no evidence of a pre-existing differential trend in acquisitions.
The average
cumulative abnormal return (CAR) associated with acquisitions undertaken by firms after a BC law’s
adoption is −1.26 percent, about two-thirds of the increased acquisitions are diversifying acquisitions, and
the acquisitions are largely funded with equity rather than cash. After a BC law is adopted, the types of
firms’ targeted by acquisitions also changes; affected firms are more likely to acquire “cash cows”—large
firms with significant cash flow and payouts.
To distinguish between playing it safe and empire building motives for the increase in
2
While an increase in acquisitions after passage of an anti-takeover law might seem counterintuitive, it is important
to recognize that the BC laws only make hostile takeovers of target firms incorporated in that state more difficult;
friendly mergers are unaffected by the law, as are hostile takeovers of firms incorporated elsewhere, even when the
acquirer is incorporated in the affected state.
3
. diversifying acquisitions, we analyze the differential response of firms based on their ex-ante leverage
and cash flow. If the acquisitions are driven by empire building motives, we would expect the increase in
acquisitions to be more prominent among firms with high cash flow and low leverage such that the
manager has a larger amount of free cash flow at his or her disposal (Jensen, 1986). On the other hand, if
the increase in acquisitions is driven by risk-reducing motives, then we would expect the increase in
acquisitions to be concentrated among firms at a greater risk of distress, including firms with low cash
flow and high leverage. To test for this heterogeneity, we use the matching difference-in-difference
estimator from Gormley and Matsa (2011) to compare estimates across subsamples.
Consistent with managers playing it safe, the increase in diversifying acquisitions are
concentrated among firms at greater risk of distress and lower cash flow prior to the passage of the BC
law.
Affected firms with an above median leverage immediately prior to the BC law are 1.5 percentage
points more likely to undertake an acquisition after a BC law is adopted relative to non-affected firms
with similar leverage levels. We find no increase in the likelihood or number of acquisitions by firms with
a below median leverage. We find a similar result when cutting the sample on another measure of firms’
bankruptcy risk—the Altman z-score.
The increase in acquisitions is also concentrated among firms with
a below median ratio of cash flow to assets before the law is adopted. The average firm with below
median cash flow undertakes about 25 percent more diversifying acquisitions after a BC law is adopted,
while there is no change in the number of diversifying acquisitions by affected firms with above median
cash flow. The results are similar when we use the payment of dividends as a proxy for a firm having
greater cash flow and less distress risk.
Overall, our evidence suggests that avoiding empire building and motivating managerial effort
are not the only challenges shareholders face.
While prior research has found evidence that weakened
governance is associated with managers exerting less effort and enjoying the quiet life (Bertrand and
Mullainathan, 2003), we show that, for many firms, weakened governance leads managers to play it safe
4
. by actively working to reduce their firms’ risks.3 We complement the existing literature by showing that
various aspects of managerial preferences manifest when governance is weakened and that the most
salient aspect varies across firms.
The multiplicity of managerial agency conflicts implies that there are tradeoffs in the how
leverage and managerial ownership affect agency conflicts within the firm. For example, increasing a
manager’s ownership stake does not necessarily better align their interests with those of diversified
shareholders. Although the ownership stake induces greater effort, it also increases a risk-averse
manager’s incentive to make value-destroying decisions that reduce the firm’s risk. This tradeoff is
overlooked in empirical studies that rely on managers’ ownership stake as a proxy for the extent of
agency conflicts between managers and shareholders.
Our paper builds upon the small, but growing, literature on how managers’ exposure to risk can
affect how they manage their firms.
In a seminal paper, Chevalier and Ellison (1999) show that career
concerns and the fear of termination affect mutual fund managers’ portfolio choices. Kempf, Reunzi, and
Thiele (2009) find further evidence of career concerns in the mutual fund industry. We apply the same
idea of career concerns and fear of termination to corporate leadership.
In that regard, our findings are
related to those of Tufano (1996, 1998), Low (2010), Acharya, Amihud, and Litov (2011), Gormley and
Matsa (2011), Kim and Lu (2011), and Panousi and Papanikolaou (2012). We build on this literature by
showing how managers’ preference to reduce risk can manifest in specific corporate policies when
governance is weakened and how the importance of this agency conflict varies across firms.
Our paper also builds on the literature studying the importance of BC and other anti-takeover
laws. Although papers have found evidence of firms and managers reducing their exposure to risk
3
In practice, the difference between the “quiet life” and “playing it safe” conflicts can be difficult to distinguish in
reduced form estimations and the theories are interrelated.
For example, for some managers, the ultimate motive of
playing it safe could be to achieve a quiet life of less managerial effort. Furthermore, playing it safe might not entail
much effort at all if it simply entails foregoing risky investments. The key distinction between what we observe and
what has been shown previously, however, is that some managers do not simply exert less effort when governance is
weakened, and that these increased efforts appear to be driven by managers’ exposure to the firm’s risk.
5
.
following the passage of a BC law,4 our paper is the first to show that the reduction in risk is not merely a
side effect of managers exerting less effort but instead seems to reflect an agency conflict arising from
managers’ risk aversion. Our analysis also illustrates how this tendency to play it safe varies across firms.
In this regard, our paper is also similar to Giroud and Mueller (2010), Kose, Li, and Pang (2010), and
Atanassov (2013), which find that the severity of agency conflicts arising from costly effort are likely to
be more severe for firms in less competitive industries, firms with greater cash flow, and less leverage. In
contrast, we show that another agency conflict, the conflict arising from managers’ risk aversion, is more
severe for firms with lower free cash flow and greater leverage.
Finally, our paper illustrates the importance of properly accounting for unobserved heterogeneity
and of avoiding bad controls. The existing literature’s focus on agency conflicts arising from costly effort
is largely driven by the lack of evidence that firms increase their acquisitions when takeover threats are
reduced.
We show that the failure to detect this increase in acquisitions was driven by two errors in the
workhorse empirical specification relied on in this literature: the average effects (AvgE) estimator
(Gormley and Matsa, 2014) and “bad” controls (Angrist and Pischke, 2009). Our difference-in-difference
estimations control for firm, industry-year, and state-year unobserved heterogeneities using fixed effects
(instead of an AvgE estimator)5 and exclude time-varying controls that could be affected by the passage
of the BC law and thus introduce a selection bias. Given the frequent use of AvgE estimators and
endogenous controls in the finance and accounting literature, our findings serve as a warning of how these
flawed approaches can confound researchers’ inferences.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows.
Section 1 describes our identification
strategy and data. Section 2 describes our findings, while Section 3 provides interpretation and additional
4
For example, Garvey and Hanka (1999) find that firms reduce their leverage; Cheng, Nagar, and Rajan (2004) find
that managers reduce their ownership stakes; Yun (2009) finds that firms increase their cash holdings relative to
lines of credit; Francis, Hasan, John, and Waisman (2010) find that bond values increase; and Atanassov (2013)
finds that patenting declines.
5
Even though BC laws are passed at the state level, we are able to include state-year fixed effects because many
firms are located and incorporated in different states. Whether a firm is affected by the BC law passage is function
of where the in firm is incorporated; not where it is located.
This lack of overlap in state of operations and
incorporation for many firms allows us to control for time-varying, state-level economic conditions.
6
. evidence regarding the heterogeneity in responses. Section 4 concludes.
1. Empirical framework
In the cross-section, weaker shareholder governance is correlated with reduced risk-taking by
firms. Figure 1 plots the correlations between various measures of firms’ risk-taking and the governance
index from Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2003), a standard proxy for firms’ external shareholder
governance.
Using data from all years in which the Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick index is available,
averages of the various measures of firms’ risk-taking are plotted for each governance index score with at
least 50 observations, and the reported regression line is weighted based on the number of underlying
observations. The figure shows that weaker shareholder governance (i.e., a higher governance index
score) is associated with lower stock volatility, lower cash flow volatility, more cash holdings, and more
diversifying acquisitions. The magnitudes of these correlations are sizable.
Relative to the sample
average, a one standard deviation decrease in shareholder governance is associated with a 9 percent
decline in stock volatility (t-stat = 12.3, adjusted for clustering at the firm level), a 10 percent reduction in
cash flow volatility (t-stat = 4.5), a 13 percent increase in cash holdings (t-stat = 3.9), and a 9 percent
increase in diversifying acquisitions (t-stat = 2.4). These cross-sectional correlations are consistent with
managers playing it safe when external governance is weaker.
These statistical relations between shareholder governance and firms’ riskiness, however, might
not reflect a causal relation. Standard proxies for governance, such as the governance index, institutional
ownership, and board size, might be correlated with factors, such as firm size or investment opportunities,
that directly affect the firm risk.
Failure to control for all of these factors could introduce an omitted
variable bias that confounds the cross-sectional relations. Simultaneity bias could also distort these
relations, as a firm’s governance and risk are likely jointly determined; for example, firms that operate in
riskier environments might elicit stronger shareholder governance, all else equal.
1.1. Business combination laws
To overcome these challenges and to determine the importance of playing it safe motives, we
7
.
follow Bertrand and Mullainathan (2003) and use U.S. states’ passage of antitakeover laws as a negative
shock to firms’ shareholder governance. The idea behind this identification strategy is that the threat of a
takeover reduces agency conflicts between managers and shareholders. Takeovers and the market for
corporate control discipline managers because value-destroying activities impair the firm’s stock value
and invite a potential takeover that would result in the manager’s termination (e.g., see Manne, 1965;
Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Scharfstein, 1988).
When the threat of a takeover is weakened, managers will
be freer to act upon their underlying preferences that do not align with shareholders’ interests. Consistent
with this, Karpoff and Malatesta (1989) find that the initial press announcement of antitakeover
legislation in a state is associated with a negative stock price reaction for affected firms.6
We focus on the adoption of business combination (BC) laws across states as a source of
variation in takeover threats. BC laws, also known as freeze-out laws, were passed by 30 states between
1985 and 1991; the list and timing can be found in Appendix Table A.1.
These laws, which were upheld
by the Supreme Court in 1987 (CTS v. Dynamics Corp.), were viewed as the most stringent antitakeover
laws passed at the time (Bertrand and Mullainathan, 2003).7 While the laws’ particular provisions varied
by state, BC laws typically prevent a wide range of business combination transactions—including the sale
of assets, mergers, share exchanges, and spinoffs—between a target firm and an interested acquirer for
three to five years unless the target’s board of directors approves the transaction prior to the acquirer
becoming an interested shareholder (which is typically defined as owning more than 10-20 percent of the
target). These state laws applied only to target firms incorporated in the state and are thought to have
6
Although in theory takeover threats could foster “managerial myopia” by discouraging profitable long-term
investments that are undervalued by equity markets (Stein 1988), empirical research has found no evidence that the
antitakeover legislation we analyze had this effect.
In addition to the negative stock price reaction to these laws
(Karpoff and Malatesta, 1989), the laws are associated with reduced total factor productivity (Bertrand and
Mullainathan, 2003). Furthermore, the investments focused on in our analysis—whole-firm acquisitions—are
subject to robust public scrutiny and debate, unlike the actions typically focused on in theories of managerial
myopia, such as the sales of individual assets and long-term capital investments (Auletta, 1986).
7
In addition to BC laws, other antitakeover laws passed at the time included fair price (FP) laws and control share
(CS) laws. FP laws regulated the price of takeover bids and other significant business combinations, while CS laws
required that target shareholders preapprove any acquisition of voting rights above a certain level.
For detailed
discussions of these laws, see Romano (1987), Karpoff and Malatesta (1989), and Bertrand and Mullainathan
(2003). Following the prior literature, we focus on BC laws in our analysis because they were viewed by many as
being the most stringent of the new state-level, antitakeover laws (Bertrand and Mullainathan, 2003).
8
. significantly reduced the threat of a hostile takeover in those states.8
Romano (1987) and Bertrand and Mullainathan (2003) analyze the political economy of the BC
laws’ passage and find that the passage of these laws typically did not result from the pressures of a large
coalition of economic players in the state. Given the lack of broad-based lobbying, these authors conclude
that an omitted economic variable is unlikely to explain measured effects of the law. Indeed, we find no
measureable differences in the characteristics of firms incorporated in states adopting the laws before the
laws come into effect. Nevertheless, we control for any political economy or business cycle factors that
may have coincided with or led to the passage of the antitakeover law by including both location state-byyear and industry-by-year fixed effects in our analysis.
Finally, we also examine the timing of the effects,
and find that law precedes the effects we assign to it rather than the other way around. For these reasons,
political economy or business cycle factors are unlikely to explain our results.
1.2. Empirical specification
We exploit the staggered adoption of BC laws across U.S.
states to evaluate the importance of
playing it safe motives in managerial preferences. Using a difference-in-differences estimator, we
compare changes among firms located in states that pass a BC law to changes among firms incorporated
elsewhere. The underlying identification assumption is that, but for the law, the two sets of firms would
follow parallel trends; that is, the change in outcome y for firms incorporated in the states that pass a BC
law would have been the same as for firms incorporated in states that did not pass a BC law.
Specifically, we estimate:
y= β1 BCst + f i + ωlt + λ jt + ηijlst ,
ijlst
(1)
where y is the outcome of interest for firm i, in industry j, located in state l, incorporated in state s, in year
8
Consistent with this, Comment and Schwert (1995) find evidence that passage of a BC law is associated with an
increase in takeover premiums paid to targets.
While Comment and Schwert (1995) do not find evidence of a decline
in the likelihood of a takeover, Garvey and Hanka (1999) note that this can occur in equilibrium even when BC laws
reduce the takeover threat. By reducing the takeover threat, BC laws will increase managers’ ability to engage in
value-destroying behavior, which has an offsetting effect of increasing the gains to doing a hostile acquisition.
Consistent with this argument, Giroud and Mueller (2010) find evidence that the likelihood of a takeover does
decline in more competitive industries, where this offsetting effect is argued to be smaller.
9
. t; BC is an indicator that equals 1 if state s has passed a BC law by year t; fi are firm fixed effects; ωlt are
state-year fixed effects; and λjt are 4-digit SIC industry-year fixed effects. We include the firm fixed
effects to control for unobserved, time-invariant heterogeneity across firms; state-year fixed effects to
control for unobserved, time-varying heterogeneities across states; and industry-year fixed effects to
control for unobserved, time-varying heterogeneities across industries. The inclusion of these fixed effects
ensures that our difference-in-difference estimates are robust to many types of unobservable omitted
variables that might otherwise confound our analysis (Gormley and Matsa, 2014). Finally, we adjust the
standard errors for clustering at the state of incorporation, s, level.
Our difference-in-difference estimate, β1, is identified using within-state-year and withinindustry-year variation that relaxes the parallel trends assumption underlying our estimation.
We are able
to obtain estimates for the BC laws’ effects even after including state-year fixed effects because more
than 60 percent of our firms are incorporated and located in different states. Our estimates are identified
by comparing the differential response of two firms that operate in the same state, l, but where only one of
these firms is incorporated in a state, s, that passes a BC law. Thus, any unobserved, time-varying statelevel factors, such as local business cycles, that might coincide with a BC law’s adoption and affect our
outcome of interest will not bias our findings.
Including industry-year fixed effects further mitigates
identification concerns. With their inclusion, our findings are robust to any potential variation in the
composition of industries across states or differential trends across industries over time.
Our analysis also takes advantage of the staggered entry of BC laws across states. Each new
passage of a BC law provides another comparison of the differential response of treated firms, and firms
affected by later events are allowed to act as controls for earlier events further improving the internal
validity of our identification strategy.
Our estimation strategy differs from previous analyses of BC laws in two ways.
First, to account
for state- and industry-specific trends, existing studies control for state-year and industry-year averages of
the dependent variables in their regression specifications. Gormley and Matsa (2014) refer to this
empirical approach as an Average Effects (AvgE) estimator. Second, the estimation is further augmented
10
.
to include a vector of time-varying controls, Xijlst, thought to affect the outcome of interest.
That approach, however, is biased. First, the industry-year and state-year controls measure the
unobserved heterogeneities with error, and this measurement error introduces a bias that confounds
inferences (Gormley and Matsa, 2014).9 Second, the inclusion of time-varying controls, X, into the
difference-in-difference estimation can also introduce a bias if any of these controls are affected by
passage of the BC law. Angrist and Pischke (2009) refer to such endogenous variables as “bad controls.”
For example, prior studies of how BC laws affect firms’ acquisition activity have included a time-varying
control for firm size; but presumably, if passage of the BC law affects acquisition activity, it will also
affect firm size. Therefore, inclusion of firm size as a control can introduce a bias.
Our estimation avoids
these biases by estimating fixed effects instead of average effects and by excluding endogenous controls.
1.3. Sample, data sources, and descriptive statistics
We study firms’ financial data from Compustat over the period from 1976 to 2000, excluding
regulated utility firms (SIC codes 4900-4999), firms located or incorporated outside the U.S., and firmyear observations with either missing or negative assets or sales. The BC law changes occurred between
1985 and 1991, so we selected our sample period to include at least 10 years of data both before and after
the laws’ adoption.
Although this sample period is slightly longer than the 1976–1995 time period
examined by Bertrand and Mullainathan (2003), our findings are robust to using the shorter time frame.
Our data on acquisitions are from the Securities Data Company’s (SDC) U.S. Mergers and Acquisitions
Database, which begins in 1980.
BC laws affect firms based on their state of incorporation at the time. Compustat, however, only
reports firms’ most recent state of incorporation and state of location, which we use as a control variable.
Thus, firms that changed their state of incorporation or location anytime in the three decades since the law
9
Computational difficulties are a likely explanation for why the earliest papers in this literature failed to use fixed
effects.
For example, Bertrand and Mullainathan (2003, p. 1057) note that they rely on an average effects estimation
because the inclusion of so many fixed effects is computationally infeasible. We overcome this difficulty of
estimating a model with multiple, high-dimensional fixed effects using the iterative procedures described in
Guimarães and Portugal (2010) and Gormley and Matsa (2014).
As discussed later, we find that properly controlling
for fixed effects can be quite important for inferences.
11
. was passed would be assigned to an incorrect state.10 To mitigate this concern, we obtain information
about firms’ states of incorporation and location from SEC Analytics, which contains historical
information back to 1994. For observations prior to 1994, we use the earliest incorporation and location
information available for each firm. In cases where information is missing from SEC Analytics, such as
for firms that stopped filling prior to 1994, we use the legacy version of Compustat to obtain this
information. Because the legacy version of Compustat has not been updated since 2006, its information
on states of incorporation and location are more likely to be historically accurate than the most recent
version of Compustat.11
Firms in states adopting BC laws appear similar to firms in other states.
Table 1 reports firms’
average characteristics (and standard errors) in the three years before the laws were adopted; statistics in
Column (1) correspond to firms incorporated in a state adopting a BC law, and statistics in Column (2)
correspond to firms incorporated in states not adopting a BC law. The p-value t-tests for statistical
differences between the two samples are reported in Column (3). Firms are similar in terms of their
acquisitions, return on assets (ROA), cash/assets, and growth.
We also find no statistically significant
differences in their average risk, as measured by either stock volatility or the volatility of ROA. In
unreported estimates, we also find no difference in firms’ average leverage or modified Altman-z score.
The only significant difference we find is that firms incorporated in states adopting a BC law tended to be
larger than firms incorporated elsewhere (p-value = 0.064).
10
This concern is greater today than for studies that used earlier versions of Compustat. For example, Bertrand and
Mullainathan (2003) spot checked 200 firms in the 1995 version of Compustat and found only 3 firms that had
changed their state of incorporation between 1985 (when the first BC law was passed) and 1995.
In fact, none of
these three firms had been misclassified because the changes had occurred prior to the BC laws’ adoption. This
measurement error has increased over time, however, as researchers continue to use increasingly outdated
information on firms’ states of incorporation and location. A notable exception is Rauh (2006), who collected
historical information on firms’ states of incorporation.
11
It turns out that our choice of data here does not have a significant impact on our subsequent estimates.
Our
findings remain the same if, similar to other researchers, we instead ignore the measurement concern and just use the
most recent version of Compustat to obtain firms’ locations and states of incorporation. The lack of a significant
change likely reflects that only a small fraction of firms are being misclassified because of past changes in firms’
locations. Relative to the most recent version of Compustat, using SEC Analytics and Compustat Legacy changes
the state of incorporation for about 5% of observations and changes treatment status for 1.9% of observations.
12
.
2. How takeover threats affect stock and cash flow volatilities, cash holdings, and acquisitions
Does managers’ underlying preference to play it safe affect corporate decisions? In the absence of
strong external shareholder governance, is some managerial effort directed toward value-destroying
activities designed to reduce firms’ risk of distress? In this section, we investigate these questions by
examining how various measures of firms’ risk-taking change when external shareholder governance is
weakened, as captured by the passage of a BC law.
2.1. Stock volatility, cash flow volatility, and cash holdings
To investigate whether BC laws are associated with firm risk, we analyze the laws’ impact on
firm’s stock volatility, cash flow volatility, and cash holdings. A firm’s stock volatility provides a
measure of the firm’s riskiness and captures any corporate choices made to reduce the firm’s risk.
We
calculate firms’ stock volatility from CRSP using the square root of firms’ sum squared daily returns over
the year. We calculate the volatility of firms’ operating cash flow using the standard deviation of firms’
quarterly ROA. Detailed definitions of our variables can be found in Appendix Table A.2, and estimates
of the laws’ effects on stock and cash flow volatilities are reported in Table 2.
We find that firms’ stock volatility decreases after a BC law is adopted.
As reported in Column
(1) of Table 2, stock volatility declines by about 2.3 percentage points, on average, for firms affected by a
BC law relative to firms located in the same state and firms operating in the same industry that are
unaffected by the change. This drop in stock volatility corresponds to about 5% of the sample mean and
7.5% of the sample standard deviation. Cash flow volatility may also decrease: the point estimate,
reported in Column (2), indicates a decrease but is estimated imprecisely and not statistically significant
at conventional confidence levels.12
We also analyze firms’ holdings of cash.
A manager who wishes to reduce the firms’ risk of
distress might accumulate a greater cash buffer so as to reduce the likelihood of becoming distressed in
12
The decline in stock volatility is not due to a reduction in leverage. We find no evidence that passage of a BC law
is associated with a significant drop in firms’ market leverage (coefficient = –0.001, standard error = 0.003). The
small, insignificant decline may reflect a downward rigidity in leverage, as found in Heider and Ljungqvist (2013).
13
.
the future. Consistent with this, we find that firms increase their cash holdings after a BC law is adopted.
On average, firms’ total cash holdings increase by about 12.3 log points, or 13 percentage points [Column
(3)]. The increase is statistically significant at the one percent confidence level. Firms’ cash balances
increase not only in absolute terms but also relative to their size, as firms’ ratio of cash to assets also
increases.
Relative to the sample mean (reported in Table 1), the ratio of cash to assets increases by about
10 percent [Column (4)].
2.2. Acquisitions
While the decline in stock volatility and increase in cash holdings are suggestive of managers
playing it safe and reducing their firms’ risk when the threat of a takeover is reduced, the evidence could
also be consistent with managers exerting less effort. For example, if managers are avoiding taking on
risky R&D expenditures because these investments would entail costly effort, we might observe a
decrease in firms’ risk and an increase in cash holdings.
To differentiate between costly effort and managerial risk aversion as potential explanations for
the observed decline in risk, we examine firms’ acquisition activity.
We focus on acquisitions because
they are a way to reduce the firms’ risk that requires substantial managerial effort. There is a long
tradition, dating back to Amihud and Lev (1981), if not before, of viewing diversifying mergers in this
way. More recently, Gormley and Matsa (2011) find that when faced with an increase in left-tail risk,
managers aggressively try to reduce risk through diversifying acquisitions and acquisitions of “cash
cows” (firms with significant cash flow).
Because initiating and completing an acquisition requires
significant managerial time and effort, one could safely conclude that an observed increase does not stem
from managers’ reluctance to exert effort. Our estimates for acquisitions are found in Table 3.
We find that firm’s acquisition activity increases after the takeover threat is reduced. After a state
adopts a BC law, firms incorporated in that state are 1.1 percentage points more likely to undertake an
acquisition than before the law, relative to other firms operating in the same industry and firms operating
in the same state [Table 3, Column (1)].
This increase is economically large, averaging about 15 percent
14
. of the pre-law level, and is statistically significant at the 1 percent level. The increase in the number of
acquisitions is even larger: firms undertake one-third more acquisitions (0.031 more acquisitions per year
relative to the baseline level of 0.094) when the firm is protected from takeovers by a BC law. The
observed change in total deal value normalized by lagged market capitalization is also positive, but not
statistically significant. Because many acquisitions reported by SDC do not include the value of the target
firm, the number of observations in the deal value estimation is significantly lower and the estimates are
less reliable.
For this reason, our preferred specifications examine the likelihood and number of
acquisitions. In later findings, however, we do find the change in deal value is statistically significant in
subsamples where we expect the results to be greatest.
The timing of the increase in acquisitions coincides with the adoption of the BC laws. Figure 2
plots point estimates from a modified version of Equation (1), where we allow the effect of BC to vary by
year in the years before and after a BC law is passed.
There is no indication of an increase in acquisitions
before the BC laws take effect, but afterwards, firms incorporated in the state tend to increase their
acquisitions relative to firms operating in the same industry and firms operating in the same state but that
are incorporated elsewhere. The precise timing of this change suggests that the additional acquisitions are
in fact caused by the reduced takeover threat.
Many of the additional acquisitions are diversifying in nature. For target firm, SDC lists a
primary four-digit SIC industry classification and up to nine other four-digit SIC codes that represent
“any small side lines the company is involved in” (Thomson Financial 1999).
We define an acquisition as
diversifying when the acquirer’s primary SIC code does not coincide with any SIC code of the target firm.
Even when SIC codes match, an acquisition typically diversifies away some idiosyncratic risk. The effect
of BC laws on diversifying acquisitions, which is reported in column (4) of Table 3, is large and
statistically significant. After a BC law is adopted, firms incorporated in that state undertake 0.02 more
diversifying acquisitions annually (p < 0.01).
This increase represents a jump of about 33 percent relative
to the average number of diversifying acquisitions before the law was adopted. Compared to the
coefficient for the total number of acquisitions [Column (2)], we can see that almost two-thirds of the
15
. additional acquisitions are outside the acquirer’s primary industry. This increase in diversifying
acquisitions is consistent with the acquisitions being aimed at reducing firms’ risk and likely contribute to
the drop in firms’ stock volatility documented above.
To shed some light on how the BC laws affect the types of firms being acquired, we examine the
subsample of acquisitions for which the target firm’s financial data are available in Compustat.13 We
examine characteristics of the target firms based on their most recent financial data available in
Compustat before the acquisition announcement using the following regression:
yijlst β 2 BCst + α j + θl + δ t + υijlst ,
=
(2)
where y is an ex ante characteristic of target firm i, for an acquisition done by a firm located in industry j,
operating in state l, incorporated in state s, and announced in year t. We examine the following target
characteristics as dependent variables: log total assets, three-year compounded annual growth rate for
assets, the ratio of cash flow to assets, and the ratio of the total payout to assets.14 BC is defined as in
Equation (1). We include industry, state of location, and year fixed effects, and we adjust the standard
errors for clustering at the state of incorporation level.
The estimates are reported in Table 4.
Following adoption of a BC law, firms are more likely to acquire cash cows—large, high cash
flow, high payout firms. As reported in Table 4, the acquired firms are larger and have greater historical
growth rates. Targets acquired by firms incorporated in a BC law state are more than 40 percent larger, on
average, than targets acquired by firms incorporated in other states [Column (1)].
Their growth rate in the
five years before being acquired is 17.1 percentage points greater, on average, than for targets acquired by
unaffected firms [Column (2)]. Affected firms also tend to acquire targets that generate and pay out
13
We match the firms in SDC Platinum to Compustat using their CUSIPs. Unfortunately, historical CUSIPs are not
available in Compustat, so we determine a firm’s historical CUSIP by matching observations to CRSP using the
CRSP/Compustat Merged Database, and then using the historical CUSIP reported by CRSP.
When the historical
CUSIP is missing, we use the CUSIP recorded in Compustat’s header file.
14
Except for the regression of log total assets, the regressions are estimated by weighted least squares, using the
target firms’ total assets as weights. Given the magnitude of the size differences between deals, weighting gives the
estimates a more meaningful interpretation: the estimated coefficients represent the effect of a BC law on
characteristics associated with the average dollar of transaction value (rather than the average deal). For example,
the regression of the ratio of cash flows to assets examines whether the ratio of the total cash flows across all
acquired targets to the total assets acquired increases after liability risk increases.
16
.
greater cash flow per dollar of total assets. Targets acquired by affected firms average 11.3 percentage
points greater ratios of operating cash flow to assets [Column (3)], and 1.47 percentage points greater
ratios of total payouts to assets [Column (4)]. These findings suggest that firms may be seeking to acquire
so-called cash cows after the threat of a takeover decreases. These results may also explain some or all of
the increase in cash holdings among firms after a BC law is passed.
The acquisitions are largely funded with equity, and investors appear to perceive the
announcements of these mergers as bad news for the firms’ shareholders.
Of the acquisitions analyzed in
Table 4, the average abnormal return over a three-day window [−1, +1] for acquisitions by firms
incorporated in a state that has passed a BC law is −1.26% (standard error is 0.23).15 And, the average
share of financing using stock is 57.72 percent (standard error is 1.32), which is about 30 percentage
points higher than that of acquisitions done by firm not incorporated in BC states.
2.3. Why our findings differ
The observed increase in acquisitions stands in contrast to some prior research on BC laws and
their impact on firms. Prior research has failed to detect any increase in acquisitions, and this has typically
led researchers to conclude, similar to that of Bertrand and Mullainathan (2003), that empire building
motives are not a primary driver of managerial preferences.16 For example, Giroud and Mueller (2010)
explicitly test for an increase in the likelihood of undertaking an acquisition and find none.
The question
thus arises: why do we detect such a large increase in acquisitions whereas prior papers do not?
To determine why our findings differ from that of the prior literature, we first estimate the
standard AvgE specification used in the prior literature, which is given by
yijlst φ1 BCst + φ2 state-yearlt + φ3 industry -yearjt + f i + δ t + ΓXijlst + uijlst ,
=
(3)
where y is a dependent variable, BC is defined as before, state-year is the average y for firms in state l in
15
To estimate abnormal returns, we use standard event study methods (see MacKinlay 1997) and compute market
model abnormal returns using CRSP equally weighted index returns. The parameters for the market model are
estimated over the [−300, −46] day interval.
16
In many regards, our findings confirm the relative importance empire building motives. While we cannot rule out
that some of the additional acquisitions are driven by empire building, our later evidence suggests that the increase
in acquisitions is more consistent with playing it safe motives than empire building motives.
17
.
year t, and industry-year is the average y for firms in industry j in year t, and Xijlst is a vector of timevarying controls that includes firm size (measured using the natural log of assets), size-squared, firm age
(measured using the number of years that a firm has been in Compustat), and the Herfindahl-Hirschman
index (HHI) of sales in the firm’s three-digit SIC industry. The use of state-year and industry-year to
control for unobserved heterogeneity, rather than state-year and industry-year fixed effects, is what makes
this an Average Effects (AvgE) estimator. We also restrict our sample to end in 1995 so as to better match
prior papers. Our estimate of Equation (3) is reported in Column (1) of Table 5.
Using Equation (3), we do not detect a significant increase in acquisition activity.
The estimated
coefficient is 0.0038 and not statistically significant at conventional levels [Table 5, Column (1)]. This
non-result is robust to using non-historical firm locations, as done in much of the literature. Our estimate
is also of similar magnitude and of similar statistical significance as prior research.
For example, Giroud
and Mueller (2010) report an estimate of 0.003 [see Table 9, Panel A, Column (5) of their paper].
Our main specification [Table 3, Column (1)] differs from the standard specification [Table 5,
Column (1)] in only four ways, so our finding of an increase in acquisitions must be attributable to at least
one of these four differences. The four differences are: (1) the use of 4-digit industry controls rather than
3-digit SIC controls; (2) the use of the longer sample period that goes to 2000 rather than 1995; (3) the
exclusion of endogenous (i.e., bad controls), like firm size, that could also be affected by passage of the
BC law; and (4) the use of fixed effects to control for unobserved heterogeneity instead of an average
effects estimation. In Columns (2)-(5) of Table 5, we implement each of these changes one at time to
determine why we detect an increase in acquisitions.
Our ability to detect the increase in acquisitions is driven by eliminating the estimation biases
introduced by the AvgE specification and the bad controls.
Switching to 4-digit SIC controls (when
calculating the industry-year control) does not significantly change our estimate [Table 5, Column (2)].
But once we properly control for the industry-year and state-year fixed effects (rather than using AvgE
controls), we detect a large and statistically significant increase in the likelihood of undertaking an
acquisition [Table 5, Column (3)]. The change suggests that the measurement bias introduced by the
18
. AvgE estimator is a reason why previous attempts to detect an increase in acquisitions were unsuccessful.
The magnitude and statistical significance of the estimate further increases when we drop the bad controls
[Column (4)] suggesting that their inclusion was also introducing a bias in prior estimates. Finally,
extending the sample out to the year 2000 [Column (5)] so as to ensure we have at least 10 years of postlaw data for each firm affected by a change in law, we obtain our original estimates. Comparing Columns
(4) and (5), demonstrates that our longer sample period has only a small effect on the estimate.
Overall, our findings in Table 5 highlight the importance of researchers avoiding AvgE
estimation, as discussed in Gormley and Matsa (2014), and the inclusion of endogenous controls, as
discussed in Angrist and Pischke (2009). In our setting, we find that the bias introduced by each of these
controls has distorted researchers’ conclusions.
3.
Interpretation and heterogeneity in responses
“Nobody likes to fail but failure is an essential part of life and learning.
If your uniform isn’t dirty, you haven’t been in the game.”
— Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke, June 2, 2013
The increase in acquisitions after BC laws are adopted indicates that motivating managerial effort
is not the only challenge that shareholders face. After shareholder governance weakens, at least some
managers appear to be quite active. This increased activity runs counter to the typical presumption that,
absent strong governance, managers will exert too little effort.
Our finding suggests that the literature’s
laser focus on governance mechanisms related to managerial effort overlook additional aspects of
managerial preferences that are important for corporate outcomes and shareholder value. But what are the
managerial preferences that motivate the increased activity?
One possibility is that managers are playing it safe. Because distress can be personally costly for
managers, managers have an incentive to reduce the likelihood of distress even if doing so is not in
19
.
shareholders’ interest (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Amihud and Lev, 1981; Holmström, 1999).17
Negative corporate outcomes often adversely affect managers’ career prospects, even if poor corporate
performance is caused by factors beyond their control (Gilson 1989; Jenter and Kanaan, forthcoming).
Consequently, managers may prioritize the value of their own human capital and the firm’s long-run
survival above shareholder value and take actions that will reduce the risk of future distress.
Combined, the high share of diversifying acquisitions, the increase in cash holdings, and the
decline in stock volatility are suggestive that these acquisitions are driven by a desire by managers to
reduce risk. The shift in the type of acquisitions towards cash cows and the use of equity to fund these
deals is also consistent with managers using these diversifying acquisitions to reduce risk. However, it is
also possible that some of the observed increase in acquisitions is driven by other type of agency
conflicts. For example, with the threat of a takeover reduced, managers might also use their firms’ free
cash flow to seek additional private benefits, such as through empire building (Jensen, 1986).
To better assess the relative importance of playing it safe and empire building motives, we
analyze heterogeneity in firms’ responses to BC laws.
If the underlying agency conflict is managers’
desire to play it safe, then we would expect the increase in acquisitions to be larger among firms at a
greater risk of distress. On the other hand, if the acquisitions reflect empire building motives, we would
expect them to be more prominent among firms with greater cash flow. We now test for such
heterogeneity.
3.1.
Specification for identifying heterogeneity in responses
To avoid endogeneity concerns, we modify our specification so that we can compare firms’
responses based on ex ante characteristics. For example, we will test for a differential response based on
firms’ leverage in the year prior to passage of the law, denoted as year T–1. However, specification (1) is
not amenable to such a test; because there are multiple events, there is no unique T–1 period for each firm
17
A number of other theoretical papers also find that managers’ exposure to risk can cause a misalignment between
managers and shareholders’ risk preferences.
For example, see Smith and Stulz (1985), Lambert (1986), Hirshleifer
and Suh (1992), Hugonnier and Morellec (2007), and Acharya and Bisin (2009).
20
. in the panel. This difficulty in testing for heterogenous responses occurs whenever researchers are
analyzing responses to multiple events that occur at different points in time.
To overcome this challenge, we use the matching difference-in-difference estimator proposed by
Gormley and Matsa (2011). For each year that a new BC law is adopted, we identify firms incorporated in
states that passed a BC law in that year, and we match them to firms not yet affected by passage of a BC
law. We analyze firm-year observations in the ten years before and the ten years after the law’s adoption.
Firms are not required to be in the sample for the full twenty years around the event, and firms are
allowed to be chosen as matches for multiple events (i.e., we are matching with replacement).
We then
estimate a separate difference-in-difference for each BC law adoption year and report an average of the
treatment effects across all of these events. By estimating the treatment effect separately for each event,
we are able to identify the T–1 characteristics of each firm and test for heterogeneity in responses based
on these T–1 characteristics. In practice, a separate estimation for each event is not necessary; instead, one
can pool the data across events (i.e., across all new BC laws) and estimate the average treatment effect
across these separate events using the following firm-panel linear regression:
yeijlst β 3 BCst + f ei + ωelt + λejt + ηeijlst ,
=
(4)
where y is the outcome of interest for firm i, in event e, industry j, located in state l, incorporated in state
s, in year t.
BC is the same as before, but we now include firm-event fixed effects, f ei , state-year-event
fixed effects, ωelt , and industry-year-event fixed effects, λejt , to ensure that we separately estimate the
impact of firm, state-year, and industry-year unobserved heterogeneities for each BC event. We allow the
fixed effects to vary by event, because this approach is more conservative than including simple fixed
effects. To account for potential covariance among firm outcomes within the same state of incorporation
(including covariance from multiple draws of the same comparison firm), we again adjust the standard
errors for clustering by state of incorporation.
Switching to the matching difference-in-difference estimator does not affect our earlier findings.
This is shown in Table 5, Column (6).
Estimating Equation (4), we again find a large increase in firms’
21
. likelihood of doing an acquisition after passage of a BC law in their state of incorporation. While the
magnitude, a 0.0084 percentage point increase, is slightly smaller than our earlier estimate of 0.011
[Table 5, Column (6)], the small difference in estimates from Equations (1) and (4) is driven by the
different sampling periods of the two estimators. In our earlier estimation, firms that were affected by
passage of a BC law prior to 1991 had more than 10 years of post-event data while firms affected by later
events might have more than 10 years of pre-event data; in the matching estimation, each firm will have
at most 10 years of pre- and post-event data.
To test for heterogeneity in firms’ responses, we estimate Equation (4) separately for various
subsamples of firms, where the subsamples are constructed using characteristics of firms in the year prior
to the BC law’s adoption. The approach allows us to examine heterogeneity in the effect of BC laws, even
when the subsampling variable is itself affected by the laws.
3.2.
Evidence on relative importance of playing it safe versus empire building motives
To assess the importance of playing it safe versus empire building motives for the observed
increase in acquisitions, we look at differential responses based on firms’ ex-ante leverage and cash
flows. If the acquisitions are driven by empire building motives, we would expect them to be more
prominent among firms with greater cash flows and lower leverage. Without easy access to cash to fund
the acquisitions, it is more difficult for a manager to extract private benefits through empire-building.
Increased leverage can also inhibit empire building by reducing the cash flow available to fund such
growth (e.g., Jensen, 1986).
If playing it safe motivates the acquisitions, however, they are instead likely
to be more prominent among firms with less cash flow and higher leverage because managers’ motive to
reduce their firms’ risk will be greater when the firm has a greater risk of distress.
Consistent with a playing it safe motive, we find that the increase in acquisitions is concentrated
among firms with greater with leverage in the year prior to a BC law’s adoption. These estimates are
reported in Table 6. Firms with an above median leverage in year T–1 that are incorporated in a state that
passes a BC law are 1.47 percentage points more likely to undertake an acquisition in a given year after
22
.
passage of the law relative to before passage of the law and relative to above-median leverage firms not
incorporated in a state that passes a BC law [Panel B, Column (1)]. This represents about a 20 percent
increase in the likelihood of doing an acquisition. We find no increase in acquisitions among below
median leverage firms; the point estimate is an order of magnitude smaller and not statistically significant
[Panel A, Column (1)]. Our findings are similar when we instead look at the number of acquisitions
[Column (2)], deal value [Column (3)], and the number of diversifying acquisitions [Column (4)].
The findings are similar if we instead proxy for firms’ ex ante risk of distress using their modified
Altman z-score in the year prior to passage of the law; these estimates are reported in Table 7.18 Firms
with a below-median Altman z-score in year T–1 that are incorporated in a state that passes a BC law
undertake 0.015 more diversifying acquisitions in a given year after passage of the law relative to before
passage of the law and relative to below-median Altman z-score firms not incorporated in a state that
passes a BC law [Panel A, Column (4)].
This represents about a 22 percent increase in the number of
diversifying acquisitions. Our findings are similar when we instead look at the likelihood of undertaking
an acquisition [Column (1)], the total number of acquisitions [Column (2)], or the deal value [Column
(3)].
In further support of a playing it safe explanation, we also find that the increase in acquisitions is
concentrated among firms with lower cash flow. These estimates are reported in Table 8.
Firms with a
below median cash-flow-to-asset ratio undertake, on average, 0.013 more diversifying acquisitions a year
after passage of a BC law relative to other firms with below median cash flow located in the same state
and firms located in the same industry but that are incorporated in a state that does not pass a BC law
[Panel A, Column (4)]. The magnitude represents about a 25 percent increase in diversifying acquisitions.
Contrary to an empire building explanation, we find no increase in diversifying acquisitions among firms
with above median cash flows [Panel B, Column (4)]. The findings are similar when we look at the
indicator for doing an acquisition [Column (1)], the total number of acquisitions [Column (2)], and total
18
Following MacKie-Mason (1990), we calculate a modified-Altman z-score as 3.3*(EBIT/assets)+1.0*(sales/
assets) +1.4*(retained earnings/assets)+1.2*(working capital/assets).
23
.
deal value [Column (3)].
The findings are also similar if we instead use an indicator for paying dividends as an alternative
proxy for firms’ level of cash flows. The increase in acquisitions occurs among the sample of firms that
do not pay dividends [Table 9]. Firms with zero dividends in year T–1 are one percentage point more
likely to undertake an acquisition, and they undertake 0.019 more diversifying acquisitions in a given year
after passage of the law relative to before passage of the law [Panel A, Columns (1) and (4)]. This
represents about a 15 percent increase in the likelihood of undertaking an acquisition and a 28 percent
increase in the number of diversifying acquisitions.
Our findings are similar when we look at the total
number of acquisitions [Column (2)] or the deal value [Column (3)]. These findings are consistent with
the increase in acquisitions occurring among firms with a greater risk of distress rather than among firms
where agency conflicts associated free cash flows are more likely prevalent.
Overall, the observed heterogeneity in responses suggests that playing it safe motives are driving
the observed increase in acquisitions. Managers, particular those at firms at greater risk of distress, appear
to actively reduce their firms’ risks of distress when governance is weakened, as captured by a reduced
threat of takeover.
These findings support theoretical models and calibrations that suggest agency
conflicts arising from managers’ exposure to risk can significantly affect firms’ investment and financing
choices (Parrino, Poteshman, and Weisbach, 2005).
4. Conclusion
Shareholders face many obstacles in designing managers’ incentives so as to maximize
shareholder value. Managers may shirk or seek out private benefits at shareholders’ expense.
Managers
may also play it safe by taking value-destroying actions that reduce their firms’ risk of distress or failure,
which could have large, negative personal costs for managers.
Understanding the relevance of these various agency conflicts and how the conflicts vary across
firms and over time is crucial for designing incentive structures that mitigate their impact on shareholder
value. For instance, suppose shareholders believe the manager is failing to make the necessary
24
. investments in R&D and other risky investments required to create long-term value. If the failure to make
these risky investments is caused by the managers’ unwillingness to exert costly effort, then shareholders
might wish to increase the managers’ ownership stake to better align her interests. On the other hand, if
the manager is forgoing these investments because she is risk-averse and worries about the potential
impact of failure on her income and wealth, then increasing the managers’ ownership stake in the firm
may only deepen the agency conflict. In this case, increasing the convexity of the manager’s payoff
structure would be more appropriate (e.g., Guay, 1999).
Understanding the source of the conflict also has
implications for a firm’s optimal leverage and other corporate policies.
Whereas the existing literature primarily focuses on agency conflicts arising from costly effort
and the extraction of private benefits, we find evidence that playing it safe motives may be equally
important. When firms’ shareholder governance is weakened by a law that reduces the threat of a hostile
takeover, we find that managers actively reduce their firms’ risk. On average, firms undertake about a
third more diversifying acquisitions after a BC law is adopted relative to firms operating in the same
industry and firms operating in the state.
The increase coincides with the timing of when each law is
passed. These acquisitions are largely funded with equity and associated with negative average
announcement returns. The types of acquisitions also changes; firms are more likely to acquire “cash
cows”—large, high cash flow, high payout firms—which can bolster a firms’ cash holdings and reduce
their risk of distress.
Consistent with this, we also find a decline in firms’ stock volatility and an increase
in their cash holdings. The observed increase in acquisitions is concentrated among firms at a greater risk
of distress, firms with higher leverage and less cash flow.
Our evidence highlights a visible manifestation of managers playing it safe after shareholder
governance is weakened. Even if such behavior is pervasive, it is typical difficult to observe.
A manager
faced with investment choices of varying risks, for example, might systematically choose investments of
both lower risk and lower NPV, and because of information asymmetries, shareholders may have a hard
time detecting such behavior. Similarly, managers may hoard cash under the ruse of “keeping the powder
dry” for future investments, when, in reality, the manager is more concerned about avoiding distress that
25
. is personally costly. Such actions could have important implications for shareholder value, and more
broadly, aggregate economic growth and competitive interactions between firms. Our evidence that this
agency conflict is salient for many firms highlights the importance to shareholders of designing
governance and compensation contracts to motivate managers to take the necessary risks.
References
Acharya, V. V., Y.
Amihud, and L. Litov. 2011.
Creditor Rights and Corporate Risk-Taking. Journal of
Financial Economics 102(1): 150-166.
Acharya, V. V., and A.
Bisin. 2009. Managerial Hedging, Equity Ownership, and Firm Value.
RAND
Journal of Economics 40(1):47-78.
Amihud, Yakov, and Baruch Lev. 1981. Risk Reduction as a Managerial Motive for Conglomerate
Mergers.
Bell Journal of Economics 12(2):605-617.
Atanassov, Julian. 2013. Do Hostile Takeovers Stifle Innovation? Evidence from Antitakeover
Legislation and Corporate Patenting.
The Journal of Finance. 68(3):1097-1131.
Angrist, Joshua D., and Jorn-Steffen Pischke, 2009, Mostly Harmless Econometrics, Princeton University
Press: New Jersey.
Aulette, Ken. 1986.
Greed and Glory on Wall Street: The Fall of the House of Lehman. Random House:
New York.
Bertrand, Marianne, and Sendhil Mullainathan. 2003.
Enjoying the Quiet Life? Corporate Governance
and Managerial Preferences. Journal of Political Economy 111(5):1043-1075.
Casselman, Ben. 2013.
Risk-Averse Culture Infects U.S. Workers, Entrepreneurs. The Wall Street
Journal, June 2.
Cheng, Shijun, Venky Nagar, and Madhav V.
Rajan. 2004. Identifying Control Motives in Managerial
Ownership: Evidence from Antitakeover Legislation.
Review of Financial Studies, 18(2), 637-672.
Chevalier, Judith, and Glenn Ellison. 1999. Career Concerns of Mutual Fund Managers? The Quarterly
Journal of Economics.
114(2):389-432.
Comment, Robert, and G. William Schwert. 1995.
Poison or Placebo? Evidence on the Deterrence and
Wealth Effects of Modern Antitakeover Measures. Journal of Financial Economics 39:3-43.
Francis, Bill B., Iftekhar Hasan, Kose John, and Maya Waisman. 2010.
The Effect of State Antitakeover
Laws on Firm’s Bondholders. Journal of Financial Economics 96(1):127-154.
Gilson, Stuart C. 1989.
Management Turnover and Financial Distress. Journal of Financial Economics
25(2):241-262.
26
. Garvey, Gerald T., and Gordon Hanka. 1999. Capital Structure and Corporate Control: The Effect of
Antitakeover Statutes on Firm Leverage. The Journal of Finance.
54(2):519-546.
Giroud, Xavier, and Holger M. Mueller. 2010.
Does Corporate Governance Matter in Competitive
Industries. Journal of Financial Economics 95:312-331.
Gormley, Todd A. and David A.
Matsa. 2011. Growing Out of Trouble: Corporate Responses to Liability
Risk.
Review of Financial Studies, 24(8), pp. 2781-2821.
Gormley, Todd A. and David A.
Matsa. 2014. Common Errors: How to (and Not to) Control for
Unobserved Heterogeneity.
Review of Financial Studies, 27(2), 617-61.
Guay, W.R., 1999. The Sensitivity of CEO Wealth to Equity Risk: An Analysis of the Magnitude and
Determinants. Journal of Financial Economics 53, 43–71.
Guimarães, P., and P.
Portugal. 2010. A Simple Feasible Procedure to Fit Models with High-Dimensional
Fixed Effects.
Stata Journal 10:628–49.
Heider, Florian, and Alexander Ljungqvist. 2013. As Certain as Debt and Taxes: Estimating the Tax
Sensitivity of Leverage from Exogenous State Tax Changes.
Working paper. European Central Bank
and New York Univeristy.
Hirshleifer, David, and Yoon Suh. 1992.
Risk, Managerial Effort, and Project Choice. Journal of
Financial Intermediation 2(3):308-345.
Holmström, Bengt. 1999.
Managerial Incentive Problems: A Dynamic Perspective. Review of Economic
Studies 66(1):169-182.
Hugonnier, J., and E. Morellec.
2007. Corporate Control and Real Investment in Incomplete Markets.
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 31(5):1781-1800.
Jensen, Michael C. 1986.
Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers. The
American Economic Review 76(2):323-329.
Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling.
1976. Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency
Costs and Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3(4):305-360.
Jenter, D., and F.
Kanaan. Forthcoming. CEO Turnover and Relative Performance Evaluation.
The
Journal of Finance.
John, Kose, Yuanzhi Li, and Jiaren Pang. 2010. When Does Corporate Governance Matter? Evidence
from Anti-Takeover Legislation.
Working paper. New York Univeristy.
Karpoff, Jonathan M., and Paul H. Malatesta.
1989. The Wealth Effects of Second-Generation State
Takeover Legislation. Journal of Financial Economics 25:291-322.
Kempf, Alexander, Stefan Ruenzi, and Tanja Thiele.
2009. Employment Risk, Compensation Incentives,
and Managerial Risk Taking: Evidence from the Mutual Fund Industry. Journal of Financial
Economics 92:92-108.
Kim, E.
Han, and Yao Lu. 2011. CEO Ownership, External Governance, and Risk-Taking.
Journal of
27
. Financial Economics 102:272-292.
Lambert, R. A. 1986. Executive Effort and Selection of Risky Projects.
RAND Journal of Economics
17(1):77-88.
Low, Angie. 2009. Managerial Risk-Taking Behavior and Equity-Based Compensation.
Journal of
Financial Economics 92(3):470-490.
MacKie-Mason, Jeffrey K. 1990. Do Taxes Affect Corporate Financing Decisions? Journal of Finance
45(5):1471-1493.
MacKinlay, A.
Craig. 1997. Event Studies in Economics and Finance.
Journal of Economic Literature
35(1):13-39.
Mann, Henry G. 1965. Mergers and the Market for Corporate Control.
Journal of Political Economy
73(2): 110-120.
Panousi, Vasia, and Dimitris Papanikolaou. 2012. Investment, Idiosyncratic Risk, and Ownership.
Journal of Finance 67(3): 1113-1148.
Rauh, Joshua D.
2006. Own Company Stock in Defined Contribution Pension Plans: A Takeover
Defense? Journal of Financial Economics 81: 379-410.
Romano, Roberta. 1987.
The Political Economy of Takeover Statutes. Virginia Law Review 73: 111-199.
Scharfstein, David. 1988.
The Disciplinary Role of Takeovers. The Review of Economic Studies 55(2):
185-199.
Smith, Clifford W., and Rene M. Stulz.
1985. The Determinants of Firms' Hedging Policies. Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis 20(4):391-405.
Stein, Jeremy C.
1988. Takeover Threats and Managerial Myopia. Journal of Political Economy 96(1):
61-80.
Sundheim, Doug.
2013. Taking Smart Risks: How Sharp Leaders Win When Stakes Are High. McGraw
Hill: New York.
Thomson Financial.
1999. Mergers & Acquisitions Definitions. Securities Data Corporation.
Tufano, P.
1996. Who Manages Risk? An Empirical Examination of Risk Management Practices in the
Gold Mining Industry. Journal of Finance 51(4):1097-1137.
Tufano, P.
1998. Agency Costs of Corporate Risk Management. Financial Management 27(1): 67-77.
Yun, Hayong.
2009. The Choice of Corporate Liquidity and Corporate Governance. Review of Financial
Studies.
22(4): 1447-1475.
28
. 0.025
0.5
0.02
σ(ROA)
Stock volatility
0.6
0.4
0.015
0.3
0.01
0.2
0.005
1
4
7
10
13
4.6
4.2
3.8
3.4
3
1
4
7
10
13
16
GIM governance index
4
7
10
13
1
# of diversifying acquistions
5
Ln(Cash)
1
16
4
7
10
13
16
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
16
GIM governance index
Figure 1
Correlation between standard proxies of firm riskiness and the GIM governance index
This figure reports the average stock volatility, volatility of quarterly ROA, log cash holdings, and the number of
diversifying acquisitions against the GIM governance index for GIM index scores with at least 50 observations. The
regression line shown is weighted based on the underlying number of observations.
29
. 0.03
Indication for acquisition
0.02
0.01
0
â€4
â€3
â€2
â€1
0
1
2
3
4
â€0.01
Years relative to passage of BC law
â€0.02
Figure 2
Effect of BC laws on likelihood of doing an acquisition by year
This figure reports the point estimates from a firmâ€panel regression of an indicator for doing
an acquisition onto an indicator for business combination (BC) laws, firm fixed effects, stateâ€
ofâ€locationâ€byâ€year fixed effects, and 4â€digit SIC industryâ€byâ€year fixed effects. The
specification is the same as that reported in Table 3, Column (1), except that the effect of BC
laws is allowed to vary by year.
30
. Table 1
Exâ€ante firm characteristics
This table reports summary statistics for firm characteristics in the three years before a
new business combination (BC) law is passed. The mean and standard deviation (in
parentheses) for each variable are reported separately for two samples of firms. Column
(1) reports estimates for firms incorporated in states that pass a BC law. Column (2)
reports estimates for firms not incorporated in states that pass a BC law.
Column (3)
reports the p â€value from a tâ€test of the difference between treated and untreated firms,
where the standard errors are adjusted for clustering at the state of incorporation.
p â€value of
difference
(3)
Treated
Untreated
(1)
(2)
# of Acquisitions
0.094
(0.407)
0.088
(0.371)
0.560
Indicator for Acquisition
0.073
(0.260)
4.09
(2.51)
â€0.080
(2.88)
0.068
(0.252)
3.72
(2.48)
â€0.046
(2.44)
0.565
0.061
(0.115)
0.538
(0.308)
0.052
(0.995)
14.33
(32.23)
0.062
(0.115)
0.504
(0.309)
0.047
(0.626)
12.88
(33.59)
5,003
20,765
Ln(Assets)
ROA
Cash / Assets
Stock Volatility
σ(ROA)
3â€year asset CAGR (%)
Observations
31
0.064
0.343
0.876
0.337
0.764
0.482
. Table 2
Volatility, cash holdings, and the effect of BC law passage
This table reports coefficients from firmâ€panel regressions of stock volatility,
volatility of quarterly ROA, log cash holdings, and cash/assets on an indicator for
business combination laws, firm fixed effects, stateâ€ofâ€locationâ€byâ€year fixed
effects, and 4â€digit SIC industryâ€byâ€year fixed effects. The BC Law indicator
equals one if a firm is incorporated in a state that has passed a business
combination law. The sample includes firmâ€year observations from 1976 to
2000. Standard errors are clustered at the state of incorporation. ***significant
at the 1% level; **significant at the 5% level.
BC Law
Firm FE
Stateâ€year FE
Industryâ€year FE
N
R
2
σ(ROA)
Log(Cash)
Cash /
Assets
(1)
Dependent Variable =
Stock
Volatility
(2)
(3)
(4)
â€0.023**
(0.010)
â€0.073
(0.066)
0.123***
(0.038)
0.006**
(0.003)
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
107,978
131,313
138,503
141,542
0.66
0.44
0.82
0.55
32
. Table 3
Acquisitions and the effect of BC law passage
This table reports coefficients from firmâ€panel regressions of acquisition activity on an indicator
for business combination laws, firm fixed effects, stateâ€ofâ€locationâ€byâ€year fixed effects, and 4â€
digit SIC industryâ€byâ€year fixed effects. The BC Law indicator equals one if a firm is incorporated
in a state that has passed a business combination law. The dependent variables are an indicator
for doing an acquisition [Column (1)], the number of acquisitions [Column (2)], deal value of
acquisitions normalized by the acquirer's market capitalization in the previous year [Column (3)],
and the number of diversifying acquisitions [Column (4)]. The sample includes firmâ€year
observations from 1980 to 2000. Standard errors are clustered at the state of incorporation.
***significant at the 1% level; **significant at the 5% level; *significant at the 1% level.
BC Law
Firm FE
Stateâ€year FE
Industryâ€year FE
N
R2
# of
acquisitions
(1)
Dependent Variable =
Indicator for
acquisition
Deal value /
(Market cap of
acquirer in tâ€1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
0.0110***
(0.0033)
0.0305***
(0.0092)
0.1897
(0.1668)
0.0186***
(0.0072)
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
156,948
156,948
122,855
156,948
0.35
0.42
0.30
0.38
33
# diversifying
acquisitions
. Table 4
Effect of BC law on the characteristics of acquisitions
This table reports coefficients from firmâ€panel regressions of exâ€ante target firm
characteristics on an indicator for business combination laws, industry fixed
effects, state of location fixed effects, and year fixed effects. The BC Law
indicator equals one if a firm is incorporated in a state that has passed a
business combination law. The dependent variables are exâ€ante target
characteristics: log total assets, 3â€year compounded annual growth rate (CAGR)
for assets, the ratio of cash flow to asset, and the ratio of the total payout to
assets*100. The sample of acquisitions is the same as that used in Table 3, but
further restricted to mergers with nonâ€missing observations for log target
assets. Target characteristics are from Compustat, and estimates for growth
rate, cash flow, and total payout are weighted by target firm size. Standard
errors, clustered at the state of incorporation are reported in parentheses. *
significant at 10% level, ** significant at 5% level, *** significant at 1% level.
Dep. Variable =
Ln(Assets)
3â€year
Cash flow / Payout /
Assets CAGR
Assets
Assets * 100
(1)
BC Law
Râ€Squared
N
Fixed effects:
Industry
State
Year
(2)
(3)
(4)
0.407***
(0.098)
0.171***
(0.062)
0.118***
(0.022)
1.474***
(0.402)
0.38
1,816
0.58
1,355
0.45
1,615
0.50
1,696
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
34
. Table 5
Why our findings differ; a stepâ€byâ€step change from previous literature
This table reports coefficients from firmâ€panel regressions of acquisition activity on an indicator for business
combination laws. The BC Law indicator equals one if a firm is incorporated in a state that has passed a business
combination law. Column (1) reports estimates from the standard specification used in the existing literature,
which includes stateâ€year AvgE controls, 3â€digit industryâ€year AvgE controls, firm fixed effects, timeâ€varying
controls for firm size (as measured using log assets), sizeâ€squared, firm age (as measured using the number of years
a firm has been in Compustat), and the Herfindhalâ€Hirschman index of sales in the firm's threeâ€digit SIC industry, and
a sample window of 1976 to 1995 [see Equation (3)]. Column (2) repeats the estimation in Column (1), but instead
uses 4â€digit industryâ€year AvgE controls. Column (3) then replaces the industryâ€year and stateâ€year AvgE controls
of Column (2) with their corresponding fixed effects. Column (4) then drops the timeâ€varying controls of earlier
columns, and Column (5) extends the sample to 2000. The estimates in Column (5) represent our earlier estimation
of Equation (1), as reported in Column (1) of Table 3. Column (6) then switches the specification to the matching
differenceâ€inâ€difference estimation of Equation (4), which includes firmâ€event, stateâ€yearâ€event, and 4â€digit industryâ€
yearâ€event fixed effects. In all specifications, standard errors are clustered at the state of incorporation.
***significant at the 1% level; **significant at the 5% level; *significant at the 1% level.
Standard
specification
used in
literature
[Equation (3)]
Extend sample
to year 2000
Second,
First,
Our matched
Third, [Our final
switch to now properly
diffâ€inâ€diff
control drop "bad specification,
4â€digit SIC
for FE
controls" Equation (1)] [Equation (4)]
controls
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
BC Law
0.0038
(0.0037)
0.0041
(0.0037)
0.0076**
(0.0031)
0.0094***
(0.0032)
0.0110***
(0.0033)
0.0084***
(0.0032)
Râ€Squared
0.27
109,680
0.27
109,525
0.35
109,682
0.34
112,718
0.35
156,948
0.42
297,880
N
35
. Table 6
Leverage and the effect of BC laws on acquisitions
This table reports coefficients from firmâ€panel regressions of acquisition activity on an indicator
for business combination laws, firmâ€byâ€event fixed effects, stateâ€ofâ€locationâ€byâ€yearâ€byâ€event
fixed effects, and 4â€digit SIC industryâ€byâ€yearâ€byâ€event fixed effects. The BC Law indicator equals
one if a firm is incorporated in a state that has passed a business combination law. The data
include firmâ€yearâ€event observations in the 10 years before and 10 years after each passage of a
new BC law. The dependent variables are an indicator for doing an acquisition [Column (1)], the
number of acquisitions [Column (2)], deal value of acquisitions normalized by the acquirer's
market capitalization in the previous year [Column (3)], and the number of diversifying
acquisitions [Column (4)]. Panel A restricts the sample to firms with below median leverage in
the year prior to a BC law being passed, while Panel B restricts the sample to firms with above
median leverage. Standard errors are clustered at the state of incorporation. ***significant at
the 1% level; **significant at the 5% level; *significant at the 1% level.
Indicator for
Dependent Variable = acquisition
# of
acquisitions
(1)
(2)
# of
Deal value /
(Market cap of diversifying
acquirer in tâ€1) acquisitions
(3)
(4)
Panel A. Firms with BELOW median leverage at time Tâ€1
BC Law
0.0016
(0.0076)
0.0060
(0.0148)
â€0.4075
(0.4814)
0.0063
(0.0125)
N
147,177
147,177
121,322
147,177
0.50
0.64
0.19
0.65
R
2
Panel B. Firms with ABOVE median leverage at time Tâ€1
BC Law
N
R2
Firmâ€event FE
Stateâ€yearâ€event FE
Industryâ€yearâ€event FE
0.0147***
(0.0056)
0.0463***
(0.0096)
0.6768*
(0.3679)
0.0206**
(0.0093)
145,064
145,064
110,057
145,064
0.53
0.59
0.51
0.60
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
36
. Table 7
Bankruptcy risk and the effect of BC laws on acquisitions
This table reports coefficients from firmâ€panel regressions of acquisition activity on an indicator
for business combination laws, firmâ€byâ€event fixed effects, stateâ€ofâ€locationâ€byâ€yearâ€byâ€event
fixed effects, and 4â€digit SIC industryâ€byâ€yearâ€byâ€event fixed effects. The BC Law indicator
equals one if a firm is incorporated in a state that has passed a business combination law. The
data include firmâ€yearâ€event observations in the 10 years before and 10 years after each
passage of a new BC law. The dependent variables are an indicator for doing an acquisition
[Column (1)], the number of acquisitions [Column (2)], deal value of acquisitions normalized by
the acquirer's market capitalization in the previous year [Column (3)], and the number of
diversifying acquisitions [Column (4)]. Panel A restricts the sample to firms with below median
Altman zâ€scores in the year prior to a BC law being passed, while Panel B restricts the sample to
firms with above median zâ€scores. Standard errors are clustered at the state of incorporation.
***significant at the 1% level; **significant at the 5% level; *significant at the 1% level.
Indicator for
Dependent Variable = acquisition
# of
acquisitions
(1)
(2)
# of
Deal value /
(Market cap of diversifying
acquirer in tâ€1) acquisitions
(3)
(4)
Panel A. Firms with BELOW median zâ€score at time Tâ€1
BC Law
0.0094**
(0.0046)
0.0385***
(0.0080)
1.560**
(0.7862)
0.0149***
(0.0053)
N
R2
115,625
115,625
85,721
115,625
0.51
0.59
0.23
0.59
Panel B. Firms with ABOVE median zâ€score at time Tâ€1
BC Law
0.0025
(0.0093)
0.0034
(0.0138)
â€0.0297
(0.0859)
0.0051
(0.0125)
N
133,480
133,480
111,069
133,480
0.50
0.59
0.20
0.01
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
R
2
Firmâ€event FE
Stateâ€yearâ€event FE
Industryâ€yearâ€event FE
37
. Table 8
Cash flows and the effect of BC laws on acquisitions
This table reports coefficients from firmâ€panel regressions of acquisition activity on an indicator
for business combination laws, firmâ€byâ€event fixed effects, stateâ€ofâ€locationâ€byâ€yearâ€byâ€event
fixed effects, and 4â€digit SIC industryâ€byâ€yearâ€byâ€event fixed effects. The BC Law indicator equals
one if a firm is incorporated in a state that has passed a business combination law. The data
include firmâ€yearâ€event observations in the 10 years before and 10 years after each passage of a
new BC law. The dependent variables are an indicator for doing an acquisition [Column (1)], the
number of acquisitions [Column (2)], deal value of acquisitions normalized by the acquirer's
market capitalization in the previous year [Column (3)], and the number of diversifying
acquisitions [Column (4)]. Panel A restricts the sample to firms with below median cash
flows/assets in the year prior to a BC law being passed, while Panel B restricts the sample to firms
with above median cash flows/assets. Standard errors are clustered at the state of incorporation.
***significant at the 1% level; **significant at the 5% level; *significant at the 1% level.
# of
diversifying
acquisitions
Indicator for
acquisition
# of
acquisitions
(1)
Dependent Variable =
Deal value /
(Market cap of
acquirer in tâ€1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
Panel A. Firms with BELOW median cash flows/assets at time Tâ€1
BC Law
0.0071*
(0.0040)
0.0192**
(0.0077)
0.1125*
(0.0676)
0.0134***
(0.0049)
N
R2
109,867
109,867
82,728
109,867
0.50
0.59
0.98
0.59
Panel B. Firms with ABOVE median cash flows/assets at time Tâ€1
BC Law
0.0025
(0.0092)
0.0092
(0.0156)
â€0.2868
(0.5158)
â€0.0024
(0.0134)
N
R2
126,281
126,281
104,615
126,281
0.51
0.59
0.16
0.58
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
Firmâ€event FE
Stateâ€yearâ€event FE
Industryâ€yearâ€event FE
38
. Table 9
Dividends and the effect of BC laws on acquisitions
This table reports coefficients from firmâ€panel regressions of acquisition activity on an
indicator for business combination laws, firmâ€byâ€event fixed effects, stateâ€ofâ€locationâ€byâ€yearâ€
byâ€event fixed effects, and 4â€digit SIC industryâ€byâ€yearâ€byâ€event fixed effects. The BC Law
indicator equals one if a firm is incorporated in a state that has passed a business combination
law. The data include firmâ€yearâ€event observations in the 10 years before and 10 years after
each passage of a new BC law. The dependent variables are an indicator for doing an
acquisition [Column (1)], the number of acquisitions [Column (2)], deal value of acquisitions
normalized by the acquirer's market capitalization in the previous year [Column (3)], and the
number of diversifying acquisitions [Column (4)]. Panel A restricts the sample to firms with
zerio dividends in the year prior to a BC law being passed, while Panel B restricts the sample to
firms with positive dividends. Standard errors are clustered at the state of incorporation.
***significant at the 1% level; **significant at the 5% level; *significant at the 1% level.
Indicator for
Dependent Variable = acquisition
# of
acquisitions
(1)
# of
Deal value /
(Market cap of diversifying
acquirer in tâ€1) acquisitions
(2)
(3)
(4)
Panel A. Firms with ZERO dividends at time Tâ€1
BC Law
0.0102**
(0.0040)
0.0340***
(0.0082)
0.4474*
(0.2532)
0.0186***
(0.0051)
N
R2
172,702
172,702
131,656
172,702
0.46
0.53
0.63
0.52
Panel B. Firms with POSITIVE dividends at time Tâ€1
BC Law
â€0.0033
(0.0076)
â€0.0020
(0.0169)
â€0.1501
(0.5056)
â€0.0001
(0.0133)
N
R2
125,178
125,178
103,813
125,178
0.56
0.69
0.15
0.70
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
Firmâ€event FE
Stateâ€yearâ€event FE
Industryâ€yearâ€event FE
39
. Appendix Table A.1
Business combination laws passed by year and state
This table reports the states that passed a business combination
law along with the year in which the law was passed. This
information was obtained from Bertrand and Mullainathan (2003).
Arizona (1987)
Connecticut (1989)
Delaware (1988)
Georgia (1988)
Idaho (1988)
Illinois (1989)
Indiana (1986)
Kansas (1989)
Kentucky (1987)
Maine (1988)
Maryland (1989)
Massachusetts (1989)
Michigan (1989)
Minnesota (1987)
Missouri (1986)
Nebraska (1988)
Nevada (1991)
New Jersey (1986)
New York (1985)
Oklahoma (1991)
Ohio (1990)
Pennsylvania (1989)
Rhode Island (1990)
South Carolina (1988)
South Dakota (1990)
Tennessee (1988)
Virginia (1988)
Washington (1987)
Wisconsin (1987)
Wyoming (1989)
40
. Appendix Table A.2
Variable Definitions
Stock volatility
Calculated from CRSP using the square root of the sum of squared daily returns over the year.
To adjust for differences in the number of trading days, the raw sum is multiplied by 252 and
divided by the number of trading days.
σ(ROA)
Calculated from Compustat using the standard deviation of firms quarterly ROA for the year.
Quarterly ROA is calculated as niqt / atqtâ€1.
Ln(Cash)
Calculated from Compustat using ln(ch).
Cash/assets
Calculated from Compustat using ch/at.
Indicator for
acquisition
Calculated using SDC's Mergers and Acquisitions Database.
Indicator equal to one if the firm does an acquisition.
# of acquisitions
Calculated using SDC's Mergers and Acquisitions Database. Number of acquisitions a firm does.
Deal value / (Market
cap of acquirer in tâ€1)
Calculated using SDC's Mergers and Acquisitions Database. Total deal value of completed acquisitions in a year
divided by firms lagged market capitalization, where market capitalization is measured as csho × prcc_c
# of diversifying
acquisitions
Calculated using SDC's Mergers and Acquisitions Database. Number of acquisitions a firm does where its
primary SIC industry does not coincide with any SIC code of the target firm.
Cash flows/assets
(oiadp †accruals) / at, where accruals = (actt †acttâ€1) †(chet †chetâ€1) †(lctt †lcttâ€1) + (dlct †dlctâ€1) †dp
Debt/assets
Calculated from Compustat using (dltt + dlc)/at.
Altman zâ€score
Calculated from Compustat using (3.3 × oiadp + 0.999 × sale + 1.4 × re + 1.2 × wcap) / at
Dividend indicator
Calculated from Compustat using indicator that equals 1 if dvc > 0
41
.