Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners1
Ian R. Appel2, Todd A. Gormley3, and Donald B. Keim4
September 4, 2015
Abstract
Passive institutional investors are an increasingly important component of U.S.
stock ownership, and their influence on firm-level governance is widely debated.
To examine whether and by which mechanisms passive investors influence firms’
governance structures, we use an instrumental variable estimation and exploit
variation in ownership by passively managed mutual funds that results from
stocks being assigned to either the Russell 1000 or 2000 index.
Our findings
suggest that passive investors play a key role in influencing firms’ governance
choices; ownership by passively managed funds is associated with more
independent directors, the removal of takeover defenses, and more equal voting
rights. Passive investors appear to exert influence through their large voting blocs,
and consistent with the observed differences in governance having a positive
influence on firm value and reducing the need for activism by other investors, we
document a decline in activism by non-passive investors and improvements in
firms’ longer-term performance.
(JEL D22, G23, G30, G34, G35)
Keywords: governance, institutional ownership, passive funds
1
For helpful comments, we thank Bernard Black, Alon Brav, Alan Crane, Sevinc Cukurova, David
Denis, Ran Duchin, Alex Edmans, Vyacheslav Fos, Erik Gilje, Stuart Gillan, Vincent Glode, Robert
Jackson, Wei Jiang, Charles Jones, OÄŸuzhan Karakas, Borja Larrain, Doron Levit, Craig Lewis, Inessa
Liskovich, Michelle Lowry, Nadya Malenko, Pedro Matos, David Matsa, Sebastien Michenaud, David
Musto, Christian Opp, Ed Rice, Michael Roberts, Dick Roll, Luke Taylor, Paul Tetlock, Jeremy
Tobacman, James Weston, and seminar participants at Boston College (Carroll), Columbia Business
School, Florida Atlantic University, FTSE World Investment Forum, University of Pennsylvania
(Wharton), University of Washington (Foster), U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission, NBER
Summer Institute for Corporate Finance, Western Finance Association Meetings, ISB Summer Research
Conference, Drexel Conference on Corporate Governance, Ohio State University Corporate Finance
Conference, Society of Financial Studies Cavalcade, 9th International Finance UC Conference, and the
NYU/Penn Conference on Law and Finance.
We also thank Alon Brav for sharing his data on hedge fund
activism, Louis Yang for his research assistance, and the Rodney L. White Center for Financial Research
for financial support.
2
Carroll School of Management, Boston College, 140 Commonwealth Avenue Chestnut Hill,
MA, 02467. Phone: (617) 552-1459.
Fax: (617) 552-0431. E-mail: ian.appel@bc.edu
3
The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 3620 Locust Walk, Suite 2400, Philadelphia, PA,
19104. Phone: (215) 746-0496.
Fax: (215) 898-6200. E-mail: tgormley@wharton.upenn.edu
4
The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 3620 Locust Walk, Suite 2400, Philadelphia, PA,
19104. Phone: (215) 898-7685.
Fax: (215) 898-6200. E-mail: keim@wharton.upenn.edu
. “We’re going to hold your stock when you hit your quarterly
earnings target. And we’ll hold it when you don’t. We’re going to
hold your stock if we like you. And if we don’t.
We’re going to
hold your stock when everyone else is piling in. And when
everyone else is running for the exits. That is precisely why we
care so much about good governance.”
— F.
William McNabb III, Chairman and CEO of Vanguard
I. Introduction
While there is considerable evidence that institutional investors influence the governance
and policies of firms (e.g., Aghion, Van Reenen and Zingales (2013); Brav et al. (2008)), this
evidence primarily focuses on the role of activists that accumulate shares and make demands
upon managers or active fund managers that exit positions when managers perform poorly.
Yet,
such active investors represent only a subset of institutions. Many institutions are instead passive
in that they do not actively buy or sell shares to influence managerial decisions. The investment
objective of such institutions is to deliver the returns of a market index (e.g., S&P 500) or
investment style (e.g., large-cap value) with low turnover, diversified portfolios, and minimal
expenses.
As shown in Figure 1, passive investors have grown significantly in recent years; the
share of equity mutual fund assets held in passively managed funds tripled over the 1998-2014
period to 33.5%, and the share of total U.S. market capitalization held by passively managed
funds quadrupled to more than 8%. However, the growth of passive investors raises questions
about how effectively managers are being monitored.
Many worry that passive investors lack the
motives and resources to monitor their large, diverse portfolios, and that the increasing market
share of such “lazy investors” weakens firm-level governance and hurts performance.1 Others
counter that passive investing does not equate with passive ownership.2 In this paper, we
examine whether passive institutional investors influence firms’ governance structures, and
ultimately, performance.
There are reasons to suspect that the growth of passive investors weakens the governance
and performance of firms. First, such institutional investors may lack an incentive to monitor
managers. In particular, passive funds seek to deliver the performance of the benchmark, and
unlike actively managed funds, they have little motive to improve an individual stock’s
performance.
Second, passive investors may be less able to exert influence over managers. By
seeking to minimize deviations from the underlying index weights, passive institutions tend to
1
An example of this viewpoint was expressed in The Economist on Feb. 7, 2015.
As it stated, “A rising
chunk of the stock market sits in the hands of lazy investors. Index funds and exchange-traded funds
mimic the market’s movements, and typically take little interest in how firms are run; conventional
mutual funds and pension funds that oversee diversified portfolios dislike becoming deeply involved in
firms’ management.”
2
For example, the title of this paper, “Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners,” was the title for an article
written by Glenn Booraem, controller of Vanguard, in April 2013 highlighting the care Vanguard takes
when voting proxies. See https://personal.vanguard.com/us/insights/article/proxy-commentary-042013.
Similar views regarding the distinction between being a passive investor, but active owner, were espoused
by Rakhi Kumar, head of corporate governance at State Street Global Advisors in The Financial Times on
April 6, 2014 in an article titled, “Passive investment, active ownership,” and by David Booth, chairman
and co-founder of Dimensional Fund Advisors, in the New York Times on March 16, 2013 in an article
titled, “Challenging Management (but Not the Market)”.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 1
.
lack a traditional lever used by non-passive investors to influence managers—the ability to
accumulate or exit positions. Third, given their diversified holdings, passive investors may have
insufficient resources to research and monitor the corporate policies of each individual firm in
their portfolio.
And yet, there are reasons why the growth of passive investors may affect firms’
governance choices and performance. First, passive institutions may be motivated to monitor
managers and improve overall market performance because this increases the value of their
assets under management (Del Guercio and Hawkins (1999)). Moreover, because passive
institutions are less willing to divest their positions in poorly performing stocks, they may be
more motivated than other institutions to be engaged owners (Romano (1993), Carleton, Nelson,
and Weisbach (1998)).
Second, institutions that manage passive funds can use their sizable
ownership stakes and voting ability to wield influence. All institutional investors have a fiduciary
duty to vote their proxies in the best interest of shareholders, and managers may be more inclined
to consider the views of passive investors over more active investors, which tend to exhibit
higher turnover rates (Del Guercio and Hawkins (1999)). Finally, while passive institutions may
lack the resources necessary to monitor the detailed policy choices of every firm in their large,
diversified portfolios, they may be effective at engaging in widespread, but low-cost, monitoring
of firms’ compliance with what they consider to be best governance practices (e.g., Black (1992),
Black (1998)).
Identifying the impact of passive investors on firms’ corporate governance and
performance can be challenging.
Correlations between passive investors and governance choices
might not reflect a causal relation since ownership by passive investors might be correlated with
factors—such as firms’ investment opportunities or ownership by active investors—that directly
affect managerial decisions.
To overcome this challenge and to assess whether passive investors affect firms’
governance and performance, we exploit variation in ownership by passive investors that occurs
around the cutoff point used to construct two widely-used market benchmarks, the Russell 1000
and Russell 2000 indexes. The Russell 1000 comprises the largest 1,000 U.S. stocks, in terms of
market capitalization, and the Russell 2000 comprises the next largest 2,000 stocks.
Because
portfolio weights assigned to each stock within an index are value-weighted, a stock’s index
assignment has a significant impact on the extent of ownership by passive funds. For example,
the 750th through 1,000th largest stocks will be included in the Russell 1000 and be given small
portfolio weights because they represent the smallest firms in their index, while the 1,001st
through 1,250th largest stocks will be included in the Russell 2000 and be given weights that are
an order of magnitude larger because they represent the largest firms in their index. Therefore,
for each dollar invested in a passive fund using the Russell 1000 as a benchmark, very little of it
will be invested in stocks at the bottom of that index; while for each dollar invested in a passive
fund using the Russell 2000 as a benchmark, a large proportion of it will be invested in stocks at
the top of the index.
This benchmarking by passive funds leads to a sharp difference in ownership by passive
institutional investors for stocks at the top of the Russell 2000 relative to stocks at the bottom of
the Russell 1000 even though these stocks are otherwise similar in terms of their overall market
capitalization.
We find that the ownership of passively managed mutual funds is, on average,
about 66% higher for stocks at the top of the Russell 2000 index relative to stocks at the bottom
of the Russell 1000 index. The difference in passive ownership matches what one would predict
based on the amount of money estimated to be passively tracking the two indexes and
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 2
. corresponds with a significant shift in firms’ ownership structure. On average, the ownership
stakes of three of the biggest passive investors, Vanguard, State Street, and Barclays Bank
(which owned iShares during our sample), are a third higher among firms at the top of the
Russell 2000, and each of these three institutions’ likelihood of owning more than 5% of a firm’s
shares increases by two thirds on average, while their likelihood of being a top 5 shareholder is
higher, on average, by 15%. We find no corresponding difference in ownership of stocks around
the cutoff among actively managed mutual funds.
Exploiting this variation in ownership around the Russell 1000/2000 cutoff in an
instrumental variable (IV) estimation, we assess the effect of passive funds on firms’ governance
structures and performance. Specifically, we instrument for ownership by passive funds with an
indicator for being assigned to the Russell 2000 in a given year.
Our IV estimation relies on the
assumption that, after conditioning on stocks’ market capitalization, inclusion in the Russell
2000 index does not directly affect our outcomes of interest except through its impact on passive
ownership. This assumption seems reasonable in our setting in that it is unclear why index
inclusion would be directly related to governance and corporate performance after restricting the
sample to stocks near the Russell 1000/2000 cutoff and after controlling for the factor that
determines index inclusion—stocks’ end-of-May market capitalization.
The three broad governance outcomes we analyze reflect those highlighted in a recent
speech by the CEO of Vanguard (see McNabb (2014)) and the historical proxy-voting policies of
the largest passive institutional investors. While passive institutions do vary their voting strategy
across firms on governance issues (e.g., see Davis and Kim (2007)), three common themes of
their historical proxy voting policies were (1) to support greater board independence, (2) oppose
antitakeover provisions, and (3) oppose unequal voting rights, as occurs when firms maintain a
dual class share structure (e.g., see McNabb (2014) and the Appendix for more details on voting
guidelines of three prominent passive institutional investors).
We also analyze vote outcomes,
such as the average support for management and governance-related shareholder proposals,
which could be directly related to a potential mechanism by which passive investors may exert
influence—their ability to exercise “voice”.
Using our IV approach, we find that passive investors have a significant impact on each
of the three aspects of governance. First, an increase in ownership by passive funds is associated
with an increase in board independence. A one standard deviation increase in ownership by
passive funds is associated with about a 0.7 standard deviation increase in the share of directors
on a firm’s board that are independent.
Second, passive ownership is associated with the removal
of takeover defenses. A one standard deviation increase in ownership by passive funds is
associated with 3.5 percentage point increase in the likelihood of removing a poison pill and a
2.5 percentage point increase in the likelihood of reducing restrictions on shareholders’ ability to
call special meetings. These findings are economically large given that, on average, only 4% of
firms remove a poison pill and 0.6% of firms eliminate restrictions on special meetings each year
during our sample period.
We find less evidence that passive ownership is associated with
differences in other takeover defenses, including classified boards or supermajority voting
requirements. Finally, an increase in passive ownership is associated with firms being less likely
to have unequal voting rights, as captured by having a dual class share structure. A one standard
deviation increase in ownership by passive funds is associated with about a one standard
deviation decrease in likelihood of having a dual class share structure.
Our evidence suggests that a key mechanism by which passive investors exert their
influence is through the power of their large voting blocs (i.e., voice).
Passive ownership is
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 3
. associated with a decline in the share of votes in support of management proposals, suggesting
managers face a more contentious and attentive shareholder base, and an increase in support for
governance-related shareholder proposals. A one standard deviation increase in ownership by
passive funds is associated with about a 0.75 standard deviation decline in support for
management proposals and about a 0.5 standard deviation increase in support for governance
proposals. We find little evidence that these differences in support are driven by a change in the
either the number or type of proposals brought to a vote.
Because the size and concentration of passive investors’ ownership stakes may make it
easier for activist investors to rally support for their demands (Brav et al. (2008), Bradley et al.
(2010)), an alternative mechanism by which passive investors might influence governance
outcomes is by facilitating the activist efforts of other investors.
However, we find no evidence
of a positive association between ownership by passive funds and the likelihood of a firm
experiencing a hedge fund activism event or takeover event. Instead, we find evidence that a
larger ownership stake by passive funds is associated with a decline in hedge fund activism,
which is consistent with the engagement of passive investors reducing the need for activism by
other investors. However, these findings do not exclude the possibility that passive investors’
ownership stakes increase the threat of activism by others, and that this perceived threat
increases the power of passive investors’ voice.
For example, companies may be responsive to
the governance views of passive investors so as to lessen the likelihood that these investors later
lend support to an activist campaign initiated by others.
Consistent with the documented changes in governance having a positive influence on
firm value we find that, on average, an increase in passive ownership is associated with an
improvement in firms’ future performance. While we find no evidence of an association between
passive ownership and measures of performance in our main IV specification, we find evidence
that longer-term ownership by passive investors is associated with significant improvements in
firms’ return on assets (ROA) and Tobin’s Q. On average, a one standard deviation increase in
ownership by passive funds is associated with about a third of standard deviation increase in
ROA.
We find little evidence, however, that passive ownership is associated with differences in
the level or composition of managerial pay (a fourth issue that is prominently discussed by
passive investors during our sample period) or firms’ capital structure or investments. Overall,
the findings are consistent with passive investors improving firm value by insisting on basic
governance-related changes, as these changes appear to improve firm value but require a low
level of costly monitoring, while avoiding more costly and firm-specific interventions related to
managerial pay and firms’ investment or capital structure choices.
Our findings are robust to various specification choices. For example, varying the
number of stocks we investigate around the cutoff between the two indexes or varying the
functional form we use to control for firms’ end-of-May market cap, which is the key factor
determining stocks’ index assignment each year, does not affect our findings.
The findings are
also robust to adding various controls, including (1) firms’ float-adjusted market cap, which is a
proprietary measure used by Russell to determine a stock’s ranking within indexes, (2) firms’
industry, (3) firms’ past stock returns, and (4) whether firms recently switched indexes.
Moreover, the findings are robust to using alternative definitions of passive ownership as the key
explanatory variable, including the institution-level (13F) ownership stake of the three largest
passive institutions or institution-level measure of “quasi-index” ownership, as defined by
Bushee (2001). Finally, we find no effect of passive ownership in placebo tests that assume
differences in passive ownership at alternative market cap thresholds (i.e., instead of the Russell
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 4
. 1000/2000 cutoff).
Overall, our findings contribute to the broad literature that studies the effects of
institutional ownership of common stock. One strand of this literature analyzes institutional
investors’ impact on various aspects of corporate governance, including governance indices
(Aggarwal et al. (2011), Chung and Zhang (2011)), CEO pay sensitivity (Hartzell and Starks
(2003)), and shareholder proposals (Gillan and Starks (2000)), while another strand studies the
effects of institutional investors on corporate policies, including leverage (Michaely, Popadak,
and Vincent (2014)), dividends (Grinstein and Michaely (2005)) and R&D (Bushee (1998),
Aghion, Van Reenen, and Zingales (2013)). A number of recent papers also highlight the role of
specific types of institutional investors, such as activist hedge funds (Brav et al.
(2008); Klein
and Zur (2009)). We contribute to this literature by focusing on passive institutions—a less
studied, but increasingly important set of institutional investors. In this regard, our paper is
related to studies of several pension funds that follow passive investment strategies but
successfully engage in activism (e.g., Carleton, Nelson, and Weisbach (1998), Del Guercio and
Hawkins (1999)).
Some argue that activism by pension fund managers is at least partially
motivated by politics rather than wealth maximization (Romano (1993)). Given that such
pressures are largely confined to public pension funds, it is not clear that this success extends to
passive investors more generally. However, consistent with these case studies and contrary to
survey evidence that passive investors might lack the willingness and ability to monitor
managers (Useem et al.
(1993)), our evidence suggests that passive investors are not passive
owners. In particular, we find evidence that passive investors successfully influence firms’
governance choices and improve long-term, firm-level performance.
The results of this paper also provide new insights into the determinants of firms’
governance structures and how large shareholders influence managerial decisions. Typically,
institutional investors, such as blockholders, are thought to influence governance through a
combination of “voice” and “exit” (e.g., Edmans (2014) and Levit (2013)).
Voice refers to direct
intervention by shareholders through either formal (e.g., proxy voting) or informal (e.g., letters to
the board) channels (Harris and Raviv (2010); Levit and Malenko (2011); Maug (1998); Shleifer
and Vishny (1986)), while exit refers to the threat or actual selling of shares (Admati and
Pfleiderer (2009); Edmans (2009); Edmans and Manso (2011)). However, because passive funds
maintain portfolio weights that are often closely aligned with the weights in their chosen
benchmark, their ability to influence managers is primarily limited to voice, which is thought to
constrain their ability to influence corporate outcomes. Our paper finds otherwise.3
Finally, our work is related to recent papers that use the Russell 1000/2000 cutoff to
analyze the price effects of additions and deletions from a market index (Chang, Hong, and
Liskovich (2014)), the importance of institutional investors’ portfolio weights for monitoring
incentives (Fich, Harford, and Tran (2015)), and the association between institution-level (13F)
ownership and payouts, investment, CEO pay, management disclosure, acquisitions, and CEO
3
In this regard, our findings complement those of Iliev and Lowry (2015), who analyze the determinants
of mutual funds’ reliance on proxy advisory service companies like Institutional Shareholder Services
(ISS).
While not the focus of the paper, Section 4.3 of Iliev and Lowry presents evidence that index
funds are more likely to “actively vote” their shares (as measured by being less likely to follow ISS vote
recommendations on non-binding shareholder proposals). Choi, Fisch, and Kahan (2013) find similar
evidence that the voting decisions of Vanguard, and other large fund families, vary substantially from ISS
vote recommendations. Our findings demonstrate that the active monitoring of passive investors results
in actual differences in firms’ governance structures and performance.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 5
.
power (Boone and White (2014); Crane, Michenaud, and Weston (2014); Lu (2013); Mullins
(2014); Schmidt (2012)). In contrast to these papers, we use the Russell 1000/2000 cutoff and
fund-level data to isolate variation in ownership by passively managed mutual funds, and we
analyze the impact of such investors on governance outcomes they explicitly mention as being
important (e.g., independent directors, fewer takeover defenses, and equal voting rights), and the
mechanisms by which passive investors might influence such governance outcomes (e.g., proxy
voting, shareholder proposals, and facilitating activism by others).4
II. Sample, data sources, and descriptive statistics
In this paper, we merge stock-level data on mutual fund ownership and Russell equity
index membership with firm-level governance, proxy voting, accounting, and executive
compensation data. We now briefly describe each data source and our sample.
A.
Mutual fund holdings and Russell 1000/2000 index membership
We use the S12 mutual fund holdings data compiled by Thomson Reuters and available
from Wharton Research Data Services (WRDS) to compute mutual fund holdings in a stock as a
percent of its market capitalization. Since May 2004, all mutual funds holding stocks traded on
U.S. exchanges are required to report those holdings every quarter to the SEC using Forms NCSR and N-Q.
Reported securities include all NYSE/AMEX/NASDAQ, Toronto and Montreal
common stocks. Before May 2004, funds were required to report holdings only twice a year
using Form N-30D, but many voluntarily reported holdings in the other two quarters. To adjust
for any missing/unreported holdings between report dates prior to May 2004, we populate
missing holdings by assuming that the holdings from the earlier date stay constant and use
monthly data from CRSP (prices, adjustment factors) to compute imputed dollar values of these
holdings.5 We exclude observations where the total mutual fund holdings exceed a firm’s market
capitalization.
We calculate the total market cap of each stock using the CRSP monthly file as
the sum of shares outstanding multiplied by price for each class of common stock associated
with a firm (i.e., we sum across all PERMNOs associated with each PERMCO).
To classify a mutual fund as either passively managed or actively managed, we use a
method similar to that of Busse and Tong (2012) and Iliev and Lowry (2015). Specifically, we
obtain fund names by merging the Thomson Reuters data with the CRSP Mutual Fund data using
the MFLINKS table available on WRDS. We then flag a fund as passively managed if its fund
name includes a string that identifies it as an index fund or if the CRSP Mutual Fund Database
classifies the fund as an index fund.6 We classify all other mutual funds that can be matched to
the CRSP mutual fund data as actively managed, and funds that cannot be matched are left
4
Beyond our focus on passively managed mutual funds and their impact on governance outcomes and
corporate performance, our empirical methodology also differs from previous and contemporaneous
papers that use the Russell cutoff as a source of identification.
Using our IV methodology, we do not find
differences in ownership by active institutions around the Russell 1000/2000 threshold, nor do we find
that index assignment affects other corporate outcomes, including capital structure, investments, the
composition of managerial pay, CEO turnover, and acquisitions, as found in some of these previous
studies. We discuss the tradeoffs of the different methodologies used in this identification setting on our
website, which can be found at http://ssrn.com/abstract=2641548.
5
WRDS estimates that approximately 60% of funds additionally report holdings every quarter before
2004. Thanks to Denys Glushkov at WRDS for assistance with S12 holdings.
6
The strings we use to identify index funds are: Index, Idx, Indx, Ind_ (where _ indicates a space),
Russell, S & P, S and P, S&P, SandP, SP, DOW, Dow, DJ, MSCI, Bloomberg, KBW, NASDAQ, NYSE,
STOXX, FTSE, Wilshire, Morningstar, 100, 400, 500, 600, 900, 1000, 1500, 2000, and 5000.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 6
.
unclassified. To generate variables for mutual fund ownership disaggregated into these three
categories, we compute the percentage of each stock’s market capitalization that is owned by
passive, active, and unclassified mutual funds at the end of each quarter.7
Our subsequent analysis is restricted to the sample of stocks found in the Russell 1000
and 2000 indexes between 1998 and 2006. We obtain data for the Russell 1000 and 2000
indexes from Russell, and we start the sample at 1998 because this is the first year Russell
provides us with its proprietary, float-adjusted market capitalization, which is used to determine
the rank (i.e., portfolio weight) of each security within an index. We end the sample prior to
2007, which is when Russell implemented a new methodology to construct the two indexes such
that they no longer necessarily reflect the 1,000 and next 2,000 largest stocks by market
capitalization.
Russell also provided us with their proprietary end-of-May total market
capitalization values for each year from 2002 to 2006. The importance of the end-of-May market
capitalizations and of ending the sample prior to 2007 is described in Section III.
B. Governance, voting, accounting, and compensation data
Governance and voting data are largely obtained from Riskmetrics (ISS), which provides
information on several aspects of corporate governance for firms in the S&P 1500.
Following
Riskmetrics’ classification of a director’s independence, which excludes linked directors (e.g.,
those with business ties to the firm), we calculate the percentage of independent directors on the
boards of each firm for each year in the sample from the director dataset. The governance
dataset from Riskmetrics is used to create indicator variables for whether a firm removes a
takeover defense or has a dual class share structure in a given year. The governance database is
available for alternating years in the sample, except for 1998 when there is a three-year lag.
We
also construct several variables related to shareholder proposals and voting. We use the voting
results database from Riskmetrics to calculate the average percentage of shares that vote in
support of management proposals at annual meetings and in support of shareholder-initiated
governance proposals for each firm between reconstitutions of the Russell indexes (i.e., between
July of year t and June of year t+1).
Our data on poison pills are obtained from Shark Repellent (FactSet). Shark Repellent
provides historical information on firms’ most recent poison pill, such as when the poison pill
was renewed, withdrawn, or allowed to expire.
The database covers all firms in the Russell 3000
beginning in 2001. We define our variable for poison pill removal as an indicator equal to 1 if a
firm’s poison pill is either withdrawn or allowed to expire at time t, and zero otherwise. Because
Shark Repellent only reports information on a firm’s most recent poison pill, our indicator only
flags firms that removed a poison pill during our sample period and did not reinstate a poison pill
subsequently.
Annual accounting data are from Compustat, and we use executive compensation data
from Execucomp.
Accounting variables are winsorized at the 1% and 99% levels. Definitions
for all our key variables are provided in Appendix Table 1.
C. Sample and descriptive statistics
7
In a previous version of this paper, we instead used total institutional ownership, as reported in the
Thomson Reuters Institutional Holdings (13F) Database, and classified institutions as either passive or
active using the quasi-index, transient, and dedicated categories of Bushee (2001).
A discussion of these
findings and the various tradeoffs inherent in using either the S12 or 13F holdings data can be found in
Section VII.B of the paper.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 7
. For our main analysis, we restrict our sample to stocks in the 250 bandwidth around the
cutoff, as determined using the end-of-June Russell-assigned portfolio weights for stocks within
each index. This sample spans an economically important set of midcap and small cap stocks,
and as discussed in Section VII.A, our subsequent findings are robust to using both wider and
narrower bandwidths.
Table 1 reports summary statistics for our main sample. The average level of mutual fund
ownership (as a percentage of shares outstanding) is around 25%. Actively managed funds are
the largest category (approximately 19% of shares outstanding), with passive and unclassified
funds each accounting for about 3% of shares outstanding.
Support for management proposals is
high (85%), consistent with the notion that many of the issues addressed by these proposals are
routine in nature, while support for shareholder-initiated governance proposals is considerably
lower (36%). Independent directors make up 65% of the total number of directors for firms in
the sample. The table also shows that poison pill removals and the lessening of restrictions on
shareholders’ ability to call a special meeting are relatively uncommon events in our sample,
occurring in just 4% and 0.6% of firm-year observations, respectively.
About 13% of firms have
a dual class share structure. Finally, firms’ ROA averages about 0.03.
III. Empirical framework
Identifying the impact of passive investors on corporate governance and performance
poses an empirical challenge.
Cross-sectional correlations between passive ownership,
governance, and performance might not reflect a causal relation since ownership by passive
investors might be correlated with factors—such as firms’ access to capital, investment
opportunities, or ownership by active investors—that directly affect corporate outcomes. Failure
to control for such factors could introduce an omitted variable bias that confounds inferences. To
overcome this challenge and to determine the importance of passive investors, we use stocks’
assignment to the top of the Russell 2000 index as an exogenous shock to ownership by passive
investors.
We now describe our identification strategy.
A. Russell index construction and passive institutional investors
Passive funds attempt to match the performance of a market index by holding a basket of
representative securities in the particular market index being tracked in proportion to their
weights in the index. The most visible types of passive funds are index funds, which hold nearly
all stocks in the market index rather than a representative sample.
Two market indexes widely used as benchmarks are the Russell 1000 and Russell 2000.
The Russell 1000 comprises the largest 1000 U.S.
stocks in terms of market capitalization, while
the Russell 2000 comprises the next largest 2000 stocks. An example index fund that uses the
Russell 1000 as a benchmark is the Vanguard Russell 1000 Index Fund (VRNIX), while the
Vanguard Russell 2000 Index Fund (VRTIX) uses the Russell 2000 as a benchmark.
To account for changes in stocks’ ranking by market cap, the Russell indexes are
reconstituted each year at the end of June. On the last Friday of June, Russell Investments
determines which stocks will be included in the two indexes for the following twelve months
using market capitalization as of the last trading day in May of that year.8 In other words, the
8
However, when the last Friday of June falls on the 29th or 30th, the two indexes are reconstituted on the
preceding Friday.
During the following twelve months, stocks are only deleted from the indexes due to
Chapter 7 bankruptcy filings, delistings, and corporate actions (takeovers), while IPOs are added quarterly
to the indexes on the basis of the market capitalization breaks established during the most recent
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 8
. 1000 largest stocks at the end of the last trading day in May will be included in the Russell 1000,
while the next 2000 largest stocks will be included in the Russell 2000.9 Each stock’s weight in
the index is then determined using its end-of-June float-adjusted market cap. The float-adjusted
market capitalization is different than the market capitalization used to determine index
membership in that it only includes the value of shares that are available to the public. For
example, shares held by another company or individual that exceed 10% of shares outstanding,
by another member of a Russell index, by an employee stock ownership plan (ESOP), or by a
government will be removed when calculating a firm’s float-adjusted market capitalization, as
will unlisted share classes. Therefore, a stock that was the 1,000th largest stock in total market
capitalization need not be the stock with the smallest portfolio weight in the Russell 1000 index.
Because the Russell indexes are value-weighted, index assignment has a significant effect
on portfolio weights; the 1000th largest stock at the end of May will be included in the Russell
1000 and be given a very small portfolio weight within its index, while the 1001th largest stock
will be included in the Russell 2000 and be given a much larger weight in its index.
For example,
between 1998 and 2006, the average portfolio weight of the bottom 250 stocks in the Russell
1000 was 0.012%, while the average portfolio weight of the top 250 stocks in the Russell 2000
was an order of magnitude larger at 0.127%. The difference in portfolio weights persists over a
wide range around the cutoff. This is seen in Figure 2, where we plot the end-of-June portfolio
weights of the 500 smallest float-adjusted stocks in the Russell 1000 and the 500 largest floatadjusted stocks in the Russell 2000 for the year 2006.
These differences in portfolio weights can have a significant impact on the extent of a
stock’s ownership by passive investors.
Because passive funds weight their holdings based on
the portfolio weights of the underlying index in an attempt to minimize tracking error, it is more
important that they match the weights of the stocks at the top of the index than of stocks at the
bottom of the index. In other words, for each dollar invested in a passive fund benchmarked to
the Russell 1000, very little of it will be invested in stocks at the bottom of that index, while for
each dollar invested in a passive fund benchmarked to the Russell 2000, a large proportion of it
will be invested in stocks at the top of the index. Because of the considerable amount of money
passively tracking the two Russell indexes (Chang, Hong and Liskovich (2014)), the portfolio
decisions of passive institutions can lead to large ownership differences in stocks around the
Russell 1000/2000 threshold.
The importance of index assignment for ownership by passive investors is illustrated in
Figure 3, where we sort stocks using their end-of-May CRSP market capitalization and plot the
average share of firms in the Russell 2000 and average end-of-September ownership by
reconstitution.
For more details regarding the reconstitution process and eligibility for inclusion in the
Russell indexes, see Russell Investments (2013).
9
Beginning in 2007, Russell implemented a “banding” policy where firms within a certain range of the
cutoff would not switch indexes. For example, a firm that was in the Russell 2000 index last year but was
among the 1000 largest firms this year would only move to the Russell 1000 index if its market
capitalization exceeded a certain threshold. Since our identification strategy relies on controlling for the
factors that determine a firm’s index assignment each year, we restrict our attention to years prior to the
implementation of this banding policy where only the end-of-May market capitalization calculated by
Russell is used to determine firms’ index assignment.
For a press release regarding the implementation of
this banding policy by Russell, see https://www.russell.com/us/news/press-release.aspx?link=pressreleases/2007/PR20070403.htm, and for more details on how the banding thresholds are determined each
year, see Russell Investments (2013).
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 9
. passively managed funds. The sample in Figure 3 contains the top 500 stocks of the Russell
2000 and bottom 500 stocks of the Russell 1000 for each year between 1998 and 2006, as
determined using the end-of-June Russell-assigned portfolio weights within each index. By
construction, the top-left panel of Figure 3 shows no break in size between the 500th and 501st
largest stocks in this sample, but as shown in the middle-left panel, there is a rather large jump in
the probability of being assigned to the Russell 2000 index around this break. The end-of-May
market cap reported by CRSP does not perfectly predict a stock’s index assignment because
Russell makes a number of adjustments when calculating its proprietary market capitalization
values such that these values, which are used to determine a stock’s index membership, do not
perfectly match market capitalizations reported in sources such as CRSP.
And consistent with
index assignment having an important impact on ownership, the bottom-left panel of Figure 3
demonstrates a distinct jump in the ownership of passive funds around this midway point.
During our sample period, the total ownership stake of passive funds is, on average, 66% higher
for a stock among the top 250 stocks of the Russell 2000 relative to a stock among the bottom
250 stocks of the Russell 1000 (p-value of difference < 0.001).
The magnitude of the observed difference in passive ownership corresponds well to the
magnitude one would predict using estimates of the total amount of passive assets tracking each
of the two indexes. While the Russell 1000 is more than 10 times larger in total market cap than
the Russell 2000 during our sample period, there is only about 2 to 3 times more dollars
passively tracking the Russell 1000 relative to the Russell 2000 (see Table 1, Panel A of Chang,
Hong, and Liskovich (2014)).10 Using their estimates for 2004, $38.9 billion in assets were
passively tracking the Russell 2000, which accounts for about 3.14% of the index’s total market
cap of $1,237 billion, while there was only $84.9 billion of assets passively tracking the Russell
1000, accounting for just 0.71% of the index’s total market cap of $12,002 billion. Based on
these estimates, assignment to the Russell 2000 in that year would increase a stock’s passive
institutional ownership by about 2.5 percentage points, which is similar to the 2.1 percentage
point increase we detect in 2004 using our measure of passive ownership.
In practice, the
realized differences in passive ownership we detect will be slightly smaller around the cutoff
than predicted by this simple back-of-the-envelope calculation because passive investments by
some institutions, like pension funds, are not reported in the S12 mutual fund database.11
The importance of index assignment for passive ownership is further highlighted by
looking at the ownership stake of three of the largest passive institutions during our sample
period—Vanguard, State Street, and Barclays Bank (which owned iShares during our sample)—
using the Thomson Reuters Institutional Holdings (13F) Database. On average, the ownership
stake of each of these three institutions for the 250 firms at the top of the Russell 2000 relative to
the bottom 250 firms of the Russell 1000 is a third higher, while the likelihood of each institution
10
The disproportionate amount of money passively tracking the Russell 2000 occurs because the Russell
2000 is the most widely used market index for small cap stocks. The Russell 1000, which spans both
large and midcap stocks, is less widely used as a benchmark because it faces more competition from other
large cap and midcap market indexes, including the S&P 500 (which is the most popular market index),
the CRSP U.S.
midcap index, and the S&P 400 midcap index.
11
While using mutual fund holdings allows us to more precisely identify passive and active ownership
stakes, a disadvantage is that it does not capture all institutional passive holdings. However, in Section
VII.B, we demonstrate that our findings are not sensitive to instead using all institutional holdings, as
reported in the Thomson Reuters Institutional Holdings (13F) Database, and to using alternative proxies
for passive ownership, as was done in a previous version of this paper.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 10
. owning more than 5% of a firm’s shares is two thirds higher and the likelihood of being a top 5
shareholder is 15% higher.
We find no evidence that index assignment is related to ownership by actively managed
funds. This is shown in the remaining two panels of Figure 3 where we plot the percent
ownership for actively managed funds and mutual funds we are unable to classify. For each
panel, including passive ownership, we scale the vertical axis to span a standard deviation on
each side of the sample mean. As seen in those panels, there is no corresponding difference in
either active or unclassified mutual fund ownership; we formally test and demonstrate this lack
of a difference in other types of ownership in Section III.C.
B.
Identification strategy and empirical specification
The construction of the Russell 1000 and 2000 indexes thus provides a source of
exogenous variation in ownership by passive investors. Stocks at the top of the Russell 2000
exhibit greater ownership by passive investors because of their inclusion at the top of their index,
while stocks at the bottom of the Russell 1000 do not. Because index assignment is determined
by an arbitrary rule surrounding the market capitalization of the 1000th largest firm, this variation
in ownership is plausibly exogenous after conditioning on firms’ market capitalization.
We use an instrumental variable strategy to identify the effect of ownership by passive
investors on firms’ corporate governance and corporate performance; in particular, we use
inclusion in the Russell 2000 as an instrument for ownership by passive funds.
Because index
assignment is determined by a stock’s market capitalization, and because market capitalization
may directly affect a stock’s institutional ownership for reasons separate from index assignment,
we also include a robust set of controls for stocks’ end-of-May market capitalization in our
estimation. Specifically, we estimate the following:
N
Yit = α + β Passive% it + ∑ θ n ( Ln( Mktcapit ) ) + γ Ln( Floatit ) + δ t + ε it
n
(1)
n=1
where Yit is the outcome of interest for firm i in reconstitution year t (i.e. from end-of-June year t
to end-of-June of year t+1) scaled by its sample standard deviation; Passive%it is the percent of a
firm’s shares held by passively managed mutual funds at the end of the first quarter of the
reconstitution year t (i.e., end of September) scaled by its sample standard deviation; Mktcapit is
the end-of-May CRSP market capitalization of stock i in year t; and Floatit is the float-adjusted
market capitalization calculated by Russell when initially setting the portfolio weights during the
end-of-June reconstitution.
We scale both Yit and Passive%it by their sample standard deviations
such that the point estimate β can be interpreted as the standard deviation difference in Yit for a
one standard deviation increase in Passive%it. We control for float-adjusted market capitalization
because it is used by Russell to compute portfolio weights within each index and could be related
to a firm’s stock liquidity, which may affect firms’ governance and other corporate outcomes
(Back, Li, and Ljungqvist (2014); Edmans, Fang, and Zur (2013)). We also include
reconstitution year fixed effects, δ t , to ensure that our estimates are identified using within-year
variation in ownership and are not driven by the aggregate upward trend in ownership by passive
investors (see Figure 1).
Finally, we cluster the standard errors, ε , at the firm level.12
12
We do not include firm fixed effects in our estimation since only a small fraction of our sample firms
switch indexes at some point during the sample and because many of the governance and corporate
outcomes we study are likely to be affected by sustained rather than transitory variation in passive
ownership. Since firm fixed effects will remove this sustained variation, they will likely not capture the
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 11
. To account for the possibility that ownership by passive funds, as measured using
Passive%, might be correlated with the error term, ε , because of the omitted variable issues
discussed above, we instrument for ownership by passive funds using index assignment.
Specifically, we instrument Passive% in the above estimation using R2000it, which is an
indicator equal to one if stock i is part of the Russell 2000 index in reconstitution year t. As
shown in Figure 3, being assigned to the Russell 2000 is associated with a significant jump in
ownership by passive funds for stocks at the top of Russell 2000 relative to stocks at the bottom
of the Russell 1000.
Our IV estimation relies on the assumption that, after conditioning on stocks’ market
capitalization, inclusion in the Russell 2000 index is associated with an increase in Passive%
(relevance condition) but does not directly affect our outcomes of interest except through its
impact on ownership by passive investors (exclusion restriction). We verify the relevance
condition below in our first stage estimations, and the exclusion restriction seems reasonable in
that it is unclear why index inclusion would be directly related to our outcomes of interest after
robustly controlling for the factor that determines index inclusion—firms’ end-of-May market
capitalization, as calculated by Russell. To control for firms’ market capitalization, we restrict
our sample to the 250 stocks at the bottom of the Russell 1000 and top 250 stocks of the Russell
2000 and include a robust set of controls for firms’ log market capitalization, Ln(Mktcap), as
measured using CRSP data, by varying the polynomial order N we use to control for end-of-May
market capitalization.13 In later robustness tests, we also show robustness to varying the number
of firms we include around the cutoff between the two indexes and to instead using end-of-May
market caps to rank stocks and select our sample each year.
The use of R2000it as an instrument allows us to isolate an exogenous source of variation
in passive ownership.
While non-index funds that passively seek to deliver the performance of a
benchmark portfolio have discretion over which stocks to hold within the benchmark, the
instrumental variable never uses such endogenous variation in passive ownership; the IV
estimation only uses variation in ownership that is driven by a stock’s index assignment and the
reshuffling of holdings by passively managed mutual funds seeking to minimize their tracking
error.
We do not use the actual portfolio weight or ranks of stocks as our instrument because
this would introduce a potentially serious endogeneity concern. In particular, this is problematic
because after Russell assigns stocks to an index, it determines actual weights using various
endogenous factors, including liquidity and inside ownership. For the most illiquid, highest
inside ownership stocks, Russell assigns a smaller portfolio weight than would be justified based
purely on their end-of-May market capitalization so as to minimize the costs of institutions
attempting to track the index.
Because weights are related to a stock’s liquidity and inside
ownership, it would be problematic to use them as instruments because both factors could
directly affect the governance structures of firms.14
relevant variation and thus potentially provide misleading inferences (e.g., see McKinnish (2008);
Gormley and Matsa (2014)).
13
At some level, our estimation can be viewed as one that makes use of a threshold event in a non-RD
estimation, as discussed in Bakke and Whited (2012).
14
This issue of why the actual weights or rankings should not be used as instruments or as part of a
regression discontinuity is also discussed in Chang, Hong, and Liskovich (forthcoming) and Mullins
(2014).
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 12
. C. First stage estimation
In this section, we report estimates of our first-stage regression of passive mutual fund
holdings on membership in the Russell 2000 index plus additional controls. Specifically, we
estimate
N
Passive% it = η + λ R2000it + ∑ χ n ( Ln( Mktcapit ) ) + σ Ln( Floatit ) + δ t + uit
n
(2)
n=1
where R2000it is a dummy variable equal to 1 if stock i is in the Russell 2000 Index for
reconstitution year t (i.e., from end-of-June of year t to end of June year t+1). In our initial tests,
we also analyze other outcome measures, including the percentage of shares outstanding owned
by all mutual funds; the percentage of shares outstanding owned by actively managed funds; and
the percentage of shares outstanding owned by unclassified mutual funds.
The model is
estimated over the 1998-2006 period, and uses a bandwidth of 250 firms and a third-order
polynomial.
The results, reported in Table 2, confirm that mutual fund ownership is related to
membership in the Russell, particularly for passive mutual funds. So that the point estimates in
Table 2 align with the observed differences in ownership shown in Figure 3, we do not scale the
ownership variables by their sample standard deviations in these initial estimates. The first
column shows that aggregate mutual fund ownership is significantly higher (at the 10% level) for
the 250 stocks at the top of the Russell 2000 than for 250 stocks at the bottom of the Russell
1000.
As expected, this relation appears to be driven entirely by passive funds: the estimated
coefficient is positive and significant at the 1% level for the passive funds (column 2), but
insignificant for actively managed and unclassified funds (columns 3 and 4).
In Table 3 we demonstrate that the estimated relation between passive ownership and
Russell 2000 membership is robust to using lower order polynomials, and to better quantify the
economic magnitude of the observed difference in ownership, we scale Passive% by its sample
standard deviation. Using a bandwidth of 250 firms and varying the polynomial order of
controls for market cap, we consistently find an increase in ownership by passive funds of about
a half of a sample standard deviation (Table 3, columns 1–3). In all cases, the increase is
statistically significant at the 1% level.15
The lack of a difference in ownership for actively managed and unclassified mutual funds
is also robust to varying the polynomial order of controls for Mktcap.
This can be seen in
Appendix Table 2. Consistent with actively managed funds being unaffected by a stock’s index
assignment, we find no evidence of a difference in ownership by either actively managed funds
or unclassified funds and the point estimates are economically small (between 1% to 5% of a
their sample standard deviations).
We also do not find evidence that membership in the Russell 2000 is associated with an
increase in the visibility of a stock and subsequent analyst coverage, which is another mechanism
by which index assignment might improve firms’ governance. In particular, if we re-estimate
Equation (2) instead using the number of analysts as the dependent variable, we find no evidence
that assignment to the top of the Russell 2000 is associated with greater analyst coverage; if
anything, we find evidence that inclusion in the Russell 2000 is associated with less analyst
15
Because our IV model is just-identified, the IV estimation is median-unbiased and weak instruments are
unlikely to be a concern in our setting, especially given the strong first stage estimates (Angrist and
Pischke, 2009).
Additionally, the Kleibergen-Paap F stat on the excluded instrument exceeds 10,
providing further confidence that a weak instrument is unlikely to be a concern (see Stock, Wright, and
Yogo (2002) and Angrist and Pischke (2009)).
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 13
. coverage but the estimates are not robust to wider bandwidths. Likewise, Crane, Michenaud, and
Weston (2014) find no evidence of an increase in media coverage among firms at the top of the
Russell 2000. The lack of an increase in either analyst or media coverage among firms at the top
of the Russell 2000 bolsters our assumption that index assignment in our setting will only affects
firms’ governance structure through its effect on passive ownership.
D. Why index assignment may matter
A question that naturally arises is why index assignment might matter at all for firms’
passive ownership.
If the increased ownership stake that comes with a stock being assigned to
the Russell 2000 index allows passive investors to exert additional influence and correct a
governance structure they deem suboptimal (as our findings below suggest), why would passive
investors not also increase their ownership stake among stocks at the bottom of the Russell 1000
so as to exert more influence among those companies as well? In other words, what would
prevent passive institutions from being more active, and hence, undoing the potential importance
of index assignment?
There are two likely explanations for why index assignment may matter for firms’
governance structures. First, passive institutions are simply more focused on minimizing
expenses and tracking errors than on affecting governance. While increasing an ownership stake
for one stock at the bottom of the Russell 1000 might not significantly affect a fund’s tracking
errors relative to a Russell 1000 benchmark, a similar increase for a number of other stocks
would.
Moreover, such targeted activism would likely increase fund expenses since the passive
investor would need to research which stocks to target. Combined these two effects would likely
result in lost market share to competitors with lower costs and lower tracking errors. Second,
index assignment may create a coordinated increase in ownership by passive institutions that
might otherwise be hard to replicate.
Achieving the same total increase in ownership stake may
be prohibitively large for any one passive institution to achieve alone, and coordinating a
combined ownership increase among multiple passive institutions may either be too costly or
impose additional regulatory disclosure requirements these institutions wish to avoid.
Overall, our finding that index assignment corresponds with a shift in passive ownership
suggests that passive institutions and the funds they manage are not active in the traditional sense
of trying to accumulate or exit positions since such actions would undo the importance of index
assignment. We now turn to analyzing whether passive ownership and index assignment affect
firms’ governance structures and the potential mechanisms by which passive investors may exert
influence.
IV. How passive investors affect firms’ corporate governance
To select the governance outcomes for our analysis, we start from a 2014 speech given by
the Chairman and CEO of Vanguard, Bill McNabb, that summarizes the broad governance issues
on which Vanguard focuses.
These issues include “Independent oversight” (i.e., board
independence), “Annual director elections and minimal anti-takeover devices”, “Shareholder
voting rights consistent with economic interest” (i.e., no dual class share structures that provide
disparate voting rights to different groups of shareholders), and “Sensible compensation tied to
performance”.16 We then compare these issues to the proxy voting policies of Vanguard and
16
This speech, which can be found at
http://www.lerner.udel.edu/sites/default/files/WCCG/PDFs/events/Transcript%20_UDel%20Corp%20Governance%2010%2030%202014_%20FINAL%20for%20UD%20websi
te.pdf, is based off the governance principles Vanguard states on its website at
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 14
. other large passive investors during our earlier sample period by obtaining the initial proxy
voting policies provided to the SEC by Vanguard, State Street, and Barclays Bank when the
filing of such policies was first required beginning on July 1, 2003. From these proxy-voting
policies, it is clear that these four broad governance issues were also a focus of passive investors
during our sample period. In particular, the largest passive investors (1) supported greater board
independence, (2) opposed takeover defenses, (3) opposed unequal voting rights, as occurs when
firms maintain a dual class share structure, and (4) supported compensation plans that align
management’s interests with shareholders and avoid excessive awards (see Appendix).17
But, do passive investors, whose impact tends to be limited to “voice,” have an effect on
these aspects of corporate governance? In this section, we investigate these questions using the
identification strategy and instrumental variable estimation described in Section III to analyze
their impact on three of these issues: board independence, takeover defenses, and equal voting
rights. We will analyze their impact on the fourth issue, the level and structure of executive
compensation, in Section VI.B.
A.
Independent directors
We first assess whether passive institutions exert influence on board independence.
Increasing the percent of independent directors was a specific concern of many passive investors
during our sample period (see Appendix) and is one dimension of governance where passive
investors have a direct say via their proxy votes in director elections. Passive investor support for
independent directors likely stems from the belief that independent directors are more likely to
be effective monitors (Fama and Jensen (1983), Weisbach (1988)). Table 4 reports results for our
IV estimation using percentage of independent director scaled by its sample standard deviation
as the dependent variable.
We find that passive investors do indeed have a significant impact on this key dimension
of corporate governance.
We find a statistically significant positive relation (at the 1% level)
between Passive% and the percentage of independent directors that is robust to various
polynomial order controls for market capitalization. The economic magnitude of the relation is
sizable. A one standard deviation increase in ownership by passive funds is associated with a
0.65 to 0.76 standard deviation increase in the share of independent directors on a firm’s board
(Table 4, columns 1–3).
In unreported analysis, we find this increase in director independence is
not driven by an increase in board size; to the contrary, greater ownership by passive funds is
associated with smaller boards.18
https://about.vanguard.com/vanguard-proxy-voting/corporate-governance/index.html. Two other
governance issues that were discussed in this speech, but are not as easily tested, are “Accountability” (of
both the board and management) and “Shareholder engagement”.
17
These historical proxy voting guidelines can be found on the SEC website and are summarized in the
Appendix. Other popular governance issues, like splitting the positions of CEO and Chairman of the
Board, however, are not mentioned in either the Vanguard speech or the proxy voting guidelines of the
largest passive investors.
At some level, this particular exclusion is not surprising since some passive
institutions (e.g. Vanguard) have the same individual act as both CEO and Chairman, and consistent with
passive investors not holding a view on this issue, we find no association between passive ownership and
whether a company’s CEO serves as Chairman of the Board.
18
Because Riskmetrics only covers firms in the S&P 1500, the sample size in Table 4 is about a third
smaller than the first stage estimates reported in Table 3. However, this reduced sample size does not
pose a problem for our estimation.
The first stage estimates in the smaller sample of observations with
non-missing director data remain statistically significant at the 1% level. This can be seen in Appendix
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 15
. The impact of passive investors on board independence is even larger prior to changes
regarding board independence requirements at the NYSE and Nasdaq exchanges. In late 2002,
both exchanges proposed changes to require that all firms listed on the exchange have a majority
of independent directors, and the SEC approved the proposed changes in 2003. Consistent with
passive investors having more of an influence on board independence prior to 2003, we find that
a one standard deviation increase in ownership by passive funds is associated with a 1.3 to 1.4
standard deviation increase in share of independent directors on a firm’s board prior to 2003
(Table 5, columns 1–3) but only a 0.26 to 0.35 standard deviation increase after 2002 (columns
4–6). The differences in the estimates across time period are statistically significant at the 1
percent confidence level.19
B.
Takeover defenses
We now consider the association between passive investors and takeover defenses.
Opposition to takeover defenses, including poison pills and restrictions on shareholders’ ability
to call special meetings, were a common theme of passive investors’ proxy voting guidelines
during our sample (see Appendix).
While poison pills may be in shareholders’ interests under some circumstances, they are
often seen as a mechanism used to shelter managers from the disciplining effects of hostile
takeovers. Specifically, poison pills (formally known as “shareholder rights plans”) effectively
bar any single shareholder from acquiring more than a pre-defined percentage of shares (often
between 10% and 15%) without significantly diluting their holdings (Bebchuk, Cohen, Ferrell
(2009)). While Coates (2000) notes that essentially every firm has a “shadow pill” in place
because a pill may be implemented by a board at any time without shareholder approval, having
a poison pill in place is still thought to provide managers with advantages in fighting off hostile
bids and unwanted activists.20 Moreover, institutional investors widely call for the redemption of
poison pills and support efforts to subject them to shareholder votes in order to improve the
accountability of managers and boards.
We find evidence that ownership by passive funds is associated with an increase in the
removal of poison pills.
To determine the influence of passive institutions on the removal of
poison pills, we estimate equation (1) with an indicator variable equal to one if the firm’s poison
pill is either withdrawn or allowed to expire and zero otherwise. These estimates are reported in
Table 6. The estimated coefficient is positive and statistically significant (at the 1% level).
A
one standard deviation increase in Passive% is associated with a 0.18–0.20 standard deviation
(i.e., 3.3–3.8 percentage point) increase in the likelihood of a poison pill being removed (Table 6,
columns 1–3). The estimate is economically sizable given that, on average, only 4% of firms
remove a poison pill each year.
We next analyze whether ownership by passive investors is associated with a greater
ability for shareholders to call a special meeting, another important aspect of governance (Daines
and Klausner (2001); Cremers and Nair (2005)). Similar to poison pills, restrictions on
Table 3A.
The first stage estimates for our later estimates in Tables 6, 7, and 8 can be found in Appendix
Tables 3A-3B. We do not separately report first stage estimates for Tables 9 and 10 since their samples
are comparable to that used in Table 3.
19
While the proposed exchange listing requirements did not become effective until 2004, many firms
began complying in 2003. Given this, we follow Chhaochharia and Grinstein (2009) and use the year
2003 as the potential breaking point; see Chhaochharia and Grinstein (2009) for more details.
20
As noted by Bebchuk, Cohen, and Ferrell (2009), “having a pill in place saves the need to install it in
‘the heat of battle’… [and] signals to hostile bidders that the board ‘will not go easy’.”
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 16
.
shareholders’ ability to call special meetings can represent a potential impediment to effective
governance by delaying dissident shareholders’ ability to remove directors, and such restrictions,
especially if combined with a poison pill, are also seen as an effective takeover defense for
entrenched managers (Daines and Klausner (2001)). To assess the ability of passive institutions
to reduce restrictions on shareholders’ ability to call special meetings, we estimate equation (1)
with an indicator variable equal to one if the firm eliminates such restrictions, and zero
otherwise. These estimates are reported in columns 4–6 of Table 6.
We find evidence that ownership by passive funds is associated with the removal of
restrictions on shareholders’ ability to call special meetings. The estimated coefficient is positive
and statistically significant (at the 1% level) in all of the estimations; in particular, a one standard
deviation increase in passive ownership is associated with about a 0.30–0.34 standard deviation
(i.e., 2.4–2.7 percentage point) increase in the likelihood that a firm eliminates restrictions on
shareholders’ ability to call special meetings.
Relative to the average share of firms that lift
restrictions each year in our sample, which is about 0.6%, the estimated magnitude is sizable.
In unreported analysis, we also analyzed the impact of passive ownership on whether
firms have annual director elections. Staggered director elections and classified boards are
another type of takeover defense that passive institutions typically oppose (see McNabb (2014)
and Appendix). We find suggestive evidence that passive ownership is also associated with
firms being less likely to have a classified board, but the estimates are not statistically significant
at conventional levels.
The statistically weaker results for classified boards may partially be an
artifact of the time period of our sample; Guo, Kruse, and Nohel (2008) note that shareholder
efforts to de-classify boards intensified significantly in 2003 following the passage of SarbanesOxley. Consistent with this possibility, we find stronger evidence that passive ownership is
associated with firms being less likely to have a classified board after 2003, but the estimates are
only statistically significant in bandwidths wider than the 250 stocks around the threshold we use
in our main analysis.21
C. Equal voting rights and dual class share structures
Finally, we analyze whether ownership by passive investors is associated with the voting
rights of shareholders.
Passive institutions uniformly oppose dual class share structures and any
other form of unequal voting rights and often threaten to withhold support for managers or
directors of any company that does not provide equal voting rights to all shareholders (see
McNabb (2014) and the Appendix for examples). Passive institutions also state they will refuse
to support any attempts by companies to implement a dual class share structure (as might occur
during a merger). Moreover, by concentrating voting power among insiders, Klausner (2012)
argues that dual class share structures are one of the most powerful takeover defenses, providing
yet another reason passive investors oppose them, and Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2010) find
evidence that dual class share structures can negatively impact firm value.
To assess whether ownership by passive investors is associated with a firm being less
likely to have unequal voting rights, we construct an indicator that equals one if the firm has a
dual class share structure, and zero otherwise, as determined by Riskmetrics.
These estimates
21
In unreported analysis, we also analyzed the impact of passive ownership on super majority vote
requirements, a fourth antitakeover device specifically mentioned in Vanguard and State Street’s
historical proxy voting policies. We find a negative association between passive ownership and the
likelihood a firm has supermajority voting requirements, but the point estimates are neither statistically
significant nor economically large.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 17
. are reported in Table 7. We find evidence that ownership by passive funds is associated with
firms being less likely to have a dual class share structure. The estimated coefficient is negative
and statistically significant (at the 1% level) in all of the estimations; a one standard deviation
increase in Passive% is associated with about a one standard deviation decrease in the likelihood
that a firm has a dual class share structure.22
Another voting rights issue that is discussed in the proxy voting guidelines of passive
investors is their opposition to cumulative voting. As Vanguard’s states in its proxy voting
guidelines, cumulative voting can allow “shareholders a voice in director elections that is
disproportionate to their economic investment in the corporation.” However, in unreported
analysis, we do not find an association between passive ownership and whether firms have
cumulative voting for directors.
V.
Possible mechanisms by which passive investors influence governance
A key mechanism by which passive investors might influence a firm’s governance
structure is via their voice. In particular, passive investors may use their ownership stake and
ability to vote in order to monitor firms and ensure conformity with their views on governance
structures. Alternatively, it is also possible the passive investors’ influence is not the result of
them being active owners.
Instead, passive investors’ concentrated ownership may facilitate
activism by others, such as hedge funds, by lowering the costs for other activists attempting to
coordinate votes against management (Brav et al. (2008), Bradley et al. (2010)).
In this section,
we investigate these two possible channels.
A. The power of passive investors’ “voice”
To address whether passive investors’ exercise voice and influence firms’ governance
through their large voting blocs, we first analyze support for management proposals. Shareholder
voting at annual meetings is a fundamental duty of shareholders, and votes against management
proposals can be a proxy for increased monitoring by shareholders (Easterbrook and Fischel
(1983)).
To assess whether passive institutions influence voting outcomes, we estimate equation
(1) with the dependent variable defined as the average percentage of shares that vote in support
of management proposals.
Consistent with an increased monitoring of managers and with passive investors
exercising voice, we find that greater ownership by passive funds is associated with less support
for management proposals (Table 8, columns 1–3). The estimated coefficients are negative and
statistically significant (at the 1% level). A one standard deviation increase in ownership by
passive funds is associated, on average, with about a 0.75 standard deviation decline in support
for management proposals.
Consistent with passive investors being active in monitoring
managers, management appears to be confronted with a more contentious shareholder base when
passive funds, which are less able to vote with their feet, make up a larger percentage of the
ownership.
22
Because adding a dual class share structure is typically not allowed by stock exchanges after a firm’s
initial IPO, the observed difference in dual class structures is most likely driven by firms removing a dual
class share structure rather than failing to add one. Consistent with this, in unreported estimates we find
that passive ownership is positively associated with the removal of dual class shares, but unlike our
findings for poison pills and restrictions on shareholder meetings, the estimates are not statistically
significant at conventional levels. This is likely attributed to the relatively small number of companies
that make such changes following their initial public offering; on average, only about 0.9 percent of firms
remove a dual class share structure each year in our sample.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 18
.
The decline in support for management proposals does not originate from a shift in the
number or type of management proposals put to a vote. In unreported analysis, we find that
greater ownership by passive funds is not associated with a change in the total number of
management proposals, and we find little evidence of an association with the composition of
proposals. The lack of difference in the composition of proposals suggests the lower support for
management proposals is not driven by managers submitting a greater number of lessshareholder-friendly proposals.
We next analyze support for governance-related shareholder proposals. While these
proposals are non-binding, they potentially increase pressure on boards to make changes to their
firms’ governance structure (Del Guercio and Hawkins (1999)).
If passive investors use such
votes to exercise voice and influence, we might expect to observe an increase in support for such
proposals.
In further support of passive investors exercising voice via their votes, we find evidence
that ownership by passive funds is associated with an overall increase in support for governancerelated shareholder proposals. On average, a one standard deviation increase in ownership by
passive funds is associated with a 0.49–0.65 standard deviation increase in support for
governance proposals (Table 8, columns 4–6). While the increase in support is only statistically
significant at the 10% level when adding second- or third-order polynomial controls (p-values
0.062 and 0.064, respectively), the implied magnitudes are economically large.
The lower
statistical significance likely reflects the relatively small number of such governance proposals.
Similar to management proposals, we find no systematic relation between ownership by passive
funds and differences in the types of shareholder proposals voted on.
B. No increased activism by others
An alternative mechanism by which passive ownership might influence firms’
governance structure is by facilitating activism by other, non-passive investors. In particular, the
size and concentration of passive investors’ ownership stakes may increase activist investors’
ability to rally support for their demands (Brav et al.
(2008), Bradley et al. (2010)). Such added
pressure from activist investors might also explain a number of the governance differences we
observe.
In other words, is it possible that the observed differences in governance are not driven
by passive investors being engaged owners, but rather, driven by their ownership stake making it
easier for others to engage in activism?
We find no evidence, however, that greater ownership by passive investors is associated
with more activism by non-passive institutions; instead, we find evidence of less activism by
non-passive institutions, consistent with passive investors monitoring managers and reducing the
need for activism by other investors. To demonstrate this, we estimate equation (1) with an
indicator variable equal to one if the firm experiences a hedge fund activism event, as defined in
Brav, Jiang, Partnoy, and Thomas (2008) and Brav, Jiang, and Kim (2010), and zero otherwise.23
These estimates are reported in Table 9. The point estimates are negative and statistically
significant.
We find that a one standard deviation increase in passive fund ownership is
associated with a 0.13–0.16 standard deviation (i.e., 1.6–2.0 percentage point) decline in the
23
We thank Alon Brav for making these data on hedge fund activism events available to us. The database
is an updated sample [1994-2011] using the same data collection procedure and estimation methods as in
Brav, Jiang, Partnoy, and Thomas (2008) and Brav, Jiang, and Kim (2010). For more information on how
the
database
is
constructed,
please
see
https://faculty.fuqua.duke.edu/~brav/HFactivism_SEPTEMBER_2013.pdf.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 19
.
likelihood of hedge fund activism. This magnitude is large given that a firm’s likelihood of an
activism event in a given year in our sample is, on average, only 1.6%.24
While the observed decline in activism by non-passive institutions is consistent with
passive investors successfully affecting governance outcomes and reducing the need for activism
by others, it does not negate the possibility that the concentration of passive institutions’
ownership stakes increases the threat of activism by others, or that this threat increases the
influence of passive investors’ “voice”. Concerned about an increased threat of activism,
managers may be particularly responsive to the views of passive investors and be taking actions
to preempt an actual activist campaign. Anecdotal evidence suggests that informal discussions
between passive institutions and managers, backed up with the threat of voice, are often used to
exert influence.25
VI.
Do passive investors affect performance, compensation, or other corporate policies?
Ownership by passive investors might also be associated with differences in firm
performance, managerial compensation, or corporate policies. Overall performance or corporate
policies might differ if the observed differences in governance associated with passive investors
help mitigate managerial agency conflicts or if managers adjust corporate policies so as to
preempt hedge fund activism campaigns that rely on the support of passive investors. We now
explore this possibility.
A.
Overall performance
There is considerable debate about the value implications of various governance
structures or whether the potential influence of passive investors will necessarily improve firm
performance. Because greater board independence, fewer takeover defenses, and equal voting
rights arguably increase shareholder rights, one might expect that passive ownership mitigates
agency conflicts and is associated with improved performance. However, theory suggests that
board independence might be a result rather than a cause of performance (Hermalin and
Weisbach (1998)), and the empirical evidence regarding the performance implications of board
independence is mixed (e.g., Bhagat and Black (2002); Hermalin and Weisbach (2003)).
Likewise, the value implication of removing poison pills and other takeover defenses is
debatable (e.g., Stein (1988), Coates (2000)).
More broadly, one might also argue that the
optimal governance structure may vary considerably across firms (e.g., Coles, Daniel, Naveen
(2008); Duchin, Matsusaka, Ozbas (2010)), and hence, the potential “one-size-fits-all”
governance view of passive investors may not always represent an improvement for individual
firms.
24
In further support that the observed differences in governance are not driven an increase in activism by
other, non-passive investors, we find no evidence that firms with greater passive ownership are more
likely to be the target of a takeover attempt, another mechanism by which activists might exercise
influence.
25
Glenn Booraem, controller of Vanguard funds, notes that engagement with directors and management
of companies is a key component of Vanguard’s governance program, and that Vanguard has “found
through hundreds of discussion every year” that it is “frequently able to accomplish as much—or more—
through dialogue” as through voting (see Booream (2013)). And in a speech from October 2014, the
CEO and Chairman of the Vanguard group, F. William McNabb, noted that Vanguard sent out 923 letters
to firms in 2013, 358 of which requested specific changes in governance, and that 80 of these companies
had adopted substantive changes without having to go through a shareholder proposal (see McNabb
(2014)).
Earlier findings regarding activism by TIAA-CREF also confirm the importance and impact of
such private negotiations (Carleton, Nelson, and Weisbach (1998)).
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 20
. Consistent with the governance structure promoted by passive investors having a positive
impact on performance for the average firm, we find evidence that ownership by passive funds is
related to an overall improvement in firms’ future performance, as measured using firms’ ROA.
Although passive fund ownership is not associated with significant differences in firms’ overall
ROA in our main specification (Table 10, columns 1-3), it is positively associated with firms’
ROA after adding controls for whether a firm switched indexes that particular year (columns 46). This is likely because improvements in performance may take time to manifest, and one
would not expect to find a relation between changes in passive fund ownership and performance
for firms that just switched indexes. Consistent with this, we find that adding controls for such
recent movers reveals a positive and statistically significant association between passive
ownership and ROA. On average, a one standard deviation increase in passive fund ownership is
associated with about a 0.31–0.41 standard deviation increase in long-term ROA.
In unreported
estimates, we also find that passive fund ownership is positively associated with Tobin’s Q,
another commonly used measure of firm performance.26
B. Executive compensation
There has been much debate regarding managerial pay and whether its growth reflects an
efficient market outcome or an agency conflict, and passive investors commonly discuss the
importance of the need to properly reward and incentivize managers while avoiding “excessive”
pay (see McNabb (2014) and the Appendix). To assess whether passive fund ownership affects
CEO compensation structure, we examine total CEO pay, its composition, and the sensitivity of
CEO pay to stock price movements.
We find less evidence that ownership by passive funds is associated with a difference in
overall managerial pay or its composition.
In unreported analysis, we find that while Passive%
is negatively associated with total pay, the estimates are not statistically significant except in
wider bandwidths. We also find little evidence that passive fund ownership is associated with
differences in the composition of managerial pay (salary, bonuses, and grants of restricted stock,
each scaled by total pay) or the sensitivity of pay to stock price movements (as measured using
the delta or vega of the manager’s stock portfolio; see Gormley, Matsa, and Milbourn (2013) for
variable definitions). Thus, for our sample at least, passive institutions appear to have a relatively
little impact on executive compensation.
However, it is important to note that our sample
predates the implementation of “Say on Pay” by the Dodd-Frank Act in 2010. This provision,
which requires nonbinding votes on executive pay packages, potentially provides an added
mechanism for passive investors to influence compensation decisions.
C. Cash, dividend, financing, and investment policies
There is an extensive literature addressing the relation between corporate ownership
structure and corporate policies; for example, agency theories suggest that better monitoring by
shareholders might lead to changes in leverage, acquisitions, cash levels, and payout policies
(Jensen (1986), La Porta et al.
(2000)). To examine whether ownership by passive investors is
associated with differences in these other corporate policies, we estimate equation (1) with
standard measures of financing, investment, cash, and dividend policies as the outcome variable.
We find relatively little evidence that ownership by passive funds is associated with
26
Similar to ROA, we find a positive association between passive ownership and Tobin’s Q only after
controlling for whether a firm switched indexes that year. Importantly, our earlier estimates for
governance and vote outcomes are unaffected by the inclusion of the additional controls for whether a
firm switched indexes that year.
These robustness tests are discussed in Section VII.A.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 21
. corporate policies related to investment, capital structure, or cash holdings. In unreported
results, we find no difference in firms’ leverage, capital expenditures, R&D expenses, cash-toasset ratio, or acquisitions. These findings are consistent with anecdotal evidence that passive
investors lack the resources necessary to research and influence corporate policies that are
inherently more firm-specific. We do, however, find weak evidence that passive ownership is
associated with higher dividends.
In unreported analysis, we find that a one standard deviation
increase in Passive% is associated with about a 0.15 standard deviation increase in firms’
dividend yield (significant at 10% level in some specifications). We find qualitatively similar
results if we instead use a payout ratio and scale firms’ annual dividends by their net income, but
the estimates are not statistically significant at conventional levels.
VII. Additional robustness checks and choice of specification
In this section, we discuss the robustness of our IV estimates.
In particular, we
demonstrate that our findings are not sensitive to how we measure end-of-May market caps, to
adding additional controls, to varying the sample bandwidth around the threshold, to using
alternative definitions of passive institutional ownership as our key explanatory variable, or to
using end-of-May market cap rankings to select our sample of stocks each year. We also address
the possibility of a selection bias around the Russell 1000/2000 threshold, particularly for the
subsample of observations covered by Riskmetrics.
A. Robustness to choice of controls, choice of bandwidth, and placebo tests
The assumption of our identification strategy is that after limiting the sample to stocks
close to the Russell 1000/2000 threshold and controlling for the one factor that determines index
membership (i.e., end-of-May market cap), index membership does not directly affect our
outcomes except through its effect on passive ownership.
This is the exclusion restriction of the
IV estimation. However, because Russell Investments uses a proprietary method to calculate
firms’ total market caps, we are only able to imperfectly control for the underlying market cap
used to determine index assignment.27
Our findings, however, are robust to using alternative ways to measure firms’ end-ofMay market cap. In particular, using the noisy end-of-May market caps obtained directly from
Russell to measure Mktcap does not affect our findings.
This is shown in Appendix Table 4,
where we re-estimate our main IV regressions for the period 1998-2006 using the 250 bandwidth
with third-order polynomial controls for Ln(Mktcap) after replacing the CRSP market cap with
the Russell-provided market cap for the years 2002-2006. The estimates are nearly the same as
before. Our findings are also robust to instead using the Compustat security monthly file to
determine end-of-May market cap (see Appendix Table 5).
Our findings are also robust to including various controls.
Adding 2-digit SIC industry
fixed effects to the specification does not affect our findings (see Appendix Table 6). Our
findings are also largely unaffected if we add controls to account for firms that moved from the
27
According to Russell’s documentation, their proprietary calculation of market capitalization includes
some ownership stakes, like common stock, non-restricted exchangeable shares, and partnership units, but
excludes other forms of shares, such as preferred stock or redeemable shares (Russell 2013). The share
price chosen by Russell to compute market capitalization can also vary for firms that have multiple share
classes or did not trade on the last day of May.
Similar to Mullins (2014), we contacted Russell
Investments and were only able to obtain a noisy measure their proprietary measure of market
capitalizations for the years 2002 through 2006. Russell does not have the data prior to 2002. See Mullins
(2014) for more details regarding the likely sources for this noise.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 22
.
Russell 1000 to the Russell 2000 that year, and vice versa. If such switchers differ in other
dimensions and represent a disproportionate share of either index, this could affect our earlier
estimates. However, all of the findings are robust to the inclusion of these controls (see
Appendix Table 7). In unreported analysis, we find that our estimates are unaffected by the
inclusion of additional controls for a stock’s liquidity, such as the Amihud measure of illiquidity
or a stock’s average bid-ask spread.
Our estimates are also robust to our choice of bandwidth around the Russell 1000/2000
threshold.
This is shown in Appendix Figure 1, where we plot the point estimates and 95th
percentile confidence intervals when varying the bandwidth between 100 and 500 firms and
using a first-order polynomial control for Ln(Mktcap); estimates are reported for both the first
stage and IV specifications of Tables 3-10. The estimates are relatively similar across the various
bandwidths, and there is no evidence to indicate that our findings are sensitive to the choice of
bandwidth.
Finally, in further support that our findings are not driven by omitted variables that may
be correlated with firms’ end-of-May market cap, we do not find an association between passive
ownership and our outcomes of interest in placebo IV or reduced form tests that use alternative
thresholds. For example, if we restrict the sample to the top 500 firms of the Russell 2000, and
replace our R2000 indicator with an indicator for the bottom 250 firms of this subsample, our IV
estimation does not detect an effect of passive ownership on any of our outcomes, nor do we find
any of our findings in a reduced form estimation of the outcomes onto R2000.
Likewise, we do
not find an effect of passive ownership in a similar placebo test that uses the bottom 500 firms of
the Russell 1000.
B. Robustness to alternative definitions of passive ownership
For our analysis above, we measure the ownership stake of passive investors by summing
up the ownership of mutual funds we classify as passively managed. A key advantage of using
the Thomson Reuters Mutual Fund Holdings Database is that it allows for a precise measure of
passive ownership.
A disadvantage of the fund-level data, however, is that it misses the holdings of passive
institutional investors that do not manage mutual funds or ETFs.
The Thomson Reuters S12
mutual fund data we use exclude holdings by banks, insurance companies, and pension funds,
some of which might also adopt passive investment strategies. While the exclusion of these
passive institutions does not affect the validity of our IV estimation, it does mean one must be
more careful in interpreting the IV point estimates. In particular, attempting to back out the
implied change in governance structure for a given percentage change in passive ownership
might lead to an overestimation of the actual economic magnitude of interest.28 To avoid this
potential concern, we scale our measure of Passive% by its sample standard deviation so that
point estimates instead reflect the observed difference in governance for a one standard deviation
28
For example, if the reduced form estimation of board independence detects a 4.87 percentage point
increase in the share of directors classified as independent for stocks in the Russell 2000 and the first
stage estimation detects a 0.94 percentage point increase in holdings by passively managed mutual funds,
then the IV estimate for board independence will equal 4.87/0.94 = 5.18.
In other words, the IV estimate
will indicate that a one percentage point change in passive ownership causes a 5.18 percentage point
increase in board independence. But if the true increase in passive ownership for stocks assigned to the
Russell 2000, after accounting for passive investors not accounted for in the mutual fund data, is instead
2.1 percentage points, then the true effect of a one percentage point increase in passive ownership on
board independence would be 4.87/2.1 = 2.32 percentage points.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 23
. difference in passive fund ownership. Under the assumption that the standard deviation change
in passive fund ownership for stocks assigned to the Russell 2000 would be similar with the
inclusion of any passive investors not captured by the S12 data, the point estimates we obtain in
the scaled regression will accurately reflect the economic magnitude of interest.
Using a broader measure of passive ownership, however, has no effect on our findings.
To illustrate this, we obtain data on institutional holdings from the Thomson Reuters Institutional
Holdings (13F) Database. Any financial institution exercising discretionary management of
investment portfolios over $100 million in qualified securities is required to report its aggregate
holdings quarterly to the SEC using Form 13F, and consistent with this capturing a larger share
of institutional ownership than the S12 data, we find that institutional holdings account for about
70% of market capitalization compared to the 25% of market capitalization accounted for by
mutual funds in the S12 data. We then classify institutions as either passive or active using
Bushee’s (2001) classification of institutions.
In particular, we classify “quasi-index”
institutions as passive and “transient” or “dedicated” institutions as active.29 Using this
alternative measure of passive and active ownership, we repeat our first stage and IV estimations.
These estimates are reported in Tables 11 and 12. As further evidence that only passive
investors adjust their holdings to index assignment, our first stage estimates only detect an
increase in “quasi-index” ownership (which includes some of the largest passive investors, like
Vanguard, State Street, and Barclay’s Bank) and no increase in “transient” or “dedicated”
ownership. Moreover, as shown in Table 12, our IV estimates when using Quasi-index% remain
qualitatively similar.30
Our findings are also robust to using alternative definitions of passive investors.
In
particular, if we instead measure passive ownership as just the sum of holdings by Barclays
Bank, State Street, and Vanguard, we get similar findings. In unreported first stage estimates, we
find that being assigned to the Russell 2000 is associated with a very large and statistically
significant increase in the combined holdings of these three passive institutions; they account for
more than half of the increase in Quasi-index ownership shown in Table 11. Moreover, our IV
estimations remain large and statistically significant when we use the combined ownership of
these three firms as the explanatory variable instead of all quasi-index ownership.
This can be
seen in Appendix Table 8. These findings provide additional confidence that our earlier estimates
are capturing the influence of passive investors and that the IV estimation is not sensitive to how
we measure passive ownership.
C. Robustness to alternative sampling choices
29
To avoid changes in the classification of an institution over time, we use Bushee’s “permanent”
classification.
Our findings, however, are similar if we do not use Bushee’s “permanent” classification
and instead use the time-varying classifications provided by Bushee or restrict the measure of passive
ownership to institutions that are classified as a quasi-indexer in every year of our sample period.
30
Similar to before, one must be cautious in interpreting the economic magnitudes of these estimates.
Because the Bushee (2001) “quasi-index” classification includes some active investors and actively
managed mutual funds, the first stage estimates for the implied standard deviation change in Quasiindex% likely understate the true standard deviation change in passive holdings. In particular, the 2.3
percentage point increase in quasi-index holdings found in Table 11, Column (2) corresponds to about a
0.14 standard deviation change in Quasi-index%, which is considerably smaller than the 0.5 standard
deviation change detected when using a more precise measure of passive holdings. This smaller first
stage estimate will cause the IV estimates to be inflated when using Quasi-index% scaled by its sample
standard deviation as the explanatory variable to be instrumented.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 24
.
In our main analysis, we select our sample to be the 250 stocks with the smallest portfolio
weights in the Russell 1000 and the 250 stocks with the largest portfolio weights in the Russell
2000. Our findings, however, are not sensitive to instead using end-of-May market caps to
determine the sample of stocks each year. In particular, we can instead rank stocks based on
their end-of-May market cap, as calculated using CRSP, and select the sample for each year of
the sample using firms ranked 750th through 1250th that year. An advantage of this latter
approach is that it eliminates the risk that Russell’s float-adjusted reweighting of stocks within an
index affects our findings.
A disadvantage of this approach, however, is that we are no longer
necessarily comparing the very bottom firms of the Russell 1000 against the very top firms of the
Russell 2000, which is where we would expect to find the biggest difference in passive
ownership (and hence, outcomes) to occur. This sampling choice, however, has little impact on
our IV estimates. While the first stage estimates are expectedly smaller in magnitude when we
use end-of-May market caps to rank stocks and select our sample each year (coefficient = 0.383,
t-stat = 9.54), the IV estimations are largely unchanged (see Appendix Table 9).
D.
Ruling out potential sample selection biases
One potential concern with our analysis is the possibility of systematic differences
(beyond market capitalization, which we control for) in the type of stocks on the two sides of the
Russell 1000/2000 threshold. For example, one might worry that “fallen angels” (stocks
experiencing significant declines in stock price) are more likely to appear in the Russell 2000,
while “rising stars” (stocks experiencing significant increases in stock price) are more likely to
appear in the Russell 1000. Additionally, this concern could be particularly relevant for our
analysis that uses the Riskmetrics data, which is largely limited to firms in the S&P 1500, if there
are systematic differences in the likelihood of fallen angels or rising stars from the Russell 2000
sample being included in the S&P 1500 (and hence, Riskmetrics) relative to the likelihood of
fallen angels or rising stars from the Russell 1000 sample being included in the S&P 1500.
If
present, such difference could cause a violation of the exclusion restriction.
However, we do not find significant evidence of differences in the lagged returns (prior
to reconstitution) between the stocks on different sides of the Russell 1000/2000 threshold.
Specifically, we find no evidence that “fallen angels” or “rising stars” are disproportionately
represented in either index, including the subsample covered by Riskmetrics. To show this, we
create indicator variables for “rising stars” and “fallen angels” that equals 1 if a stock’s return is
in the top or bottom 5% of the sample for the 12 months before reconstitution (i.e., end-of-May
in year t-1 to end-of-May in year t), respectively. We do not find statistically significant
differences in the proportion of fallen angels and rising stars in the Russell 1000 versus the
Russell 2000, either in the full sample or in the sample of observations covered by Riskmetrics.
Moreover, we do not find evidence of a significant difference in either the lagged stock return or
lagged change in stocks’ end-of-May market cap ranking between the stocks on either side of the
Russell 1000/2000 threshold for the sample observations covered by Riskmetrics.
While there is
evidence in the full sample that stocks at the top of the Russell 2000 have a higher average
lagged stock return, our main second-stage results are robust to controlling for past stock price
returns (see Appendix Table 10) or other indicators for a large change in market cap over the
past year.
Finally, any selection into the Riskmetrics database based on dual class share structures
cannot easily explain our findings regarding dual class structures. Since S&P requires firms to
have a public float of at least 50% of the stock in order to be added to the S&P 1500, companies
with dual class structures might be less likely to be included in the S&P 1500. However, because
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 25
.
our analysis is limited to the subsample of firms covered by Riskmetrics, our estimates indicate
that among firms covered by Riskmetrics, more passive ownership is associated with a firm
being less likely to have a dual class share structure. In other words, any type of selection (if it
existed) would not be a problem for our analysis.
VIII. Conclusion
Passive institutions, like Vanguard and State Street, are an increasingly important
component of U.S. stock ownership, and the impact of their growth on firm-level governance is
widely debated.
Despite arguments that they may be lazy investors that lack both the motivation
and resources to monitor managers, there are multiple reasons why passive investors may have a
vested interest in affecting firms’ governance structures and performance and why their large
ownership stakes might make them an influential voice in decisions pertaining to firms’
governance structures.
To examine whether passively managed mutual funds affect firms’ governance, and if so,
by which mechanisms, we exploit variation in passive institutional ownership that occurs around
the cutoff used to construct the Russell 1000 and Russell 2000 indexes. Benchmarking to these
indexes leads to about a 66% difference in passive ownership for stocks at the top of the Russell
2000 relative to stocks at the bottom of the Russell 1000. Thus, we instrument passive
institutional ownership with an indicator for being assigned to the Russell 2000 in a given year
and analyze the influence of passive investors in an economically important sample of large U.S.
publicly listed firms.
Our instrumental variable estimation relies on the assumption that after
conditioning on firms’ market capitalization, which determines index assignment, inclusion in
the Russell 2000 index does not directly affect our governance or corporate outcomes except
through its impact on ownership by passive investors.
Our findings suggest that while passive institutional investors are not active owners in the
traditional sense of accumulating or selling shares in a target company with the express purpose
of influencing management, they are not passive owners either. In particular, we find that
ownership by passively managed mutual funds is associated with more independent directors on
a board, fewer takeover defenses, and more equal voting rights, as captured by a firm being less
likely to have a dual class share structure. The observed differences in actual governance
structures suggest that passive institutions are attentive to firms’ corporate governance, and that
they use their large voting blocs to exercise voice and exert influence.
For example, we find that
higher passive ownership is associated with less support for management proposals and a greater
support for shareholder-initiated governance proposals. Engagement by passive investors also
appears to reduce the need for activism by other, non-passive investors; we find that companies
with greater passive ownership exhibit improvements in long-term performance and are less
likely to be targeted for activism by a hedge fund.
Our findings, however, do not resolve the ongoing debate regarding the value
implications of various governance structures, including board independence, takeover defenses,
and equal voting rights for shareholders, and whether the optimal governance structure may vary
across firms in ways that do not always conform to the proxy-voting guidelines of the largest
passive institutions. The findings also do not address whether passive investors attempt to
determine the individual governance needs of each company in their large portfolios or instead
follow a “check the box” approach to governance.
While some large passive investors do vary
their voting strategies across firms in ways that are not consistent with such a one-size-fits-all
approach to governance (e.g., see Davis and Kim, (2007)), additional analysis regarding these
questions would seem to be a promising direction for further research.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 26
. References
Admati, Anat R., and Paul Pfleiderer, 2009, The “Wall Street Walk” and shareholder activism:
Exit as a form of voice, Review of Financial Studies 22, 2645–2685.
Aggarwal, Reena, Isil Erel, Miguel Ferreira, and Pedro Matos, 2011, Does governance travel
around the world? Evidence from institutional investors, Journal of Financial Economics
100, 154–181.
Aghion, Philippe, John Van Reenen, and Luigi Zingales, 2013, Innovation and Institutional
Ownership, American Economic Review 103, 277–304.
Angrist, Joshua D., and Jörn-Steffen Pischke, 2009, Mostly harmless econometrics: An
empiricist’s companion, Princeton University Press, Princeton.
Back, Kerry, Tao Li, and Alexander Ljungqvist, 2014, Liquidity and governance, NBER
working paper 19669.
Bakke, Tor-Erik, and Toni M. Whited, 2012, Threshold events and identification: A study of
cash shortfalls, Journal of Finance 67, 1083–1111.
Bebchuk, Lucian, Alma Cohen, and Allen Ferrell, 2009, What matters in corporate governance?
Review of Financial Studies 22, 783–827.
Bhagat, Sanjai, and Bernard S. Black, 2002, The Non-Correlation Between Board Independence
and Long-Term Firm Performance, Journal of Corporation Law 27, 231–274.
Black, Bernard S., 1992, Agents watching agents: The promise of institutional investor voice,
UCLA Law Review 39, 811–893.
Black, Bernard S., 1998, Shareholder activism and corporate governance in the United States, in
Peter Newman, ed.: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law (Palgrave
Macmillan: New York, NY).
Boone, Audra L., and Joshua T. White, 2014, The effect of institutional ownership on firm
transparency and information production, forthcoming in Journal of Financial Economics.
Bradley, Michael, Alon Brav, Itay Goldstein, and Wei Jiang, 2010, Activist arbitrage: A study of
open-ending attempts of closed-end funds, Journal of Financial Economics 95, 1–19.
Brav, Alon, Wei Jiang, and Hyunseob Kim, 2010, Hedge fund activism: A review, Foundations
and Trends in Finance 4, 1–66.
Brav, Alon, Wei Jiang, Frank Partnoy, and Randall Thomas, 2008, Hedge fund activism,
corporate governance, and firm performance, Journal of Finance 63, 1729–1775.
Bushee, Brian J., 1998, The influence of institutional investors on myopic R&D investment
behavior, Accounting Review 73, 305–333.
Bushee, Brian J., 2001, Do institutional investors prefer near-term earnings over long-run value?
Contemporary Accounting Research 18, 207–246.
Busse, Jeffrey A., and Qing Tong, 2012, Mutual fund industry selection and persistence, Review
of Asset Pricing Studies 2, 245–274.
Carleton, William T., James M.
Nelson, and Michael S. Weisbach, 1998, The influence of
institutions on corporate governance through private negotiations: Evidence from TIAACREF, Journal,of Finance 53, 1335–1362.
Chang, Yen-Cheng, Harrison Hong, and Inessa Liskovich, 2014, Regression discontinuity and
the price effects of stock market indexing, Review of Financial Studies, forthcoming.
Chhaochharia, Vidhi, and Yaniv Grinstein, 2009, CEO compensation and board structure, The
Journal of Finance 64, 231–261.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 27
. Choi, Stephen, Jill Fisch, and Marcel Kahan, 2013, Who calls the shots? How mutual funds vote
on director elections, Harvard Business Law Review 3, 35–81.
Chung, Kee H., and Hao Zhang, 2011, Corporate governance and institutional ownership,
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 46, 247–273.
Coates IV, John C., 2000, Takeover defenses in the shadow of the pill: A critique of the
scientific evidence, Texas Law Review 79, 271–382.
Coles, Jeffrey L., Naveen D. Daniel, and Lalitha Naveen, 2008, Boards: Does one size fit all?
Journal of Financial Economics 87, 329–356.
Crane, Alan D., Sébastien Michenaud, and James P. Weston, 2014, The effect of institutional
ownership on payout policy: Evidence from index thresholds, working paper.
Cremers, K.J. Martijn, and Vinay B.
Nair, 2005, Governance mechanisms and equity prices,
Journal of Finance 60, 2859–894.
Daines, Robert, and Michael Klausner, 2001, Do IPO charters maximize firm value?
Antitakeover protection in IPOs, The Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 17,
83–120.
Davis, Gerald F., and E. Han Kim, 2007, Business ties and proxy voting by mutual funds,
Journal of Financial Economics 85, 552–570.
Del Guercio, Diane, and Jennifer Hawkins, 1999, The motivation and impact of pension fund
activism, Journal of Financial Economics 52, 293–340.
Duchin, Ran, John G. Matsusaka, and Oguzhan Ozbas, 2010, When are outside directors
effective? Journal of Financial Economics 96, 195–214.
Easterbrook, Frank H., and Daniel R.
Fischel, 1983, Voting in corporate law, Journal of Law and
Economics 26, 395–427.
Edmans, Alex, 2009, Blockholder trading, market efficiency, and managerial myopia, Journal of
Finance 64, 2481–2513.
Edmans, Alex, 2014, Blockholders and corporate governance, prepared for Annual Review of
Financial Economics.
Edmans, Alex, Vivian W. Fang, and Emmanuel Zur, 2013, The effect of liquidity on governance,
Review of Financial Studies 26, 1443–1482.
Edmans, Alex, and Gustavo Manso, 2011, Governance through trading and intervention: A
theory of multiple blockholders, Review of Financial Studies 24, 2395–2428.
Fama, Eugene F., and Michael C. Jensen, 1983, Separation of Ownership and Control, Journal of
Law and Economics 26, 301–325.
Fich, Eliezer M., Jarrad Harford, and Anh L.
Tran, 2015, Motivated monitors: the importance of
institutional investors’ portfolio weights, Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming.
Gillan, Stuart L., and Laura T. Starks, 2000, Corporate governance proposals and shareholder
activism: the role of institutional investors, Journal of Financial Economics 57, 275–305.
Gompers, Paul A., and Joy Ishii, and Andrew Metrick, 2010, Extreme governance: An analysis
of dual-class firms in the United States, Review of Financial Studies 23, 1051–1088.
Gormley, Todd A. and David A.
Matsa, 2014, Common errors: How to (and not to) control for
unobserved heterogeneity, Review of Financial Studies 27(2), 617–661.
Gormley, Todd A., David A. Matsa, and Todd Milbourn, 2013, CEO compensation and
corporate risk: Evidence from a natural experiment, Journal of Account and Economics
56, 79–101.
Grinstein, Yaniv, and Roni Michaely, 2005, Institutional holdings and payout policy, Journal of
Finance 60, 1389–1426.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 28
. Guo, Re-Jin, Timothy A. Kruse, and Tom Nohel, 2008, Undoing the powerful anti-takeover
force of staggered boards, Journal of Corporate Finance 14, 274 – 288.
Harris, Milton, and Arthur Raviv, 2010, Control of corporate decisions: Shareholders vs.
management, Review of Financial Studies 23, 4115–4157.
Hartzell, Jay C., and Laura T. Starks, 2003, Institutional investors and executive compensation,
Journal of Finance 58, 2351–2374.
Hermalin, Benjamin E., and Michael S. Weisbach, 1998, Endogenously chosen boards of
directors and their monitoring of the CEO, American Economic Review 88, 96–118.
Hermalin, Benjamin E., and Michael S.
Weisbach, 2003, Boards of directors as an endogenously
determined institution: A survey of the economic literature, Economic Policy Review 9,
7–26.
Iliev, Peter, and Michelle Lowry, 2015, Are mutual funds active voters? The Review of Financial
Studies 28, 446-485.
Investment Technology Group, 2008, 2008 Russell Reconstitution Recap.
Jensen, Michael C., 1986, Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance and takeovers,
American Economic Review 76, 323–329.
Klausner, Michael, 2012, Fact and fiction in corporate law and governance, Stanford Law
Review 65, 1325–1370.
Klein, April and Emmanuel Zur, 2009, Entrepreneurial shareholder activism: Hedge Funds and
other private investors, Journal of Finance 64, 187–229.
La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny, 2000,
Agency problems and dividend policies around the world, Journal of Finance 55, 1–33.
Levit, Doron, 2013, Soft shareholder activism, working paper.
Levit, Doron, and Nadya Malenko, 2011, Nonbinding voting and shareholder proposals, Journal
of Finance 66, 1579–1614.
Lu, Ruichang, 2013, How does institutional ownership affect bank loan pricing: Evidence from a
regression discontinuity design, working paper.
Maug, Ernst, 1998, Large shareholders as monitors: Is there a trade-off between liquidity and
control? Journal of Finance 53, 65–98.
McKinnish, T. 2008, Panel data models and transitory fluctuations in the explanatory variable, In
Modeling and evaluating treatment effect in econometrics, eds.
Daniel L. Millimet,
Jeffrey A. Smith, and Edward J.
Vytlacil, 334–58. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
McNabb, F. William III, 2014, Getting to know you: Sharing practical governance viewpoints,
University of Delaware, John Weinberg Center for Corporate Governance, speech on
October 30, 2014.
Michaely, Roni, Jillian Popadak, and Christopher Vincent, 2014, The deleveraging of U.S.
firms
and institutional investors’ role, working paper.
Mullins, William, 2014, The governance impact of index funds: Evidence from a regression
discontinuity, working paper.
Romano, Roberta, 1993, Public pension fund activism in corporate governance reconsidered,
Columbia Law Review 93, 795–853.
Russell Investments, 2013, Russell U.S. Equity Indexes Construction and Methodology.
Schmidt, Cornelius, 2012, Shareholding monitoring incentives and corporate policies, working
paper.
Shliefer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny, 1986, Large shareholders and corporate control, Journal
of Political Economy 94, 461–488.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 29
.
Sommer, Jeff, 2013, Challenging Management (but Not the Market), The New York Times,
March 16.
Stein, Jeremy C., 1988, Takeover Threats and Managerial Myopia, Journal of Political Economy
96, 61-80.
Stock, James H., Jonathan H. Wright, and Motohiro Yogo, 2002, A survey of weak instruments
and weak identification in generalized method of moments, Journal of Business &
Economics Statistics 20, 518–529.
The Economist, 2015, “Capitalism’s unlikely heroes: Why activist investors are good for the
public company,” February 7th.
Useem, Michael, Edward H. Bowman, Jennifer Myatt, and Craig W. Irvine, 1993, US
institutional investors look at corporate governance in the 1990s, European Management
Journal 11, 175–89.
Vanguard, 2014, Our views on corporate governance, https://about.vanguard.com/vanguardproxy-voting/corporate-governance/.
Weisbach, Michael S., 1988, Outside directors and CEO turnover, Journal of Financial
Economics 20, 431–460.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 30
.
35%
30%
%
of
equity
mutual
fund
assets
that
are
passively
managed
25%
20%
15%
10%
2014
2013
2012
2011
2010
2009
2008
2007
2006
2005
2004
2003
2002
2001
2000
1999
1998
5%
10.0%
8.0%
%
of
total
market
cap
held
by
passively
managed
funds
6.0%
4.0%
2.0%
2014
2013
2012
2011
2010
2009
2008
2007
2006
2005
2004
2003
2002
2001
2000
1999
1998
0.0%
Figure 1
Growth of passive investors, 1998-2014
This figure plots the estimated percent of all U.S. equity mutual fund assets under
management between 1998 and 2014 that are held in passively managed funds and the
estimated percent of total U.S. market capitalization held by passively managed mutual
funds. We construct the figure by matching the S12 mutual fund holdings data compiled
in the Thomson Reuters Mutual Fund Holdings Database to market caps reported in
CRSP and fund names in the CRSP Mutual Fund data.
We use a name-parsing procedure
along with the index fund identifier from the CRSP Mutual Fund File to classify mutual
funds as passively managed. Our procedure is described in the text.
Holdings and
market cap are calculated each year at the end of the third quarter.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 31
. Por$olio
weight
in
index
%
0.2
0.2
0.18
0.18
0.16
0.16
0.14
0.14
0.12
0.12
0.1
0.1
0.08
0.08
Bo2om
500
ï¬rms
within
Russell
1000
0.06
0.04
0.06
0.04
0.02
0
500
Top
500
ï¬rms
within
Russell
2000
0.02
0
600
700
800
Ranking
within
index
900
1000
0
100
200
300
400
500
Ranking
within
index
Figure 2
Portfolio weights in the Russell 1000 and 2000 indices by within-index ranking for the year 2006
This figure plots the portfolio weights of the bottom 500 firms in the Russell 1000 index and the top 500 firms in the Russell 2000
index for the end-of-June 2006. Observations are ordered by their within-index ranking such that rankings of 1 and 1000 represent
the firms with the largest and 1000th largest portfolio weight in the index, respectively. The portfolio weights are given as a percent.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 32
. Ac0ve
ownership
%
Ln(Market
capitaliza0on)
24
22
21
19
1
0.5
0
Passive
ownership
%
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
800
900
1000
21
15
9
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
800
900
1000
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
800
900
1000
0
Unclassiï¬ed
ownership
%
Frac0on
in
Russell
2000
0
27
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
800
900
1000
6
4
2
0
Figure 3
Market capitalization, index assignment, and ownership by market
capitalization rankings for the bottom 500 firms of Russell 1000
and top 500 firms of Russell 2000
4
3
2
1
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
800
900
1000
Ranking
based
on
end-â€of-â€May
market
capitaliza0on
This figure plots the average end-of-May Ln(market capitalization), fraction
of firm-year observations in the Russell 2000, and passive, active, and
unclassified mutual fund ownership (%) by ranking, where ranking is
determined using end-of-May market capitalization, as reported in CRSP.
The sample includes the bottom 500 firms of the Russell 1000 and the top 500
firms of the Russell 2000, as determined using end-of-June Russell-assigned
portfolio weights for each index. Mutual fund ownership is calculated as of
September each year, and all averages are calculated using bins of 10 firms
and data from 1998-2006. For the ownership panels, we scale the vertical
axis to report a standard deviation on each side of the sample mean.
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 33
. Table 1
Summary statistics
This table reports summary statistics of our key variables for our main sample:
firms in the 250 bandwidth around the cutoff between the Russell 1000 and
2000 indexes from 1998-2006. Definitions for all variables are provided in
Appendix Table 1. Accounting variables are winsorized at the 1% level, and
we delete observations where either mutual fund ownership is missing or total
mutual fund holdings exceed a stock's market capitalization.
Obs.
Total mutual fund ownership %
Passive ownership %
Active ownership %
Unclassified ownership %
Independent director %
Poison pill removal
Greater ability to call special meeting
Indicator for dual class shares
Mngt. proposal support %
Shareholder gov.
proposal support %
Indicator for hedge fund activism
ROA
Mean Median
4,415
4,415
4,415
4,415
2,871
2,957
1,858
1,858
1,288
202
4,415
4,291
25.2
3.0
18.9
3.2
65.1
0.04
0.006
0.13
84.7
36.3
0.016
0.03
25.0
2.6
18.1
2.5
66.7
0
0
0
87.2
31.5
0
0.04
SD
12.9
2.3
10.9
2.9
18.1
0.19
0.08
0.33
11.9
22.8
0.12
0.11
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 34
. Table 2
Impact of index assignment on mutual fund ownership
This table reports estimates of a regression of mutual fund holdings on an indicator for
membership in the Russell 2000 index plus additional controls. Specifically, we estimate
N
Ownership% it = η + λ R2000it + ∑ χ n ( Ln( Mktcapit )) + σ Ln( Float )it + δ t + u it
n
n=1
where R2000it is a dummy variable equal to 1 if stock i is in the Russell 2000 Index at end
of June in year t, Mktcapit is the CRSP market value of equity of stock i measured at May
31 in year t, N is the polynomial order we use to control for Ln(Mktcapit), Floatit is the
float-adjusted market value of equity (provided by Russell) at June 30 in year t, and δt are
year fixed effects. Ownership%it measures mutual fund ownership (in percent) for stock i
at the end of September in year t. In this table we use four different definitions for
Ownership% for stock i: (1) the percentage of shares outstanding owned by all mutual
funds (from S12 filings); (2) the percentage of shares outstanding owned by "passive"
funds; (3) the percentage of shares outstanding owned by “active” mutual funds; and (4)
the percentage of shares outstanding owned by “unclassified” mutual funds.
The mutual
fund classifications are defined in the text. The sample consists of the top 250 firms in the
Russell 2000 index and bottom 250 firms of the Russell 1000 index (i.e., bandwidth =
250) for which we obtain holdings data from Thomson Reuters Mutual Fund Holdings
Database and which we match with data from the monthly CRSP file. The model is
estimated over the 1998-2006 period using a polynomial order control for Ln(Mktcap) of
N = 3.
Standard errors, ε, are clustered at the firm level and reported in parentheses. The
symbols * and *** indicate significance at the 10% and 1% levels, respectively.
Percent of firm's common shares held by:
Dependent variable =
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
# of firms
Observations
R-squared
Passive
Active
Unclassified
(1)
R2000
All
mutual
funds
(2)
(3)
(4)
1.216*
(0.662)
1.086***
(0.067)
0.118
(0.604)
0.012
(0.135)
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
1,654
4,415
0.21
1,654
4,415
0.62
1,654
4,415
0.12
1,654
4,415
0.09
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 35
. Table 3
First stage estimation for ownership by passively managed funds
This table reports estimates of our first-stage regression of passive ownership
onto an indicator for membership in the Russell 2000 index plus additional
controls. Specifically, we estimate
N
Passive% it = η + λ R2000it + ∑ χ n ( Ln( Mktcapit )) + σ Ln( Float )it + δ t + u it
n
n=1
where R2000it is a dummy variable equal to 1 if stock i is in the Russell 2000
index at end of June in year t, Mktcapit is the CRSP market value of equity of
stock i measured at May 31 in year t, Floatit is the float-adjusted market
value of equity (provided by Russell) at June 30 in year t, and δt are year
fixed effects. Passive%it is the percentage of shares outstanding owned by
passively managed mutual funds, as defined in the text, for stock i at the end
of September in year t scaled by its sample standard deviation. The data
consist of firms in the two Russell indexes for which we obtain holdings data
from Thomson Reuters Mutual Fund Holdings Database and which we
match with data from the monthly CRSP file.
The model is estimated over
the 1998-2006 period using a bandwidth of 250 firms around the Russell
1000/2000 threshold, and polynomial order controls for Ln(Mktcap) of N =
1, 2, and 3. Standard errors, ε, are clustered at the firm level and reported in
parentheses. *** indicates significance at the 1% level.
Passive % scaled by its
sample standard deviation
Dependent variable =
(1)
R2000
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
# of firms
Observations
R-squared
(2)
(3)
0.505***
(0.028)
0.512***
(0.028)
0.473***
(0.029)
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
1,654
4,415
0.61
1,654
4,415
0.62
1,654
4,415
0.62
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 36
.
Table 4
Ownership by passive investors and board independence
This table reports estimates of our instrumental variable estimation used
to identify the effect of ownership by passive investors on board
independence. Specifically, we estimate
N
Yit = α + β Passive% it + ∑ θ n ( Ln( Mktcapit )) + γ Ln( Float )it + δ t + ε it
n
n=1
where Yit is the percentage of independent directors on the board of firm i
in year t (from Riskmetrics) scaled by its sample standard deviation,
Passive%it is the percentage of shares outstanding owned by passively
managed funds (as defined in the text) for stock i at the end of September
in year t scaled by its sample standard deviation, Mktcapit is the CRSP
market value of equity of stock i measured at May 31 in year t, and
Floatit is the float-adjusted market value of equity (provided by Russell)
at June 30 in year t, and δt are year fixed effects. We instrument
Passive% in the above estimation using R2000it, an indicator equal to
one if firm i is part of the Russell 2000 index in year t. The data consist
of firms in the two Russell indexes for which we obtain holdings data
from Thomson Reuters Mutual Fund Holdings Database and which we
match with data from the monthly CRSP file.
The model is estimated
over the 1998-2006 period using 250 firms around the Russell
1000/2000 threshold, and polynomial order controls for Ln(Mktcap) of N
= 1, 2, and 3. Standard errors, ε, are clustered at the firm level and
reported in parentheses. *** indicates significance at the 1% level.
Dependent variable =
Independent director %
(1)
Passive %
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
# of firms
Observations
(2)
(3)
0.729***
(0.160)
0.762***
(0.162)
0.654***
(0.159)
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
1,082
2,871
1,082
2,871
1,082
2,871
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 37
.
Table 5
Passive ownership and board independence, pre- versus post-2002 rule change
This table reports estimates of the second-stage regression of our instrumental variable
estimation used to identify the effect of passive investors on the percentage of independent board
directors both before and after the 2002 change in exchange-listing requirements regarding board
independence. The estimation is the same as in Table 4, except we now separately estimate the
model over the 1998-2002 and 2003-2006 time periods using a bandwidth of 250 firms around
the Russell 1000/2000 threshold, and polynomial order controls for Ln(Mktcap) of N = 1, 2, and
3. Both the dependent variable and Passive% are scaled by their sample standard deviations.
Standard errors, ε, are clustered at the firm level and reported in parentheses. The symbols *, **,
and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Dependent variable =
Independent director %
Sample years = 1998-2002
(1)
Passive %
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
# of firms
Observations
(2)
(3)
1.314*** 1.461*** 1.257***
(0.298) (0.303) (0.297)
Sample years = 2003-2006
(4)
(5)
0.354*** 0.324**
(0.136) (0.137)
(6)
0.264*
(0.160)
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
882
1,682
882
1,682
882
1,682
549
1,189
549
1,189
549
1,189
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 38
.
Table 6
Ownership by passive investors and takeover defenses
This table reports estimates of our instrumental variable estimation used to identify the effect of
institutional ownership by passive investors on takeover defense outcomes. Specifically, we estimate
N
Yit = α + β Passive% it + ∑ θ n ( Ln( Mktcapit )) + γ Ln( Float )it + δ t + ε it
n
n=1
where Yit is the governance variable for firm i in year t scaled by its sample standard deviation,
Passive%it is the percentage of shares outstanding owned by passively managed mutual funds (as
defined in the text) for stock i at the end of September in year t scaled by its sample standard deviation,
Mktcapit is the CRSP market value of equity of stock i measured at May 31 in year t, and Floatit is the
float-adjusted market value of equity (provided by Russell) at June 30 in year t, and δt are year fixed
effects. The governance variables investigated in this table, from Shark Repellent (Factset) and
Riskmetrics, are: an indicator for either the withdrawal or expiration (without renewal) of a poison pill
in year t, and an indicator for there being fewer restrictions on shareholders' ability to call a special
meeting in year t. We instrument Passive% in the above estimation using R2000it, an indicator equal
to one if firm i is part of the Russell 2000 index in year t.
The data consist of firms in the two Russell
indexes for which we obtain holdings data from Thomson Reuters Mutual Fund Holdings Database
and which we match with data from the monthly CRSP file. The model is estimated over the 19982006 period using a bandwidth of 250 firms around the Russell 1000/2000 threshold and first, second,
and third polynomial order controls for Ln(Mktcap). Standard errors, ε, are clustered at the firm level
and reported in parentheses.
*** indicates significance at the 1% levels.
Dependent variable =
(1)
Passive %
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
# of firms
Observations
Greater ability to
call special meeting
Poison pill removal
(2)
(3)
0.176*** 0.181*** 0.203***
(0.0647) (0.0650) (0.0741)
(4)
(5)
(6)
0.304*** 0.310*** 0.341***
(0.0999) (0.108)
(0.114)
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
1,164
2,957
1,164
2,957
1,164
2,957
1,050
1,858
1,050
1,858
1,050
1,858
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 39
. Table 7
Ownership by passive investors and dual class share structures
This table reports estimates of our instrumental variable estimation used to
identify the effect of passive investors on the likelihood of dual class
shares. Specifically, we estimate
N
Yit = α + β Passive% it + ∑ θ n ( Ln( Mktcapit )) + γ Ln( Float )it + δ t + ε it
n
n=1
where Yit is an indicator equal to 1 if firm i has dual class shares in year t
according to Riskmetrics scaled by its sample standard deviation,
Passive%it is the percentage of shares outstanding owned by passively
managed mutual funds (as defined in the text) for stock i at the end of
September in year t scaled by its sample standard deviation, Mktcapit is the
CRSP market value of equity of stock i measured at May 31 in year t, and
Floatit is the float-adjusted market value of equity (provided by Russell) at
June 30 in year t, and δt are year fixed effects. We instrument Passive% in
the above estimation using R2000it, an indicator equal to one if firm i is
part of the Russell 2000 index in year t. The data consist of firms in the
two Russell indexes for which we obtain holdings data from Thomson
Reuters Mutual Fund Holdings Database and which we match with data
from the monthly CRSP file.
The model is estimated over the 1998-2006
period using a bandwidth of 250 firms around the Russell 1000/2000
threshold, and polynomial order controls for Ln(Mktcap) of N = 1, 2, and
3. Standard errors, ε, are clustered at the firm level and reported in
parentheses. *** indicates significance at the 1% level.
Dependent variable =
Indicator for dual class shares
(1)
Passive %
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
# of firms
Observations
(2)
(3)
-0.886***
(0.179)
-1.031***
(0.167)
-1.005***
(0.181)
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
1,050
1,858
1,050
1,858
1,050
1,858
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 40
.
Table 8
Ownership by passive investors and shareholder support for proposals
This table reports estimates of our instrumental variable estimation to identify the effect of
passive investors on shareholder support for management proposals and shareholder-initiated
governance proposals. Specifically, we estimate
N
Yit = α + β Passive% it + ∑ θ n ( Ln( Mktcapit )) + γ Ln( Float )it + δ t + ε it
n
n=1
where Yit is either the average percentage of shareholders that vote along with management
proposals at annual meetings for i in year t (from Riskmetrics) or the average percentage of
shareholders that vote in support of a shareholder-initiated governance proposal for firm i in
year t (from Riskmetrics) each scaled by their sample standard deviation, Passive%it is the
percentage of shares outstanding owned by passively managed mutual funds (as defined in the
text) for stock i at the end of September in year t scaled by its sample standard deviation,
Mktcapit is the CRSP market value of equity of stock i measured at May 31 in year t, and Floatit
is the float-adjusted market value of equity (provided by Russell) at June 30 in year t, and δt are
year fixed effects. We instrument Passive% in the above estimation using R2000it, an indicator
equal to one if firm i is part of the Russell 2000 index in year t. The data consist of firms in the
two Russell indexes for which we obtain holdings data from Thomson Reuters Mutual Fund
Holdings Database and which we match with data from the monthly CRSP file.
The model is
estimated over the 1998-2006 period using a bandwidth of 250 firms around the Russell
1000/2000 threshold, and polynomial order controls for Ln(Mktcap) of N = 1, 2, and 3.
Standard errors, ε, are clustered at the firm level and reported in parentheses. The symbols *,
**, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Dependent variable =
Management
proposal support %
(1)
Passive %
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
# of firms
Observations
(2)
(3)
-0.783***-0.745***-0.734***
(0.180) (0.179) (0.231)
Governance
proposal support %
(4)
(5)
(6)
0.492**
(0.247)
0.649*
(0.348)
0.622*
(0.336)
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
775
1,288
775
1,288
775
1,288
127
202
127
202
127
202
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 41
. Table 9
Ownership by passive investors and hedge fund activism
This table reports estimates of our instrumental variable estimation used to
identify the effect of ownership by passive investors on the likelihood of hedge
fund activism. Specifically, we estimate
N
Yit = α + β Passive% it + ∑ θ n ( Ln( Mktcapit )) + γ Ln( Float )it + δ t + ε it
n
n=1
where Yit is an indicator equal to 1 if firm i experiences a hedge fund activism
event in year t, as defined in Brav, Jiang, Partnoy, and Thomas (2008) and Brav,
Jiang, and Kim (2010), scaled by its sample standard deviation, Passive%it is the
percentage of shares outstanding owned by passively managed mutual funds (as
defined in the text) for stock i at the end of September in year t scaled by its
sample standard deviation, Mktcapit is the CRSP market value of equity of stock i
measured at May 31 in year t, and Floatit is the float-adjusted market value of
equity (provided by Russell) at June 30 in year t, and δt are year fixed effects. We
instrument Passive% in the above estimation using R2000it, an indicator equal to
one if firm i is part of the Russell 2000 index in year t. The data consist of firms
in the two Russell indexes for which we obtain holdings data from Thomson
Reuters Mutual Fund Holdings Database and which we match with data from the
monthly CRSP file.
The model is estimated over the 1998-2006 period using a
bandwidth of 250 firms around the Russell 1000/2000 threshold, and polynomial
order controls for Ln(Mktcap) of N = 1, 2, and 3. Standard errors, ε, are clustered
at the firm level and reported in parentheses. The symbols * and ** indicate
significance at the 10% and 5% levels, respectively.
Dependent variable =
Indicator for hedge fund activism event
(1)
Passive %
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
# of firms
Observations
(2)
(3)
-0.131*
(0.0721)
-0.130*
(0.0718)
-0.162**
(0.0805)
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
1,654
4,415
1,654
4,415
1,654
4,415
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 42
.
Table 10
Ownership by passive investors and firms' return on assets
This table reports estimates of our instrumental variable estimation used to identify the effect
of ownership by passive institutional investors on firms' performance, as measured using
firms' return on assets (ROA). Specifically, we estimate
N
Yit = α + β Passive% it + ∑ θ n ( Ln( Mktcapit )) + γ Ln( Float )it + δ t + ε it
n
n=1
where Yit is the ROA for firm i in year t scaled by its sample standard deviation, Passive%it is
the percentage of shares outstanding owned by passively managed mutual funds (as defined
in the text) for stock i at the end of September in year t scaled by its sample standard
deviation, Mktcapit is the CRSP market value of equity of stock i measured at May 31 in year
t, and Floatit is the float-adjusted market value of equity (provided by Russell) at June 30 in
year t, and δt are year fixed effects. We instrument Passive% in the above estimation using
R2000it, an indicator equal to one if firm i is part of the Russell 2000 index in year t. The
specification in columns (1)-(3) are the same as in earlier tables, but in columns (4)-(6), we
add two additional controls to the specification: an indicator that equals one for firms that are
in the Russell 2000 index in year t but were in the Russell 1000 in year t-1, and an indicator
that equals one for firms that are in the Russell 1000 index in year t but were in the Russell
2000 index in year t-1.
The data consist of firms in the two Russell indexes for which we
obtain holdings data from Thomson Reuters Mutual Fund Holdings Database and which we
match with data from the monthly CRSP file. The model is estimated over the 1998-2006
period using a bandwidth of 250 firms around the Russell 1000/2000 threshold and first,
second, and third polynomial order controls for Ln(Mktcap). Standard errors, ε, are clustered
at the firm level and reported in parentheses.
*** indicates significance at the 1% level.
Dependent variable =
ROA
(1)
Passive %
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
Controls for movers
# of firms
Observations
(2)
(3)
-0.028 -0.015 0.035
(0.098) (0.093) (0.105)
(4)
(5)
(6)
0.304*** 0.310*** 0.414***
(0.111) (0.106) (0.121)
250
1
yes
yes
no
250
2
yes
yes
no
250
3
yes
yes
no
250
1
yes
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
1,600
4,291
1,600
4,291
1,600
4,291
1,600
4,291
1,600
4,291
1,600
4,291
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 43
. Table 11
Impact of index assignment on institution-level (13F) stock ownership
This table reports estimates of our first-stage regression of institutional holdings on
an indicator for membership in the Russell 2000 index plus additional controls.
Specifically, we estimate
N
Ownership% it = η + λ R2000it + ∑ χ n ( Ln( Mktcapit )) + σ Ln( Float )it + δ t + u it
n
n=1
where R2000it is a dummy variable equal to 1 if stock i is in the Russell 2000 index at
end of June in year t, Mktcapit is the CRSP market value of equity of stock i
measured at May 31 in year t, N is the polynomial order we use to control for
Ln(Mktcapit), Floatit is the float-adjusted market value of equity (provided by
Russell) at June 30 in year t, and δt are year fixed effects. Ownership%it measures
institution-level (13F) ownership (in percent) for stock i at the end of September in
year t. In this table we use four different definitions for Ownership% for stock i: (1)
the percentage of shares outstanding owned by all institutional investors; (2) the
percentage of shares outstanding owned by "quasi-index" institutions, as classified by
Bushee (2001); (3) the percentage of shares outstanding owned by "dedicated"
institutions as classified by Bushee; and (4) the percentage of shares outstanding
owned by “transient” institutions as classified by Bushee. The Bushee classifications
are defined in the text.
The sample consists of the top 250 firms in the Russell 2000
index and bottom 250 firms of the Russell 1000 index (i.e., bandwidth = 250) for
which we obtain holdings data from Thomson Reuters Institutional Holdings (13F)
Database and which we match with data from the monthly CRSP file. The model is
estimated over the 1998-2006 period using a polynomial order control for
Ln(Mktcap) of N = 3. Standard errors, ε, are clustered at the firm level and reported
in parentheses.
*** indicates significance at the 1% level.
Percent of firm's common shares held by:
Dependent variable =
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
# of firms
Observations
R-squared
Quasiindex
Dedicated
Transient
(1)
R2000
All
Institutions
(2)
(3)
(4)
1.354
(1.517)
2.381***
(0.748)
-0.539
(0.891)
-0.445
(0.845)
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
1,633
4,357
0.24
1,633
4,357
0.26
1,633
4,357
0.02
1,633
4,357
0.09
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 44
. Table 12
Robustness of IV estimates to using passive indicator based on institution-level (13F) stock ownership
This table reports estimates of the second-stage regression of our instrumental variable estimation to identify the effect of institutional
ownership by passive investors on our governance and corporate outcome variables where passive ownership is measured using the
percentage of stock held by "quasi-index" institutions, as classified by Bushee (2001) and defined in the text. The estimation and outcomes
are the same as in Tables 4-10, except Passive% is replaced by Quasi-index%, the share of market cap held by quasi-index institutions
scaled by its sample standard deviation. The model is estimated over the 1998-2006 period using a bandwidth of 250 firms around the
Russell 1000/2000 threshold and a third polynomial order control for Ln(Mktcap). To demonstrate the robustness of the association
between passive ownership and longer-term performance, we include the additional controls for recent movers, used in columns 4-6 of
Table 10, when analyzing ROA (column 8).
Standard errors, ε, are clustered at the firm level and reported in parentheses. The symbols *,
**, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Quasi-index %
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
# of firms
Observations
Poison pill
removal
(1)
Dep. variable =
Ind.
directors
%
Ability to
Mngt.
Ind.
for dual
call special
proposal
class shares
meeting
support %
Gov.
proposal
support %
HF activism
event
ROA
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
1.197***
(0.388)
0.885*
(0.479)
0.958**
(0.473)
-2.866**
(1.170)
-1.148**
(0.516)
1.297*
(0.680)
-0.580*
(0.336)
1.803**
(0.899)
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
1,073
2,840
1,160
2,940
1,047
1,847
1,047
1,847
768
1,279
125
200
1,633
4,357
1,586
4,246
Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 45
. Appendix for
“Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners”
. IX. Appendix – Excerpts from Fund Governance/Voting Policies
In this appendix, we provide excerpts from the historical voting policies of various
institutional investors that offer index-related investment products. These proxy-voting policies
were all obtained from fund prospectuses issued in late 2003 and early 2004 shortly after the
SEC first required the filing of such voting policies on July 1, 2003. Four common themes of
these governance/voting policies are (1) to withhold support or vote against boards that are not
sufficiently independent, (2) broadly oppose takeover defenses, like poison pills, restrictions on
shareholders’ ability to call a special meeting, and classified boards, (3) oppose unequal voting
rights (i.e., dual class share structures), and (4) push for executive compensation that is tied to
performance but not excessive.
A.
iShares: Proxy Voting Guidelines31
“The Company has adopted as its proxy voting policies the proxy voting guidelines of BGFA
[Barclays Global Fund Advisors], the investment advisor to each Fund. The Company has
delegated to BGFA the responsibility for voting proxies on the portfolio securities held by each
Fund. Therefore, the remainder of this section discusses BGFA’s proxy voting guidelines…
When voting proxies, BGFA attempts to ensure that companies follow practices that advance
their economic value and allow the market to place a proper value on their assets.
With respect to
certain specific issues:
•
•
•
BGFA generally supports management in the election of directors and generally supports
proposals that strengthen the independence of boards of directors;
BGFA generally does not support proposals on social issues that lack a demonstrable
economic benefit to the issuer and the Fund investing in such issuer; and
BGFA generally votes against anti-takeover proposals and proposals which would create
additional barriers or costs to corporate transactions.”
B. State Street Global Advisors: Proxy Voting Policies and Procedures32
“For most issues and in most circumstances, we abide by the following general guidelines…
FM votes in support of management on the following ballot items…
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
Elimination of cumulative voting…
Capitalization changes which eliminate other classes of stock and voting rights…
Elimination of pre-emptive rights for share issuance of less than a given percentage
(country specific - ranging from 5% to 20%) of the outstanding shares
Elimination of "poison pill" rights…
Stock option plans which are incentive based and not excessive
Other stock-based plans which are appropriately structured
Reductions in super-majority vote requirements…
31
32
http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/930667/000119312503100400/d485bpos.txt
http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/826686/000104746904004745/a2128691z485bpos.txt
Appendix for Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 1
. FM votes against management on the following items…
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
Capitalization changes that add "blank check" classes of stock or classes that dilute the
voting interests of existing shareholders…
Anti-takeover and related provisions that serve to prevent the majority of shareholders
from exercising their rights or effectively deter appropriate tender offers and other offers
Amendments to bylaws which would require super-majority shareholder votes to pass or
repeal certain provisions
Elimination of Shareholders' Right to Call Special Meetings
Establishment of classified boards of directors…
Shareholder rights plans that allow the board of directors to block appropriate offers to
shareholders or which trigger provisions preventing legitimate offers from proceeding
Excessive compensation…
Proposals requesting re-election of insiders or affiliated directors who serve on audit,
compensation, and nominating committees…
FM votes in support of shareholders on the following ballot items…
•
•
•
•
•
Establishment of an annual election of the board of directors
Mandates requiring a majority of independent directors on the Board of Directors and the
audit, nominating, and compensation committees…
Mandates that shareholder-rights plans be put to a vote or repealed…
Repeals of various anti-takeover related provisions
Reduction or elimination of super-majority vote requirements…”
C. Vanguard: Proxy Voting Guidelines33
“The Board of Trustees (the Board) of each Vanguard fund that invests in stocks has adopted
proxy voting procedures and guidelines to govern proxy voting by the fund. The Board has
delegated day-to-day oversight of proxy voting to the Proxy Oversight Committee (the
Committee), comprised of senior Vanguard officers and subject to the operating procedures and
guidelines described below…
I. THE BOARD OF DIRECTORS
A.
ELECTION OF DIRECTORS
We believe that good governance starts with a majority-independent board, whose key
committees are comprised entirely of independent directors. As such, companies should
attest to the independence of directors who serve on the Compensation, Nominating and
Audit committees…
33
http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/105563/000093247104000415/wellington485b032004.txt
Appendix for Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 2
. We will generally support proposals to declassify existing boards (whether proposed by
management or shareholders), and will block efforts by companies to adopt classified board
structures, in which only part of the board is elected each year.
II. APPROVAL OF INDEPENDENT AUDITORS
We believe that the relationship between the company and its auditors should be limited
primarily to the audit, although it may include certain closely related activities that do not, in
the aggregate, raise any appearance of impaired independence. We will generally support
management's recommendation for the ratification of the auditor, except in instances where
audit and audit-related fees make up less than 50% of the total fees paid by the company to
the audit firm. We will evaluate on a case-by-case basis instances in which the audit firm has
a substantial non-audit relationship with the company (regardless of its size relative to the
audit fee) to determine whether we believe independence has been compromised.
III.
COMPENSATION ISSUES
A. STOCK-BASED COMPENSATION PLANS
We believe that appropriately designed stock-based compensation plans, administered by
an independent committee of the board and approved by shareholders, can be an effective
way to align the interests of long-term shareholders and the interests of management,
employees, and directors. Conversely, we oppose plans that substantially dilute our
ownership interest in the company, provide participants with excessive awards, or have
inherently objectionable structural features…
IV.
CORPORATE STRUCTURE AND SHAREHOLDER RIGHTS
We believe the exercise of shareholder rights, in proportion to economic ownership, to be a
fundamental privilege of stock ownership that should not be unnecessarily limited. Such
limits may be placed on shareholders' ability to act by corporate charter or by-law provisions,
or by the adoption of certain takeover provisions. We believe that, in general, the market for
corporate control should be allowed to function without undue interference from these
artificial barriers.
Our positions on a number of the most commonly presented issues in this area are as follows:
A.
SHAREHOLDER RIGHTS PLANS (POISON PILLS)
A company's adoption of a so-called poison pill effectively limits a potential acquirer's
ability to buy a controlling interest without the approval of the target's board of directors.
Such a plan, in conjunction with other takeover defenses, may serve to entrench
incumbent management and directors…
B. CUMULATIVE VOTING
Appendix for Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 3
. We are generally opposed to cumulative voting under the premise that it allows
shareholders a voice in director elections that is disproportionate to their economic
investment in the corporation.
C. SUPERMAJORITY VOTE REQUIREMENTS
We support shareholders' ability to approve or reject matters presented for a vote based
on a simple majority. Accordingly, we will support proposals to remove supermajority
requirements and oppose proposals to impose them.
D. RIGHT TO CALL MEETINGS AND ACT BY WRITTEN CONSENT
We support shareholders' right to call special meetings of the board (for good cause and
with ample representation) and to act by written consent.
We will generally vote for
proposals to grant these rights to shareholders and against proposals to abridge them.
E. CONFIDENTIAL VOTING
We believe that the integrity of the voting process is enhanced substantially when
shareholders (both institutions and individuals) can vote without fear of coercion or
retribution based on their votes. As such, we support proposals to provide confidential
voting.
F.
DUAL CLASSES OF STOCK
We are opposed to dual class capitalization structures that provide disparate voting rights
to different groups of shareholders with similar economic investments. As such, we will
oppose the creation of separate classes with different voting rights and will support the
dissolution of such classes.
V. CORPORATE AND SOCIAL POLICY ISSUES
Proposals in this category, initiated primarily by shareholders, typically request that the company
disclose or amend certain business practices.
We generally believe that these are "ordinary
business matters" that are primarily the responsibility of management and should be evaluated
and approved solely by the corporation's board of directors. Often, proposals may address
concerns with which we philosophically agree, but absent a compelling economic impact on
shareholder value (e.g., proposals to require expensing of stock options), we will typically
abstain from voting on these proposals. This reflects our belief that regardless of our
philosophical perspective on the issue, these decisions should be the province of company
management unless they have a significant, tangible impact on the value of our investment and,
we don't view management as responsive to the matter.”
Appendix for Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 4
.
0.7
First
Stage
1.6
0.6
1.2
0.5
0.8
0.4
0.4
0.3
Independent
Directors
%
0
1
Greater
Ability
to
Call
Spec.
Meet.
0
0.6
Poison
Pill
Removal
BW
0.4
0.2
0
Dual
Class
Shares
Indicator
0
0.75
-â€0.5
-â€0.5
0.5
-â€1
-â€1
0.25
-â€1.5
-â€1.5
0
-â€2
Management
Prop.
Support
%
-â€2
Governance
Proposal
Support
%
Hedge
Fund
AcOvism
Indicator
2
0.2
1
1.5
0
0.75
-â€0.2
0.5
-â€0.4
ROA
0.25
1
0.5
0
-â€0.5
500
450
400
350
300
250
200
150
100
-â€0.6
500
450
400
350
300
250
200
150
100
0
500
450
400
350
300
250
200
150
100
Appendix Figure 1
First stage and IV point estimates in the 100 through 500 bandwidths around Russell 1000/2000 threshold
This figure plots the point estimate and 95th percentile confidence intervals by bandwidth choice for the outcomes reported in Tables
3-10. The first stage and IV estimations are the same as in Tables 3-10 except the bandwidth is varied between 100 and 500 firms
around the Russell 1000/2000 threshold. A third-order polynomial control for Ln(Mktcap) is included in all estimations.
Appendix for Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 5
500
499
498
497
496
495
494
493
492
491
490
489
488
487
486
485
484
483
482
481
480
479
478
477
476
475
474
473
472
471
. Appendix Table 1
Variable definitions
Variable Name
Source
Definition
R2000
Mutual fund ownership %
Passive %
Active %
Unclassified %
Independent director %
Poison pill removal
Greater ability to call spec. meet.
Indicator for dual class shares
Mngt. proposal support %
Shareholder gov. prop.
support %
Indicator for hedge fund activism
ROA
Institutional ownership %
Quasi-index %
Dedicated %
Transient %
Russell Investments
Thomson Reuters S12 files
Thomson Reuters S12 files
Thomson Reuters S12 files
Thomson Reuters S12 files
Riskmetrics (Directors)
Shark Repellent (FactSet)
Riskmetrics (Governance)
Riskmetrics (Governance)
Riskmetrics (Voting Results)
Riskmetrics (Voting Results)
Brav, Jiang, and Kim (2010)
Compustat
Thomson Reuters 13F files
Brian Bushee website
Brian Bushee website
Brian Bushee website
Indicator equal to 1 if firm is in the Russell 2000
% of shares outstanding held by mutual funds in September of year t
% of shares outstanding held in September of year t by passively managed funds
% of shares outstanding held in September of year t by actively managed funds
% of shares outstanding held in September of year t by unclassified funds
% of board seats held by directors classified as independent by Riskmetrics
Indicator equal to 1 if poison pill is withdrawn or allowed to expire at time t
Indicator equal to 1 if shareholders better able to call a special meeting at time t
Indicator equal to 1 if a firm has dual class shares at time t
Percentage of 'Yes" votes for management proposals
Percentage of 'Yes" votes for sharehold governance proposals
Indicator equal to 1 if a firm has an activism event at time t
Net income (ni) / total assets (at)
% of shares outstanding held by institutional investors in September of year t
% of shares outstanding held by quasi-indexer institutions in September of year t
% of shares outstanding held by dedicated insitutions in September of year t
% of shares outstanding held by transient insitutions in September of year t
Appendix for Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 6
. Appendix Table 2
First stage estimation for ownership by actively managed and unclassified mutual funds
This table reports estimates of our first-stage regression of ownership by actively managed and
unclassified mutual funds onto an indicator for membership in the Russell 2000 index plus additional
controls over the 1998-2006 sample period. The specification is the same as in Table 3, except that the
dependent variable in columns (1)-(3) is now Active%it, which is the percentage of shares outstanding
owned by actively managed mutual funds for stock i at the end of September in year t scaled by its
sample standard deviation, and the dependent variable in columns (4)-(6) is now Unclassified%it, which
is the percentage of shares outstanding owned by unclassified mutual funds for stock i at the end of
September in year t scaled by its sample standard deviation. Both Active% and Unclassified% are
defined in the text. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level and reported in parentheses.
Dependent variable =
Active % scaled by its
sample standard deviation
Unclassified % scaled by its
sample standard deviation
(1)
R2000
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
# of firms
Observations
R-squared
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
0.055
(0.055)
0.049
(0.054)
0.011
(0.056)
0.028
(0.047)
0.020
(0.046)
0.004
(0.047)
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
1,654
4,415
0.12
1,654
4,415
0.12
1,654
4,415
0.12
1,654
4,415
0.08
1,654
4,415
0.09
1,654
4,415
0.09
Appendix for Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 7
.
Appendix Table 3A
First-stage estimation for Tables 4, 6, and 7
This table reports estimates of our first-stage regression of passive ownership onto an indicator for membership in the Russell 2000 index plus
additional controls over the 1998-2006 sample period. The specification is the same as in Table 3, but we now restrict our sample to the
smaller subsample of observations with non-missing Riskmetrics (Directors) data on board independence, non-missing Shark Repellent
(FactSet) data on poison pills, or non-missing Riskmetrics (Governance) data on shareholders' ability to call special meetings and dual class
share structures. Specifically, these are the first-stage estimates for the IV estimates reported in Tables 4, 6, and 7. Standard errors are clustered
at the firm level and reported in parentheses.
*** indicates significance at the 1% level.
Dependent variable =
Passive % scaled by its sample standard deviation
(1)
R2000
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
1st stage estimate for…
# of firms
Observations
R-squared
(2)
(3)
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
0.423***
(0.031)
0.428***
(0.031)
0.412***
(0.030)
0.624***
(0.040)
0.628***
(0.041)
0.596***
(0.046)
0.551***
(0.046)
0.536***
(0.046)
0.510***
(0.043)
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
Table 4,
Col. (1)
Table 4,
Col. (2)
Table 4,
Col.
(3)
Table 6,
Col. (1)
Table 6,
Col. (2)
Table 6,
Col.
(3)
1,082
2,871
0.74
1,082
2,871
0.74
1,082
2,871
0.74
1,164
2,957
0.50
1,164
2,957
0.50
1,164
2,957
0.50
Table 6,
Table 6,
Table 6,
Col. (4) & Col. (5) & Col.
(6) &
Table 7,
Table 7,
Table 7,
Col. (1)
Col. (2)
Col.
(3)
1,050
1,858
0.67
1,050
1,858
0.67
1,050
1,858
0.67
Appendix for Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 8
. Appendix Table 3B
First-stage estimation for Table 8
This table reports estimates of our first-stage regression of passive ownership onto an indicator for membership in the
Russell 2000 index plus additional controls over the 1998-2006 sample period. The specification is the same as in
Table 3, but we now restrict our sample to the smaller subsample of observations with non-missing Riskmetrics
(Voting Results) data on % support for management proposals and shareholder-intitiated governance proposals.
Specifically, these are the first-stage estimates for the IV estimates reported in Table 8. Standard errors are clustered at
the firm level and reported in parentheses. *** indicates significance at the 1% level.
Dependent variable =
Passive % scaled by its sample standard deviation
(1)
R2000
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
1st stage estimate for…
# of firms
Observations
R-squared
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
0.420***
(0.036)
0.415***
(0.036)
0.373***
(0.041)
0.774***
(0.198)
0.696***
(0.231)
0.754***
(0.232)
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
1
yes
yes
250
2
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
Table 8,
Table 8,
Table 8,
Table 8,
Table 8,
Table 8,
Column (1) Column (2) Column (3) Column (4) Column (5) Column (6)
775
1,288
0.74
775
1,287
0.74
775
1,287
0.74
127
202
0.59
127
202
0.60
127
202
0.61
Appendix for Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 9
.
Appendix Table 4
Robustness of findings to using Russell-provided market capitalization
This table reports estimates of the second-stage regression of our instrumental variable estimation to identify the effect of institutional
ownership by passive investors on our governance and corporate outcome variables when we instead measure end-of-May market caps
using Russell-provided market caps for the years 2002-2006. The estimation and outcomes are the same as in Tables 4-10, except Mktcapit
is the Russell-provided end-of-May market cap of stock i in year t, except when it is missing (i.e., years 1998-2001), in which case, we use
the CRSP market value of equity of stock i measured at May 31 in year t. We instrument Passive% using R2000it, an indicator equal to one
if firm i is part of the Russell 2000 index in year t. The model is estimated over the 1998-2006 period using a bandwidth of 250 firms
around the Russell 1000/2000 threshold and a third polynomial order control for Ln(Mktcap).
To demonstrate the robustness of the
association between passive ownership and longer-term performance, we include the additional controls for recent movers, used in
columns 4-6 of Table 10, when analyzing ROA (column 8). Standard errors, ε, are clustered at the firm level and reported in parentheses.
The symbols *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Passive %
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
# of firms
Observations
Poison pill
removal
(1)
Dep. variable =
Ind.
directors
%
Ability to
Mngt.
Ind.
for dual
call special
proposal
class shares
meeting
support %
Gov.
proposal
support %
HF activism
event
ROA
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
0.487***
(0.147)
0.194**
(0.095)
0.387***
(0.135)
-0.482**
(0.187)
-0.694***
(0.237)
0.287
(0.340)
-0.156*
(0.0891)
0.540***
(0.133)
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
1,082
2,871
1,164
2,957
1,050
1,858
1,050
1,858
775
1,288
127
202
1,654
4,415
1,600
4,291
Appendix for Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 10
. Appendix Table 5
Robustness of findings to using Compustat market capitalization
This table reports estimates of the second-stage regression of our instrumental variable estimation to identify the effect of institutional
ownership by passive investors on our governance and corporate outcome variables when we instead measure end-of-May market
caps using Compustat The estimation and outcomes are the same as in Tables 4-10, except that Mktcapit is the the Compustat market
value of equity of stock i measured at May 31 in year t. We instrument Passive% using R2000it, an indicator equal to one if firm i is
part of the Russell 2000 index in year t. The model is estimated over the 1998-2006 period using a bandwidth of 250 firms around
the Russell 1000/2000 threshold and a third polynomial order control for Ln(Mktcap). To demonstrate the robustness of the
association between passive ownership and longer-term performance, we include the additional controls for recent movers, used in
columns 4-6 of Table 10, when analyzing ROA (column 8).
Standard errors, ε, are clustered at the firm level and reported in
parentheses. The symbols *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Dependent variable =
Ind.
directors
%
Ability to
Poison pill
call special
removal
meeting
Ind. for
dual class
shares
(1)
Passive %
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
# of firms
Observations
(2)
(3)
(4)
0.650***
(0.169)
0.176**
(0.073)
0.299***
(0.112)
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
1,024
2,739
1,085
2,791
992
1,764
992
1,764
Mngt.
Gov.
HF activism
proposal
proposal
event
support % support %
(5)
ROA
(6)
(7)
(8)
0.565*
(0.294)
-0.134*
(0.081)
0.417***
(0.124)
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
733
1,225
119
191
1,549
4,171
1,496
4,052
-1.139*** -0.796***
(0.183)
(0.243)
Appendix for Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 11
.
Appendix Table 6
Robustness of findings to including industry fixed effects
This table reports estimates of the second-stage regression of our instrumental variable estimation to identify the effect of
institutional ownership by passive investors on our governance and corporate outcome variables when we add 2-digit SIC industry
fixed effects. The data, outcome variables, and specification are the same as in Tables 4-10 except that we now also include 2-digit
SIC industry fixed effects in the specification. The model is estimated over the 1998-2006 period using a bandwidth of 250 firms
around the Russell 1000/2000 threshold and a third polynomial order control for Ln(Mktcap). To demonstrate the robustness of the
association between passive ownership and longer-term performance, we include the additional controls for recent movers, used in
columns 4-6 of Table 10, when analyzing ROA (column 8).
Standard errors, ε, are clustered at the firm level and reported in
parentheses. The symbols *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Dependent variable =
Ind.
directors
%
Ability to
Poison pill
call special
removal
meeting
Ind. for
dual class
shares
(1)
Passive %
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
2-digit industry FE
# of firms
Observations
(2)
(3)
(4)
0.537***
(0.151)
0.182**
(0.0795)
0.349***
(0.116)
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
1,080
2,871
1,164
2,957
1,050
1,858
1,050
1,858
Mngt.
Gov.
HF activism
proposal
proposal
event
support % support %
(5)
ROA
(6)
(7)
(8)
0.478
(0.336)
-0.161*
(0.0840)
0.453***
(0.122)
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
775
1,288
127
202
1,654
4,415
1,600
4,291
-0.781*** -0.660***
(0.178)
(0.230)
Appendix for Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 12
.
Appendix Table 7
Robustness of findings to including controls for firms that recently switched indexes
This table reports estimates of the second-stage regression of our instrumental variable estimation to identify the effect of
institutional ownership by passive investors on our governance and corporate outcome variables when we add controls to account for
firms that recently switched indexes. Specifically, the data, outcome variables, and specification are the same as in Tables 4-10
except that we now two additional controls to the specification: an indicator that equals one for firms that are in the Russell 2000
index in year t but were in the Russell 1000 in year t-1, and an indicator that equals one for firms that are in the Russell 1000 index in
year t but were in the Russell 2000 index in year t-1. The model is estimated over the 1998-2006 period using a bandwidth of 250
firms around the Russell 1000/2000 threshold and a third polynomial order control for Ln(Mktcap). Standard errors, ε, are clustered
at the firm level.
The symbols *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Dependent variable =
Ind.
directors
%
Ability to
Ind. for
Mngt.
Gov.
Poison pill
call special dual class proposal
proposal
removal
meeting
shares
support % support %
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
Controls for movers
# of firms
Observations
(4)
(5)
(7)
(8)
(2)
0.514***
(0.170)
0.201***
(0.077)
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
1,080
2,871
1,164
2,957
1,050
1,858
1,050
1,858
775
1,288
127
202
1,654
4,415
1,600
4,291
0.296*** -1.090*** -0.953***
(0.113)
(0.193)
(0.250)
(6)
ROA
(1)
Passive %
(3)
HF
activism
event
0.663**
(0.324)
-0.287*** 0.414***
(0.097)
(0.121)
Appendix for Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 13
. Appendix Table 8
Robustness of findings to using only ownership of Barclays Bank, State Street, and Vanguard
This table reports estimates of the second-stage regression of our instrumental variable estimation to identify the effect of aggregate institutional
ownership by Vanguard, State Street, and Barclays Bank on our governance and corporate outcome variables. Specifically, we estimate
N
Yit = α + β BSV % it + ∑ θ n ( Ln( Mktcapit )) + γ Ln( Float )it + δ t + ε it
n
n=1
where: Yit is the outcome variable for firm i in year t; BSV%it is the percentage of shares outstanding owned by Barclays Bank, State Street, and
Vanguard of stock i at the end of September in year t; Mktcapit is the CRSP market value of equity of stock i measured at May 31 in year t; and
Floatit is the float-adjusted market value of equity (provided by Russell) at June 30 in year t, and δt are year fixed effects. The outcome variables
investigated in this table are the same as in earlier tables, and we instrument BSV% in the above estimation using R2000it, an indicator equal to
one if firm i is part of the Russell 2000 index in year t. The data consist of firms in the two Russell indexes for which we obtain holdings data
from Thomson Reuters Institutional Holdings (13F) Database and which we match with data from the monthly CRSP file.
The model is
estimated over the 1998-2006 period using a bandwidth of 250 firms around the Russell 1000/2000 threshold and a third polynomial order
control for Ln(Mktcap). To demonstrate the robustness of the association between passive ownership and longer-term performance, we include
the additional controls for recent movers, used in columns 4-6 of Table 10, when analyzing ROA (column 8). Standard errors, ε, are clustered at
the firm level.
The symbols *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
BSV %
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
# of firms
Observations
Ind.
directors
%
Poison pill
removal
(1)
Dependent variable =
Ability to
Mngt.
Ind. for dual
call special
proposal
class shares
meeting
support %
Gov.
proposal
support %
HF activism
event
ROA
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
0.673***
(0.159)
0.249***
(0.0920)
0.432***
(0.152)
-1.293***
(0.262)
-0.792***
(0.265)
0.838*
(0.496)
-0.204**
(0.0967)
0.596***
(0.184)
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
1,073
2,840
1,160
2,940
1,047
1,847
1,047
1,847
768
1,279
125
200
1,633
4,357
1,586
4,246
Appendix for Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 14
. Appendix Table 9
Robustness of findings to using end-of-May market cap rankings to select sample
This table reports estimates of the second-stage regression of our instrumental variable estimation to identify the effect of institutional
ownership by passive investors on our governance and corporate outcome variables when we instead choose our sample using end-of-May
market cap rankings. The data, outcome variables, and specification are the same as in Tables 4-10 except that we choose our sample by
ranking stocks within a year using their end-of-May CRSP market cap and selecting our sample to only include stocks ranked 750th largest
through 1250th largest each year. The model is estimated over the 1998-2006 period using a third polynomial order control for Ln(Mktcap).
To demonstrate the robustness of the association between passive ownership and longer-term performance, we include the additional
controls for recent movers, used in columns 4-6 of Table 10, when analyzing ROA (column 8). Standard errors, ε, are clustered at the firm
level and reported in parentheses.
The symbols *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Passive %
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
2-digit industry FE
# of firms
Observations
Ind.
directors
%
Poison pill
removal
(1)
Dependent variable =
Ability to
Mngt.
Ind. for dual
call special
proposal
class shares
meeting
support %
Gov.
proposal
support %
HF activism
event
ROA
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
0.448**
(0.202)
0.186
(0.123)
0.378**
(0.186)
-1.800***
(0.366)
-0.748**
(0.333)
0.352
(0.304)
-0.249**
(0.114)
0.353**
(0.175)
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
1,073
2,949
1,157
2,966
1,053
1,886
1,053
1,886
772
1,294
119
195
1,626
4,431
1,593
4,325
Appendix for Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 15
. Appendix Table 10
Robustness of findings to including control for a firm's lagged stock return
This table reports estimates of the second-stage regression of our instrumental variable estimation to identify the effect of institutional
ownership by passive investors on our governance and corporate outcome variables when we add a control to account for a firm's
stock return in the previous reconstitution year. Specifically, the data, outcome variables, and specification are the same as in Tables 410 except that we add one control to the specification: the stock return in the year prior to the determination of a stock's index
assignment [i.e., from end-of-May in year t-1 to end-of-May in year t]. The model is estimated over the 1998-2006 period using a
bandwidth of 250 firms around the Russell 1000/2000 threshold and a third polynomial order control for Ln(Mktcap). To demonstrate
the robustness of the association between passive ownership and longer-term performance, we include the additional controls for
recent movers, used in columns 4-6 of Table 10, when analyzing ROA (column 8).
Standard errors, ε, are clustered at the firm level.
The symbols *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Dependent variable =
Ind.
Ability to Ind. for
Mngt.
Gov.
Poison pill
directors
call special dual class proposal proposal
removal
%
meeting
shares support % support %
Bandwidth
Polynomial order, N
Float control
Year fixed effects
Control for lagged stock return
# of firms
Observations
(4)
(5)
ROA
(6)
(7)
(8)
0.604*
(0.326)
-0.160*
(0.0840)
0.466***
(0.128)
(1)
Passive %
(3)
HF
activism
event
(2)
0.675***
(0.163)
0.209**
(0.0846)
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
250
3
yes
yes
yes
1,075
2,856
1,111
2,855
1,046
1,850
1,046
1,850
746
1,252
126
201
1,537
4,185
1,483
4,068
0.355*** -1.021*** -0.711***
(0.119)
(0.184)
(0.268)
Appendix for Passive Investors, Not Passive Owners -- Page 16
. Biographical Sketch of Authors
Ian Appel is an assistant professor of finance at the Carroll School of Management at
Boston College. His research interests are in the areas of corporate finance, law and
finance, and institutional investors. His recent research examines the effects of
shareholder litigation and passive institutional investors. Ian received his Ph.D.
in
finance from The Wharton School at the University of Pennsylvania.
Todd Gormley is an Assistant Professor of Finance at The Wharton School at the
University of Pennsylvania, where he teaches advanced corporate finance in the MBA
program and empirical methodologies in the PhD program. Professor Gormley’s
research focuses on how financial sector competition affects the local economy, how
external governance affects managerial choices, and how individuals and managers
respond to risk. His recent research examines whether passive institutional investors are
passive owners and whether managers have an underlying preference to “play it safe”
when external governance is weakened.
Professor Gormley received his Ph.D. in
Economics from the Massachusetts Institution of Technology.
Donald Keim is the John B. Neff Professor of Finance and Director of the Rodney L.
White Center for Financial Research at the Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania.
His research has dealt with: the relation between stock returns and predetermined
variables (dividend yields, market cap, earnings/price ratios, and calendar turning points);
tests of asset pricing models; the behavior of institutional investors with respect to
trading, stock holdings, and corporate governance; the investment choices of participants
in defined contribution pension plans; and the risks and returns of stock market-based
real estate investments.
He received an MBA and PhD from the University of Chicago.
.