Antitrust & Trade
Regulation Report™
VOL. 108, NO. 2691
APRIL 10, 2015
RESTRAINTS OF TRADE
Insurance
Contingent Commissions and the Antitrust Laws:
What Can We Learn from the In re Insurance Brokerage Antitrust Litigation?
BY WILLIAM KOLASKY
AND
KATHRYN MCNEECE
n 2014, the last of the tag-along actions were settled
in the long-running In re Insurance Brokerage Antitrust Litigation,1 a massive multidistrict litigation in
which the plaintiffs alleged that most of the major com-
I
1
618 F.3d 300 (3d Cir. 2010).
Copyright ௠2015 William Kolasky and Kathryn McNeece
Mr.
Kolasky is a partner in the Washington,
D.C. ofï¬ce of Hughes Hubbard & Reed
LLP. Ms.
McNeece is an articling student
(pending Ontario license) in the Toronto, Ont.,
ofï¬ce of Blake, Cassels & Graydon LLP. They
thank Greta Fails, an associate at Hughes
Hubbard & Reed LLP’s New York ofï¬ce, for
her assistance in ï¬nalizing this article. Mr.
Kolasky represented one of the insurer defendants in this litigation.
COPYRIGHT ஽ 2015 BY THE BUREAU OF NATIONAL AFFAIRS, INC.
mercial insurance companies and major insurance brokers had conspired to allocate customers in exchange
for contingent commission payments in violation of
both the federal antitrust laws and RICO.
That litigation challenged business practices that are
common throughout the insurance industry and, in particular, called into question the dual role insurance brokers play as intermediaries who act both as producers
for the insurers and as advisors to their policyholder clients.
Now that both the criminal and civil litigation has finally been concluded after more than a decade, this is a
good time to review how these business practices will
be treated under the antitrust laws going forward and
what broader applicability the Third Circuit’s decision
may have in other industries where intermediaries play
an important role in matching sellers and buyers.
I.
The Role of Insurance Brokers
In the market for commercial insurance, insurance
brokers match companies seeking insurance coverage
with insurers that will provide them with policies. Insurance brokers often receive some or all of their compensation from commissions paid by the insurers that underwrite the policies in question. During the period covered by the In re Insurance Brokerage case,
commissions took the form of either ‘‘standard’’ commissions, usually simple percentages of the premiums
generated by the policy the insurer sells through the
broker, or ‘‘contingent’’ commissions, which are based
on some aggregate measure of the volume of business
generated for the insurer by the broker.
Contingent
commissions vary among insurers: some have a tiered
bonus structure in which the broker can earn additional
ISSN 0003-6021
. 2
compensation by reaching certain volume thresholds;
some offer bonuses based on retention of renewal business; some base commissions on the percent increase in
the book of business or in the amount of profits generated by the book of business placed with the insurer by
the broker over a certain period of time; and some combine multiple criteria.
Standard commissions are widely accepted in the insurance industry (and indeed were not challenged in
the In re Insurance Brokerage litigation), but contingent commissions have been criticized for creating a
conflict of interest for brokers. Unlike insurance agents,
who owe fiduciary duties to insurance companies, insurance brokers are agents of the policyholder. Since
contingent commissions to the broker are based on the
profitability or value of a book of business to the insurer, some worry that the incentive structure results in
insurance companies competing with each other on the
attractiveness of their contingent commissions to the
broker, rather than solely on the attractiveness of their
policies to the policyholder. Critics such as Daniel
Schwarcz argue that these incentives introduce inefficiency into the insurance markets, even where their existence is disclosed to sophisticated insurance buyers.2
In particular, Schwarcz notes that buyers using intermediaries have a limited capacity to assess the insurers’
strengths and weaknesses, that intermediaries can discriminate among buyers and take advantage of those
who are less sophisticated, and that the relationship of
trust between buyer and intermediary leads buyers not
to scrutinize the advice they receive from the broker.3
In the In re Insurance Brokerage litigation, plaintiffs alleged that the defendant brokers manipulated relationships in just this way to steer business to preferred insurers improperly.
Defenders of the practice of contingent commissions
argue that contingent commissions do not necessarily
create a conflict of interest for insurance brokers.
In
their view, the different structures of contingent commission agreements provide incentives that—in some
cases—are diametrically opposed to each other: ‘‘For
example, incentives created by an agreement that required an incumbent insurer to pay if it retained a given
percentage of its business would conflict with incentives created by an agreement with another insurer that
rewarded growth in new business.’’4 In a leading article
on the economics of insurance intermediaries, Cummins and Doherty argue that profit-based contingent
commissions, for example, align the interests of brokers and insurers such that they can share information
about the risk of prospective policyholders and make
2
Daniel Schwarcz, Beyond Disclosure: The Case for Banning Contingent Commissions, 25 YALE L. & POL’Y REV. 289, 295
(2007).
3
Id.
at 294.
4
Brief of Appellees at 5–6, In re Ins. Brokerage Antitrust
Litig., 618 F.3d 300 (3d Cir. 2010) (No.
07-4046), 2008 WL
4005068 at *5–6.
markets more efficient by alleviating adverse selection.5
The increased confidence insurers will have regarding
estimated risk will lead to more aggressive bidding by
insurers for policyholders’ business. In this way, contingent commissions actually stimulate competition in insurance markets. Those who take this view of contingent commissions argue that a robust disclosure regime
informing potential policyholders of contingent commissions and ‘‘preferred provider’’ schemes is all that is
needed to alleviate the risk of anticompetitive behavior
within the framework of the insurance markets.
The In re Insurance Brokerage litigation represents
the ultimate legal clash between those views.
In order to
properly contextualize the Third Circuit’s decision in
that case, it is necessary first to review the recent history of legal attacks on contingent commissions generally.
II. Eliot Spitzer’s Attack on Contingent
Commissions
In the late 1990s and early 2000s, the largest insurance broker, Marsh & McClennan Companies
(‘‘Marsh’’), began entering into ‘‘Placement Service
Agreements’’ (‘‘PSAs’’) with insurers that entitled
Marsh to additional payments if it directed a certain volume of business to an insurer, regardless of the profitability of that business.’’6 In early 2004, two letters urging investigation into these types of contingent commissions spurred then-Attorney General of New York Eliot
Spitzer to begin an investigation of contingent commissions paid to property and casualty insurance brokers.
By May of that year, Mr. Spitzer had expanded his investigation to include insurance companies, and by the
fall, the investigation had uncovered emails suggesting
Marsh had conspired with certain insurers to rig bids by
obtaining false quotes.7
Relying on these emails, Mr.
Spitzer filed a complaint
(the ‘‘Marsh Complaint’’) against Marsh on October 14,
2004, alleging both that Marsh had orchestrated a bidrigging scheme to steer its clients to the insurers that
would pay it the largest contingent commissions and
that Marsh conspired with insurance companies to restrain trade by providing its clients with false bids, allocating the opportunity to sell insurance to its clients,
and creating a scheme to pay itself for implementing
the conspiracy.8
5
See J. David Cummins & Neil A. Doherty, The Economics
of Insurance Intermediaries, 73 J.
RISK & INS. 359 (2006), available
at
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_
id=928728.
6
Sean M. Fitzpatrick, The Small Laws: Eliot Spitzer and
the Way to Insurance Market Reform, 74 FORDHAM L.
REV. 3041,
3044 (2006).
7
Id. at 3045–46.
8
Complaint ¶¶ 43–74, 80–83, State v.
Marsh & McLennan
Cos., No. 04-403342 (N.Y. Sup.
Ct. Oct. 14, 2004).
The complaint also alleged fraud and violations of New York state security laws. Id. ¶¶ 79, 84–85.
To request permission to reuse or share this document, please contact permissions@bna.com.
In your request, be sure to include the following information: (1) your name, company, mailing address, email and telephone number; (2) name of the document and/or a link to the document PDF; (3)
reason for request (what you want to do with the document); and (4) the approximate number of copies to be made or URL address (if posting to a
website).
4-10-15
COPYRIGHT ஽ 2015 BY THE BUREAU OF NATIONAL AFFAIRS, INC.
ATRR
ISSN 0003-6021
. 3
Attorney General Spitzer’s efforts to eliminate contingent commission payments to the largest brokers
were initially successful. Almost immediately after the
Marsh Complaint was filed, Marsh, Aon Corporation
(‘‘Aon’’), Willis Group Holdings Limited (‘‘Willis’’), and
other large brokers announced that they would stop accepting contingent commissions.9 In January 2005,
Marsh agreed to settle the Spitzer lawsuit and a related
suit by the New York Department of Insurance for $850
million.10 In March 2005, Spitzer filed a lawsuit against
Aon and (along with the attorneys general of Connecticut and Illinois) announced a $190 million settlement
with that firm.11 In April, Willis, the third largest insurance broker, agreed to settle for $50 million.12 As part
of these settlements, each broker agreed it would no
longer accept contingent commissions.13
Attorney General Spitzer’s efforts to attack bid rigging and contingent commissions were not limited to
civil actions against brokers. The same day the Attorney
General’s office filed its civil complaint against Marsh,
two AIG insurance executives pleaded guilty to criminal
charges of rigging bids with Marsh.14 In the wake of
Spitzer’s lawsuit, dozens of brokers and insurance company employees pleaded guilty to criminal antitrust
charges, while dozens more resigned, including
Marsh’s chairman and CEO, Jeffrey Greenberg.15
Despite these early successes, the Attorney General’s
gains from attacking contingent commissions as anticompetitive or otherwise illegal quickly eroded.16 In
9
See Schwarcz, supra note 3, at 291–92.
See Joseph B. Treaster & Terence Neilan, Marsh to Pay
$850 Million to Settle Charges, N.Y.
TIMES, Jan. 31, 2005, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2005/01/31/business/31cndinsu.html.
11
See Joseph B. Treaster, Aon Will Pay $190 Million to
Settle Complaints on Bids, N.Y.
TIMES, Mar. 5, 2005, available
at http://www.nytimes.com/2005/03/05/business/05insure.html.
12
The Associated Press, Insurance Broker Settling Inquiry
for $50 Million, N.Y. TIMES, Apr.
9, 2005, available at http://
www.nytimes.com/2005/04/09/business/09willis.html.
13
See Agreement Between the Attorney General of the
State of New York and the Superintendent of Insurance of the
State of New York, and Marsh & McLennan Companies, Inc.,
Marsh Inc. and their subsidiaries and affiliates (collectively
‘‘Marsh’’) ¶ 10 (Jan. 30, 2005), http://www.dfs.ny.gov/
insurance/dept_inv/oag050130.pdf; Agreement Among the Attorney General of the State of New York, the Superintendent
of Insurance of the State of New York, the Attorney General of
the State of Connecticut, the Illinois Attorney General, the Director of the Division of Insurance, Illinois Department of Financial and Professional Regulation, and Aon Corporation and
its subsidiaries and affiliates (collectively ‘‘Aon’’) ¶ 10 (Mar.
4,
2005), http://www.ag.ny.gov/sites/default/files/press-releases/
archived/aonsettlement.pdf; Assurance of Discontinuance Pursuant to Executive Law § 63(15), at ¶ 9, In the Matter of Willis
Group Holdings Ltd. (Apr. 7, 2005), http://www.dfs.ny.gov/
insurance/dept_inv/oag0504072.pdf.
14
See Joseph B.
Treaster, Broker Accused of Rigging Bids
for Insurance, N.Y. TIMES, Oct. 15, 2004, available at http://
www.nytimes.com/2004/10/15/business/15insure.html.
15
See, e.g., Joseph B.
Treaster, Insurance Chief Quits in Inquiry Led by Spitzer, N.Y. TIMES, Oct. 26, 2004, available at
http://www.nytimes.com/2004/10/26/business/26insure.html.
16
Spitzer himself seemed conflicted about whether contingent commissions were problematic on their own or only in
conjunction with bid rigging or other questionable practices.
While he frequently referred to the payment of contingent
commissions as ‘‘kickbacks,’’ he indicated on more than one
occasion that they may be appropriate in some parts of the in10
ANTITRUST & TRADE REGULATION REPORT
ISSN 0003-6021
September 2007, the Appellate Division of the First Department in New York dismissed four causes of action
based on a failure to disclose the existence of a contingent commission agreement by holding that
‘‘[c]ontingent commission agreements between brokers
and insurers are not illegal, and, in the absence of a special relationship between the parties, defendant[s]
ha[ve] no duty to disclose the existence of [a] contingent commission agreement.’’17 In February 2008, two
former Marsh managing directors who had declined to
plead guilty with their colleagues were convicted on
only a single charge of restraining trade contrary to
New York state antitrust law and acquitted of the remaining charges.
In the summer of 2009, however, the
judge overturned both men’s convictions because the
prosecutor had failed to disclose documents containing
evidence that undermined the court’s confidence in the
verdict.18 The decision to throw out the conviction was
not appealed.19 The judge subsequently vacated the
convictions of those individuals who had previously
pleaded guilty to similar charges.20
Though at the time of Attorney General Spitzer’s lawsuit against Marsh widespread changes in the operation
of the insurance industry due to increased regulation
also seemed inevitable, state legislative and regulatory
reactions to contingent commissions have been mild.
While the 2005 settlements signed by Marsh, Aon, and
Willis banned those three largest insurance brokers
from accepting contingent commissions, by 2010, the
New York State Insurance Department had decided to
lift the ban in favor of a consistently applied regime of
disclosure standards.21 At that time, large insurance
brokers signaled that they would voluntarily refrain
from accepting contingent commissions,22 but by 2013
the insurance industry had by and large returned to its
pre-2005 practices, suggesting that the Attorney Genersurance industry. See Press Release, Nat’l Ass’n of Prof’l Ins.
Agents, PIA National Encouraged by Remarks Made by NY Attorney General Eliot Spitzer on Contingent Commissions (Jan.
31, 2005), http://www.pianet.com/news/press-releases/2005/
pia-national-encouraged-by-remarks-made-by-ny-attorneygeneral-eliot-spitzer-on-contingent-commissions.
17
Hersch v. DeWitt Stern Grp., Inc., 43 A.D.3d 644, 645
(N.Y.
App. Div. 2007) (internal citations omitted).
18
Reuters, Bid-Rigging Convictions Overturned, N.Y.
TIMES,
July 7, 2010, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2010/07/08/
business/08insure.html?_r=0.
19
After their convictions were thrown out, Gilman and McNenney sued Marsh, alleging they were terminated without
cause and demanding payment of their severance packages
and other damages. See Susanne Craig, Former Executives
Claim Marsh ‘Colluded’ With Spitzer, N.Y. TIMES DEALBOOK,
June 27, 2011, http://dealbook.nytimes.com/2011/06/27/formerexecutives-claim-marsh-colluded-with-spitzer/.
More recently,
Gilman and McNenney filed a defamation suit against Mr.
Spitzer for statements he made in an article in Slate Magazine.
See Jeremy W. Peters, Spitzer and Slate Face Defamation
Lawsuit, N.Y. TIMES, Aug.
22, 2011, available at http://
www.nytimes.com/2011/08/23/business/media/spitzer-andslate-face-lawsuit-over-column-on-wall-street.html?_r=0.
20
See Karen Freifeld, Cuomo Drops Effort Over Marsh Executives’ Convictions, BLOOMBERG, Dec. 16, 2010, http://
www.bloomberg.com/news/2010-12-16/cuomo-drops-appealto-restore-marsh-mclennan-executives-convictions.html.
21
Andrew G. Simpson, Large Brokers Freed to Go After
Contingent Commissions But Will They?, INSURANCE JOURNAL,
Feb.
17, 2010, available at http://www.insurancejournal.com/
news/national/2010/02/17/107441.htm.
22
Id.
BNA
4-10-15
. 4
al’s attack on the insurance industry was, at the end,
much ado about very little.23
nothing per se unlawful about such relationships.29 The
decision was appealed to the Third Circuit, which delivered its opinion in 2010.
III. Ensuing Private Antitrust Actions
IV. The Third Circuit’s Opinion
In late 2004, as soon as Attorney General Spitzer filed
the Marsh Complaint, private litigants began suing brokers and insurers in federal and state courts across the
country. Many of the cases were styled as class actions
and contained federal antitrust claims as well as RICO
and common law claims.24 The Judicial Panel on Multidistrict Litigation consolidated the majority of civil suits
related to the payment of contingent commissions in
the United States District Court for the District of New
Jersey under the name In re Insurance Brokerage Antitrust Litigation.25 The cases transferred to New Jersey
proceeded on two dockets, one for cases arising from
commercial property and casualty insurance and the
other for cases arising from employee benefit insurance.
In their antitrust claims in those cases, the plaintiffs
principally alleged a series of broker-centered ‘‘hub and
spoke’’ conspiracies, in which each broker allegedly
colluded with partner-insurers to steer customers to
those preferred insurers in exchange for contingent
commission payments.
If an insurer refused to pay contingent commissions, it was not eligible for partner status, and could not gain access to that broker’s lucrative
book of business. The plaintiffs also alleged a global
conspiracy wherein, while engaging in their separate
‘‘hub and spoke’’ conspiracies, the ‘‘hub’’ brokers simultaneously agreed not to compete by agreeing not to
disclose the contingent commission arrangements of
other brokers. The plaintiffs claimed that, as a result of
these alleged agreements, they ‘‘paid inflated prices for
their insurance coverage and were .
. . denied the benefits of a competitive market.’’26
After three successive rounds of pleadings, the New
Jersey court granted the defendants’ motions to dismiss
the plaintiffs’ complaints with prejudice.27 District
Court Judge Garret E.
Brown, Jr. concluded that since
Plaintiffs had alleged only vertical agreements by brokers to allocate customers to their preferred insurers in
exchange for contingent commission payments, they
‘‘face[d] the problem of the ‘rimless wheel’ – a situation
in which various defendants enter into separate agreements with a common defendant, but where the defendants have no connection with one another, other than
the common defendant’s involvement in each transaction.’’28 But, the court explained, while vertical restraints may be challenged under the rule of reason,
without agreement among the vertical partners, there is
This article will review the two lines of argument the
Third Circuit considered with regard to contingent commissions. First, it will consider the Third Circuit’s treatment of the McCarran-Ferguson Act’s insurance exemption to the antitrust laws and its application to contingent commissions.
Second, it will then turn to the
Third Circuit’s treatment of the antitrust law claims and
the sufficiency of pleadings under the standard set out
in Bell Atlantic Corp. v. Twombly.30
23
Alistair Gray, Insurers’ contingent commissions attacked, THE FINANCIAL TIMES, Jan.
13, 2013, available at http://
www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/bb834a80-5c42-11e2-ab3800144feab49a.html#axzz2pct7GNJ3.
24
Many copied liberally from the Marsh Complaint.
25
Fifty-one suits were eventually transferred to the District
of New Jersey.
26
In re Ins. Brokerage Antitrust Litig., 618 F.3d at 308.
27
The plaintiffs were given two opportunities to re-plead
and to submit additional detailed factual allegations to support
their claims. See Memorandum Opinion at 2–6, ECF No.
1298,
In re Ins. Brokerage Antitrust Litig., MDL No. 1663, Civ.
No.
04-5184 (D.N.J. Aug. 31, 2007).
28
See Memorandum Opinion, supra note 28, at 33–34.
4-10-15
A.
The McCarran-Ferguson Exemption
The defendant insurance companies argued that regardless of the adequacy of the plaintiffs’ pleadings of
their antitrust claims, those claims were barred by the
McCarran-Ferguson Act, which exempts the ‘‘business
of insurance’’ from the Sherman Act where it is regulated by state law. The Third Circuit panel disagreed. It
found that the alleged misconduct did not fall within the
‘‘business of insurance’’ for the purposes of the Act’s
antitrust exemption.
The antitrust claims, therefore,
were not barred by the McCarran-Ferguson Act, and
analysis of the antitrust pleadings would be dispositive
in the case.
The McCarran-Ferguson Act provides that ‘‘[n]o Act
of Congress shall be construed to invalidate, impair, or
supersede any law enacted by any State for the purpose
of regulating the business of insurance,’’31 with the exception that ‘‘[n]othing contained in this chapter shall
render the said Sherman Act inapplicable to any agreement to boycott, coerce, or intimidate, or act of boycott,
coercion, or intimidation.’’32 In practice, the Act provides a statutory antitrust exemption for activities that
fit three criteria: (i) they constitute the ‘‘business of insurance,’’ (ii) they are regulated under state law, and
(iii) they do not constitute acts of ‘‘boycott, coercion, or
intimidation.’’33 The panel’s analysis focused exclu29
Id. at 29–30 (‘‘Plaintiffs have not established a plausible
scheme for the first part of the alleged conspiracy, namely, the
consolidation of the Broker Defendants’ business with a few
preferred partner insurers. Plaintiffs have not set forth facts to
support the theory that the Insurer Defendants agreed with
each other, either expressly or impliedly, to pay the Broker Defendants contingent commissions in order to receive the benefit of lessened competition by some discernable method.
Plaintiffs’ explanation of this purported conspiracy has not significantly changed since the Court initially dismissed the First
Amended Complaints.
The allocation of premium volume in
exchange for contingent commission payments consists of a
vertical relationship among the Broker Defendants and the Insurer Defendants.’’). Vertical agreements between entities operating at different levels of a distribution chain, such as an insurer and a broker, are not per se illegal under the Sherman
Act, but are subject to rule of reason analysis. See Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc.
v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 907
(2007) (vertical price restraints); Cont’l T.V., Inc.
v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 59 (1977) (vertical non-price restraints).
30
550 U.S.
544 (2007).
31
15 U.S.C. § 1012(b) (2013).
32
Id. § 1013(b).
33
In re Ins.
Brokerage Antitrust Litig., 618 F.3d at 351
(quoting Ticor Title Ins. Co. v.
FTC, 998 F.2d 1129, 1133 (3d
Cir. 1993)).
COPYRIGHT ஽ 2015 BY THE BUREAU OF NATIONAL AFFAIRS, INC.
ATRR
ISSN 0003-6021
. 5
sively on the first criterion, and looked primarily to
three earlier cases to define ‘‘the business of insurance’’
for these purposes: Group Life & Health Insurance Co.
v. Royal Drug Co.,34 Union Labor Life Insurance Co. v.
Pireno,35 and Owens v. Aetna Life & Casualty Co.36
In Royal Drug, independent pharmacies challenged a
Blue Cross ‘‘participating pharmacies’’ plan, which allowed insured persons to purchase discounted prescriptions from participating pharmacies while policyholders who went to non-participating pharmacies had to
pay retail price.
In ruling for the plaintiffs, the Supreme
Court cautioned that an overly expansive interpretation
of ‘‘the business of insurance’’ risked bringing all activities of insurance companies within the antitrust exemption, a result that it found would be ‘‘plainly contrary’’
to the statutory language.37 In Pireno, the Supreme
Court extended the Royal Drug analysis to name three
criteria that must be met for activity to come within the
‘‘business of insurance’’ for purposes of the McCarranFerguson Act: ‘‘ï¬rst, whether the practice has the effect
of transferring or spreading a policyholder’s risk; second, whether the practice is an integral part of the
policy relationship between the insurer and the insured;
and third, whether the practice is limited to entities
within the insurance industry.’’38
The Third Circuit considered these precedents along
with Owens, a Third Circuit case, in determining how to
characterize the defendants’ conduct.39 The panel
found that the second and third Pireno criteria were
clearly met: the alleged agreement was an integral part
of the policy relationship between the insurer and the
insured ‘‘insofar as it would affect the insurers from
which a prospective purchaser could obtain coverage,’’40 and all of the parties were clearly entities within
the insurance industry. However, the panel held that
the alleged conduct did not meet the first Pireno factor
because the alleged agreement did not have the effect
of transferring or spreading policyholders’ risk: the
agreement involved ‘‘not whether or to what extent a
prospective insurance purchaser would transfer its risk
to an insurer, but merely to which insurer that risk
would be transferred.’’41 In addition, the court concluded that the alleged misconduct did not fall into any
of the categories of the business of insurance named in
Owens. Although the conduct involved what Owens described as ‘‘accepting or rejecting coverages tendered
by brokers,’’ the panel understood Owens to be referring to discrimination between the types of policies tendered, not a simple division of the market.42 Therefore,
the court concluded, the defendants’ conduct did not
constitute the business of insurance for the purposes of
34
440 U.S.
205 (1979).
458 U.S. 119 (1982).
36
654 F.2d 218 (3d Cir. 1981).
37
440 U.S.
at 217.
38
458 U.S. at 129.
39
Owens named several activities that fall within the ‘‘business of insurance’’ due to their relationship to risk-spreading
or the contract between insurer and insured: preparing and filing a rating schedule, deciding on rating classification differences between individual policies and group marketing plans,
authorizing agents to solicit policies, and accepting or rejecting coverage tendered by brokers. 654 F.2d at 225–26.
40
In re Ins.
Brokerage Antitrust Litig., 618 F.3d at 356.
41
Id. at 357.
42
Id. at 358.
35
ANTITRUST & TRADE REGULATION REPORT
ISSN 0003-6021
the antitrust exemption in the McCarran-Ferguson Act,
and the Act did not bar the plaintiffs’ antitrust claims.
Since 2010, one case has analyzed the Third Circuit’s
McCarran-Ferguson Act conclusions.
In June 2014, the
Northern District of Alabama adopted the Third Circuit’s reasoning in a factually analogous case: In re Blue
Cross Blue Shield Antitrust Litigation.43 In Blue Cross,
provider and subscriber plaintiffs alleged that the defendant Blue Cross/Blue Shield plans engaged in a conspiracy to horizontally allocate geographic markets by
agreeing to carve the United States into ‘‘service areas’’
in which only one plan was permitted to sell health insurance to subscribers and contract with providers.44
The court analogized the defendant plans’ alleged conduct to the defendant insurance companies’ alleged
conduct in the Insurance Brokerage litigation and
found that the defendant plans’ alleged conduct was
‘‘similarly unrelated to the spreading of risk.’’45 The
court therefore concluded that the alleged conduct did
not constitute the ‘‘business of insurance,’’ but rather
involved the ‘‘business of insurance companies,’’ and
that the McCarran-Ferguson Act did not bar the plaintiffs’ claims.46
B. The Court’s Antitrust Analysis
Having disposed of the McCarran-Ferguson issue,
the Third Circuit began its analysis of the plaintiffs’ antitrust claims by reviewing the legal standards applicable to antitrust claims. In the consolidated class action complaints, the plaintiffs had pleaded only per se
violations of antitrust laws, meaning that in order to
prevail on a motion to dismiss they would need to show
the existence of a horizontal agreement among partner
insurers.47 The panel applied the Twombly standard,
which requires a complaint to allege enough facts to
‘‘state a claim for relief that is plausible on its face,’’ in
order to defeat a motion to dismiss under Federal Rule
of Civil Procedure 12(b)(6).48 Just as the Supreme
Court had done in Twombly, the panel held that in order to state a claim for relief based on a per se violation
of Section 1, a plaintiff must allege sufficient facts to
plausibly imply a horizontal agreement among insurers,
not simply a series of parallel vertical agreements between each individual insurer and a single broker that
they may have entered into for their own independent
business interests.49 To meet this requirement, the
plaintiffs were required to have alleged either direct evidence of an agreement or to have alleged facts to show
that parallel vertical agreements would have been contrary to the business interests of each insurer absent an
agreement among the insurers.50
The Third Circuit then examined the facts plaintiffs
had alleged to meet this requirement and to show that
the ‘‘spokes’’ in their alleged hub-and-spoke conspiracies were, in fact, connected.51 The plaintiffs argued,
first, that the essential nature of contingent commission
43
MDL No.
2406, Civ. No. 2:13-CV-20000-RDP, 2014 WL
2767360 (N.D.
Ala. June 18, 2014).
44
2014 WL 2767360, at *1.
45
Id. at *13.
46
Id.
at *10.
47
In re Ins. Brokerage Antitrust Litig., 618 F.3d at 318.
48
Id. at 319.
49
Id.
at 321.
50
Id. at 323.
51
Id. at 326.
BNA
4-10-15
.
6
agreements implies agreements among the insurers,
and second, that certain aspects of the alleged customer
steering schemes—particularly methods used to ensure
that business was placed with a certain insurer—
implied agreements among the insurers.52 The Third
Circuit rejected both arguments.
As to the nature of contingent commission agreements, the court noted that ‘‘each insurer had sound, independent business reasons to pay contingent commissions to become and remain a ‘preferred insurer.’ ’’53
The panel also considered that ‘‘plaintiffs’ argument
proves too much. If the parallel decisions by several insurers to pay contingent commissions imply a horizontal agreement, then it is difficult to see why parallel decisions to pay standard commissions . . .
would not also
imply an agreement.’’54
As to the specific features of the alleged customer
steering schemes, the court ruled that while the conduct
alleged might give rise to claims under state law for deception or unfair trade practices, the allegations failed
to state conduct prohibited by the Sherman Act.55 In the
panel’s view, the alleged ‘‘incumbent protection
racket,’’ including ‘‘first look’’ and ‘‘last look’’ bidding
practices meant to ensure that a certain policy was
placed or remained with a certain insurer, involved only
practices that were vertical in nature (between the broker and the insurer), and ‘‘the complaints themselves
provide[d] obvious reasons to conclude that the brokers
were able to steer clients to preferred insurers without
the need for any agreement among the insurers.’’56 For
these reasons, the Third Circuit held that the plaintiffs
had failed to state a claim of a per se violation of the
Sherman Act with respect to their broad customer allocation claims tied to the payment of contingent commissions, and the claims were dismissed.
The In re Insurance Brokerage plaintiffs had more
success with their bid-rigging allegations—namely, that
one Marsh entity, Marsh Global Broking, had conspired
with a subset of the insurer defendants to rig bids by
having those insurers submit false bids in order to direct business to certain insurers while maintaining a veneer of competition. The Third Circuit found that the
willingness of the insurers involved in the specific incidents of bid-rigging alleged in the complaint to submit
protective bids and actively assist in deceptive practices
plausibly suggested collusion and horizontal agreements among those insurers not to compete for each
other’s incumbent business.57 The court, therefore, reversed the district court with regard to these antitrust
claims and remanded to the lower court for consideration of the sufficiency of those allegations under Rule
9(b) of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure, which requires that allegations of fraudulent conduct be pleaded
with particularity.58
52
Id. at 327.
Id.
(quoting Brief of Appellees, supra note 5, at 38).
54
Id. at 328.
55
Id. at 334.
56
Id.
at 334–35.
57
Id. at 339–40, 347–48.
58
The District Court never spoke on the 9(b) issue, as the
many parties settled between 2011 and 2013.
53
4-10-15
V. Ultimate Denouement
After the remaining federal and state law claims were
remanded to the district court, the plaintiffs in the consolidated class action and in various tag-along individual and class actions reached settlements with all of
the remaining defendants while the claims in their complaint were still at the motion to dismiss stage.
The
terms of the class action settlements are all public.
Those terms indicate that the plaintiffs settled the remaining claims for a small fraction of the amounts of
the settlements Attorney General Spitzer had earlier extracted from Marsh and some of the other major broker
and insurer defendants or that the class action plaintiffs
had extracted from those brokers and insurers who
settled early in the litigation before the Third Circuit’s
ruling.59
The Third Circuit’s opinion and the ensuing settlements provide two major takeaways for those practicing antitrust in the insurance industry. First, the opinion, along with the Blue Cross decision adopting the
Third Circuit’s opinion, show that, in line with other exemptions from the antitrust laws, courts will construe
the McCarran-Ferguson Act narrowly. Only those activities that meet the indicia set out in Pireno, or that fall
within the specifically enumerated categories as described in Owens, will fall within its carve-out from the
antitrust laws.
Consequently, those who have concerns
about the antitrust implications of certain actions
should be wary of depending on the shelter of the
McCarran-Ferguson Act if they are not directly related
to risk-spreading activities.
Second, the In re Insurance Brokerage opinion
should assuage concerns that contingent commission
payments to insurance brokers via ‘‘preferred-partner’’
arrangements with insurance companies are per se anticompetitive. Although the Third Circuit opinion left
open the possibility that such practices could be challenged under a ‘‘rule of reason’’ analysis, the settlement
of the tag-along cases, several of which sought to allege
rule of reason claims, at the motion to dismiss stage,
and the growing acceptance of contingent commissions
by state insurance regulators subject to a disclosure regime suggests that there is little room for actions challenging these vertical arrangements on a rule of reason
theory either. The Third Circuit’s opinion suggests that
these parallel vertical agreements—be they structured
as contingent commissions or ‘‘preferred partner’’
agreements—will not fall afoul of antitrust laws without
evidence of actual collusion among the insurers, or of
other traditionally anticompetitive practices such as
bid-rigging.
59
See In re Ins.
Brokerage Antitrust Litig., MDL No. 1663,
Civ. No.
04-5184, 2009 WL 411877 (D.N.J. Feb. 17, 2009) (approving $69 million settlement with Marsh Defendants); In re
Ins.
Brokerage Antitrust Litig., 579 F.3d 241, 248, 252, 254–55
(3d Cir. 2009) (affirming district court’s approvals of $121.8
million settlement with Zurich Defendants and $28 million
settlement with Gallagher Defendants); In re Ins. Brokerage
Antitrust Litig., 282 F.R.D.
92, 101, 118 (D.N.J. 2012) (approving $41 million Global Settlement with eleven of the fourteen
defendants remaining after the Third Circuit’s decision); In re
Ins. Brokerage Antitrust Litig., 297 F.R.D.
136, 143, 147 (D.N.J.
2013) (approving $10.5 million settlement resolving the consolidated class action as to the final three remaining defendants).
COPYRIGHT ஽ 2015 BY THE BUREAU OF NATIONAL AFFAIRS, INC.
ATRR
ISSN 0003-6021
.