CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
Antitrust Compliance 2.0: The Use of
Structural Analysis and Empirical Screens
to Detect Collusion and Corruption in
Bidding Procurement Processes
Rosa M. Abrantes-Metz
Global Economics Group & NYU Stern School of
Business
&
Elizabeth Prewitt
Hughes Hubbard & Reed LLP
www.competitionpolicyinternational.com
Competition Policy International, Inc. 2015© Copying, reprinting, or distributing this article is forbidden by anyone
other than the publisher or author.
66060371_2
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
Antitrust Compliance 2.0: The Use of Structural Analysis and
Empirical Screens to Detect Collusion and Corruption in Bidding
Procurement Processes
Rosa M. Abrantes-Metz & Elizabeth Prewitt1
I. INTRODUCTION
Collusion among bidders is a recurring problem in both public and private
procurements. This is evident from recent U.S. enforcement actions and those of other
jurisdictions across the globe targeting bidâ€rigging cartels and resulting in substantial fines,
civil damages, and terms of incarceration for individuals in jurisdictions with criminal
penalties. The harm caused by such cartels is perhaps most keenly felt by government
entities in emerging markets with limited budgets to develop and maintain infrastructure
and obtain necessary goods and services. But private companies making significant
purchases through tender or bidding processes are similarly vulnerable.
Moreover, collusive conduct between horizontal competitors is not the only means
by which the integrity of such procurement processes can be undermined; individuals with
purchasing authority have facilitated bidâ€rigging cartels in return for bribes or kickbacks.
Such corruption can therefore operate handâ€inâ€hand with bidâ€rigging, often increasing the
potential harm and likelihood of detection by enforcers and civil litigants.
Instead of waiting for the proverbial “knock on the door” by an enforcer, companies
are increasingly adopting proactive detection methods to assess risk and target compliance
efforts―a trend that will arguably be encouraged by recent statements by the U.S.
Department of Justice “DOJ” warning that compliance programs are expected to
incorporate auditing and testing functions. Similarly, in recent years some enforcers have
eschewed waiting for leniency applicants to come forward with evidence of a cartel in favor
of examining market structures and behavioral patterns to detect collusive conduct.
This article explores how the increase in enforcement actions targeting bidâ€rigging
and corruption globally raises the risk of detection, and how screens can be used as a
proactive tool to successfully uncover this conduct.
1
Rosa M. Abrantes Metz, Managing Director, Global Economics Group, Adjunct Associate Professor,
NYU’s Stern School of Business & Elizabeth Prewitt, Partner, Hughes Hubbard and Reed LLP. The authors
gratefully acknowledge the contributions of Sigrid Jernudd, an Associate at Hughes Hubbard and Reed LLP, in
writing this article. The views expressed in this study belong solely to the authors and should not be
attributed to the organizations with whom they are affiliated or their clients. Contacts: RAbrantesâ€
Metz@GlobalEconomicsGroup.com and Elizabeth.Prewitt@hugheshubbard.com.
2
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
II. INCREASED DETECTION RISKS
A. Increased Antitrust Enforcement Directed at Bid-Rigging Cartels Raises the Risk of
Detection
Bidâ€rigging poses a substantial risk of large administrative and criminal fines and
penalties, as demonstrated by recent enforcement actions across the globe. In Fiscal Year
2014 alone, the Antitrust Division of the DOJ collected $1.3 billion in criminal fines and
penalties,2 and approximately $760 million of this total—59 percent—came from cases
involving at least some allegation of bidâ€rigging.3
Penalties arising from such conduct can extend beyond fines and civil damages to
include debarment from future government procurements. For example, the World Bank
proscribes behavior that is corrupt, fraudulent, collusive, coercive, or obstructive,4 and
actions that amount to “collusion”—such as bidâ€rigging—can therefore lead to debarment
from contracts funded by the World Bank.5
While historically examples of bidâ€rigging cartels have most frequently appeared in
infrastructure industries such as construction and road paving, cartels have been found in a
number of industries and taken a number of forms. In connection with the DOJ’s ongoing
investigation into market allocation, priceâ€fixing, and bidâ€rigging in the automotive parts
industry, as of June 2015, 55 individuals have been charged and 35 companies have
pleaded guilty or agreed to plead guilty with fines totaling more than $2.5 billion.6 In those
matters, bidâ€rigging presented with a range of other antiâ€competitive conduct. But bidâ€
rigging in its most classic form has been the core or sole antitrust allegation in a number of
other DOJ investigations, such as in the food distribution industry, where the NYC Board of
Education’s school food contracts to serve 1.1 million schoolchildren were rigged by
competing suppliers.7
And enforcement actions have also been directed at less traditional forms of bidâ€
rigging, often called “atypical” or “hub and spoke” cartels.8 For example, the DOJ filed a
number of charges in the financial service industry in connection with its investigation of
2 Bill Baer, Assistant Attorney General, Antitrust Division, DOJ, Statement before the Subcommittee on
Regulatory Reform, Commercial and Antitrust Law, Committee on the Judiciary, U.S. House of Representatives
2â€3 May 15, 2015 , available online at http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/testimony/313877.pdf.
3 This percentage was calculated by reviewing all DOJ press releases during this period.
4 World Bank, Guidelines on the Procurement of Goods, Works, and Nonâ€Consulting Services, Art. 1.16 a
Jan. 2011, rev. July 2014 , available online at http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTPROCUREMENT/
Resources/Procurement_GLs_English_Final_Jan2011_revised_July1â€2014.pdf.
5 For example, in 2008 and 2009, the World Bank debarred seven firms, including two for up to eight
years, for alleged bidâ€rigging in the Philippines. See Bob Davis, World Bank Bans Chinese Firms Due to Bidâ€
Rigging Allegations, WALL ST. J. Jan. 15, 2009 , available online at http://www.wsj.com/articles/
SB123200130285285123.
6 DOJ, Press Release, Current and Former Executives of an Automotive Parts Manufacturer Indicted for
Roles in Conspiracy to Fix Prices—Investigation Has Resulted in Charges Against 90 Individuals and
Corporations May 21, 2015 , http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/press_releases/2015/314206.htm.
7 See Indictment, United States v. Penachio, No. 00 CR 583 ¶¶ 27â€29 S.D.N.Y. May 31, 2000 .
8 Elizabeth Prewitt & Greta Fails, Indirect information exchanges to hubâ€andâ€spoke cartels: enforcement
and litigation trends in the United States and Europe, 1 COMP. L. & POL’Y 63, 63â€64 2015 .
3
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
brokers conspiring with competing providers to rig bids for municipal bond investment
contracts, and as of May 2015, seventeen individuals have been convicted or have pleaded
guilty.9 Moreover, states have filed their own actions targeting bidâ€rigging conduct even
when there has been no parallel DOJ enforcement action, as we have seen perhaps most
notably in New York State’s insurance brokerage rigging investigation.10
Investigations targeting bidâ€rigging have become increasingly prevalent over the
last few years. In the DOJ’s ongoing real estate foreclosure auctionâ€rigging investigation
over 50 individuals have pleaded guilty or agreed to plead guilty, and 20 other real estate
investors have been charged.11 And in connection with an ongoing DOJ investigation into
the rigging of municipal tax liens in New Jersey over 20 individuals and entities have been
charged, with 15 guilty pleas to date.12 And, in recent weeks, we have seen both a Georgia
real estate investor plead guilty to conspiring to rig bids at public real estate foreclosure
actions13 and five school bus owners in San Juan, Puerto Rico indicted for participating in a
conspiracy to rid bids in a Caguas municipality auction for public school bus contracts.14
But these recent U.S. actions are only part of a global enforcement trend.
Worldwide enforcement trends also show an increased focus on bidâ€rigging. For
example, in 2013 South Korea’s Fair Trade Commission “KFTC” formed an investigative
9 See, e.g., DOJ, Press Release, Former Bank of America Executive Sentenced to Serve 26 Months in Prison
for Role in Conspiracy and Fraud Involving Investment Contracts for Municipal Bond Proceeds May 18,
2015 , http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/press_releases/2015/314127.htm former managing director of
Bank of America’s municipal derivatives group was sentenced to serve 26 months in prison ; DOJ, Press
Release, Three Former UBS Executives Sentenced to Serve Time in Prison for Frauds Involving Contracts
Related to the Investment of Municipal Bond Proceeds July 24, 2013 , http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/
press_releases/2013/299604.htm former UBS AG executives sentenced to serve 18 months in prison with a
U.S. $1 million fine, 27 months in prison with a $400,000 fine, and sixteen months in prison with a $300,000
fine .
10 In October 2004, the New York State Attorney General filed a civil complaint against Marsh &
McLennan “Marsh” , an insurance broker, alleging that Marsh had solicited rigged bids for insurance
contracts and had received improper contingent commission payments in return for steering its clients to a
select group of insurers. Complaint, State v. Marsh & McLennan Cos., No. 04â€43342 N.Y. Sup. Ct. Oct. 14,
2004 ; see also William Kolasky & Kathryn McNeece, Contingent Commissions and the Antitrust Laws: What
Can We Learn from the In re Insurance Brokerage Antitrust Litigation?, Bloomberg BNA Antitrust & Trade
Regulation Report Apr. 10, 2015 , available online at http://www.hugheshubbard.com/Documents/
Contingent%20Commissions%20and%20the%20Antitrust%20Laws.pdf.
11 DOJ, Press Release, Two Northern California Real Estate Investors Agree to Plead Guilty to Bid Rigging
and Fraud Conspiracies at Public Foreclosure Auctions Apr. 23, 2015 , http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/
press_releases/2015/313378.htm.
12 DOJ, Press Release, Former New York Tax Liens Investment Company Executive Pleads Guilty for Role
in Bid Rigging Scheme at Municipal Tax Lien Auctions May 12, 2014 , http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/
press_releases/2014/305817.htm.
13 DOJ, Press Release, Georgia Real Estate Investor Pleads Guilty to Bid Rigging and Fraud Conspiracies at
Public Real Estate Foreclosure Auctions June 5, 2015 , http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/
press_releases/2015/314842.htm. The investor also pled guilty to mail fraud. Id.
14 DOJ, Press Release, Five School Bus Owners Indicted for Bidâ€Rigging and Fraud Conspiracies at Puerto
May 21, 2015 , http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/
Rico Public School Bus Action
press_releases/2015/314217.htm. The school bus owners were also charged with mail fraud and conspiracy
to commit mail fraud. Id.
4
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
division focusing exclusively on bidâ€rigging,15 and in 2014 the Malaysia Competition
Commission “MyCC” announced the launch of new initiatives to detect bidâ€rigging.16 In
the last few weeks alone, we have seen examples of enforcement actions directed at bidâ€
rigging, including the Russian Federal Antimonopoly Service “FAS” announcement of
fines against four companies for bidâ€rigging cartel behavior,17 and an individual who
participated in a bidâ€rigging conspiracy related to Canadian government contracts was
sentenced.18 These are just recent anecdotal examples of enforcement actions resulting
from the increased scrutiny of procurements for antiâ€competitive conduct.
Patterns of enforcement actions occurring over the last decade warn that future
enforcement actions should be anticipated in jurisdictions that embrace leniency programs
and in industries that have already experienced aggressive enforcement. This is, in part,
because companies implicated in existing investigations may be rewarded with immunity
from fines in exchange for being the first to report on any separate undisclosed conspiracy,
as well as a reduction in fines related to the prior conspiracy. The policy, known as amnesty
plus, has been extremely successful in incentivizing targeted companies to race to disclose
any additional misconduct they have undertaken before their coâ€conspirators19 and that
trend is expected to continue.
B. The Rise in Anti-Corruption Enforcement Further Increases the Risk of Detection
While collusion and corruption both pose their own challenges to the integrity of
procurements, they “may frequently occur in tandem, and have a mutually reinforcing
15 Jaeâ€Chan Jeong, Korea: Korean Fair Trade Commission, Global Competition Review Asiaâ€Pacific
Antitrust Review 2015, http://globalcompetitionreview.com/reviews/69/sections/235/chapters/2755/
koreaâ€koreaâ€fairâ€tradeâ€commission/. In February 2014, Korean courts sentenced three individuals to six
months’ imprisonment for rigging bids on tenders to supply cables to nuclear power plants under the Penal
Code and one individual for two years’ imprisonment for rigging bids on tenders for construction projects
under the Construction Industry Regulation Act.
16 Press Release, Malaysia Competition Commission, MyCC Launches Two Handbooks on Bid Rigging
Nov. 4, 2014 , http://mycc.gov.my/wpâ€content/uploads/2014/07/Newsâ€Releaseâ€MyCCâ€Launchesâ€Twoâ€
Bidâ€Riggingâ€Handbooks_041114_kch.pdf. In addition to the handbooks, the MyCC launched a number of
seminars attended by procurement officials countryâ€wide. Id. at 2. Some of these materials are available in
English. See, e.g., Malaysia Competition Commission, Help Us Detect Bid Rigging June 2014 ,
http://mycc.gov.my/wpâ€content/uploads/2014/06/MYCC_Handbook_HelpUsDetectBidRigging.pdf; Malaysia
Competition Commission, Overview of Bid Rigging Under the Competition Act 2010 June 2014 ,
http://mycc.gov.my/wpâ€content/uploads/2014/06/BIDâ€RIGGINGâ€UNDERâ€THEâ€CA2010â€Finalâ€iskandar.pdf.
The MyCC announced in 2015 that—working with the Malaysian Antiâ€Corruption Agency—it intended to
focus on bidâ€rigging. Veena Babulal, MyCC to enforce anti bidâ€rigging laws soon, NEW STRAIT TIMES ONLINE
May 16, 2015 , http://www.nst.com.my/node/84442.
17 MLex, Russian antitrust watchdog to fine bidâ€rigging cartel June 8, 2015 . FAS also announced that it
had forwarded information on the companies’ executives to the pertinent authorities to pursue criminal
charges against them. Id.
18 MLex, Former Microtime employee sentenced after pleading guilty to bidâ€rigging May 21, 2015 . The
employee must serve an 18â€month conditional sentence, perform 60 hours of community service, and pay a
$23,000 fine. Id.
19 See Scott D. Hammond & Belinda A. Barnett, U.S. DOJ Antitrust Division, Frequently Asked Questions
Regarding the Antitrust Division’s Antitrust Program 8 Nov. 19, 2008 “A large percentage of the Division’s
investigations have been initiated as a result of evidence developed during an investigation of a completely
separate conspiracy.” , http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/criminal/239583.pdf.
5
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
effect.”20 Over the last several years we have seen a rise in U.S. Foreign Corrupt Practices
Act “FCPA” charges targeting bribery of foreign officials, along with increased antiâ€
corruption efforts worldwide.21
The policy argument for increased enforcement is plain to see. A 2012 study by the
European Commission estimated that corruption could be responsible for increasing the
cost of public procurement in Europe by 20â€25 percent.22 And such incremental costs
associated with corruption are perhaps even more deeply felt in emerging markets where
funds to build and service critical infrastructure are more limited.23
Given the potential impact on government budgets, enforcers around the globe are
increasingly turning the microscope on public bidding to uncover evidence of corruption
involving the public officials overseeing the bidding process and the companies submitting
bids. These investigations have revealed evidence of agreements between competing
bidders to rig bids and fix prices, at times paying bribes to officials to facilitate these
collusive agreements.
When bribery payments are made to local government officials to facilitate the
allocation of contracts as part of a bidâ€rigging conspiracy, these can and have given rise to
FCPA violations. And in circumstances where the Antitrust Division has discovered
evidence of corrupt payments in the course of international cartel investigations, it has
charged violations of both the Sherman Act and the FCPA simultaneously. For example, in
2011 Bridgestone Corporation was charged with conspiracy to rig bids and to violate the
FCPA because Bridgestone’s employees bribed sales agents at stateâ€owned enterprises in
Argentina, Brazil, Ecuador, Mexico, and Venezuela, among other countries, to secure the
confidential information necessary to effectuate the bidâ€rigging scheme.24 While this
matter stands as an atypical example of an Antitrust Division enforcement action directed
at a FCPA violation, the Criminal Division of the DOJ has a dedicated FCPA unit with a
mandate to detect and prosecute such offenses.
It should be noted that there are other types of corruption schemes operating handâ€
inâ€hand with schemes to rig bids, but that are not charged as violations of the FCPA or the
Sherman Act. Most often these enforcement actions involve persons within the contracting
authority or entity engaging in improper communication with one or more of the bidding
companies and transmitting sensitive bidding information to secretly assist one or more
companies to win contracts. For example, in March 2015, the DOJ announced a plea
agreement with Asem Elgawhary, a former vice president of Bechtel Corporation and the
20 OECD, Report, Collusion and Corruption in Public Procurement 1 2010 , available online at
http://www.oecd.org/competition/cartels/46235884.pdf.
21 See generally Hughes Hubbard, FCPA/Antiâ€Bribery Alert Winter 2015 1â€4 February 2015 ,
http://www.hugheshubbard.com/PublicationDocuments/FCPA%20Antiâ€
Bribery%20Alert%20Winter%202015.pdf.
22 European Commission, Frequently Asked Questions: How corruption is tackled at EU level Feb. 12,
2012 , http://europa.eu/rapid/pressâ€release_MEMOâ€12â€105_en.htm?locale en.
23 OECD, Report, Collusion and Corruption in Public Procurement 2010 , available online at
http://www.oecd.org/competition/cartels/46235884.pdf.
24 Plea Agreement, United States v. Bridgestone Corporation, No. 4:11â€crâ€00651 ¶ 4 k †p S.D. Tex. Oct.
5, 2011 No. 21 .
6
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
general manager of a joint venture with Egypt’s stateâ€owned electrical company. Elgawhary
accepted $5.2 million in kickbacks from three power companies to manipulate the bidding
process for stateâ€run power contracts and was ultimately sentenced to serve 42 months in
jail.25 While Elgawhary was not charged by the DOJ with bidâ€rigging or a FCPA violation,
these facts depict a typical mixture of corruption and collusion.
In a somewhat prototypical case involving kickbacks and bidâ€rigging prosecuted by
the Antitrust Division, United States v. McDonald, a project manager for a prime contractor
facilitated a bidâ€rigging conspiracy between subcontractors to create the false appearance
that the competitive bidding process required for the governmentâ€funded projects was
followed.26 McDonald accomplished this by providing confidential information to the
subcontractor paying him kickbacks to effectuate the bidâ€rigging scheme.
Still other examples and variations of this hybrid of corruption and collusion
conduct exist and will be uncovered by enforcers or entities employing tools to detect the
telltale patterns.
In situations where bribery appears in connection with bidâ€rigging, whether as a
violation of the FCPA or as commercial bribery, an overlap in U.S. enforcement efforts
should be expected. Moreover, the rise of antiâ€corruption enforcement in other
jurisdictions means that the long arm of U.S. law is not the only enforcement threat capable
of reaching this conduct. We are seeing more and more countries adopt and aggressively
enforce their own foreign corruption laws. In fact, TRACE International recently found that
the number of nonâ€U.S. enforcement actions involving the bribery of foreign officials nearly
doubled between 2013 and 2014.27
Other jurisdictions are recognizing the connection between bidâ€rigging and
corruption, and are directing their enforcement resources to examine procurements
accordingly. For example, in an investigation of corruption and collusion relating to the
procurement of combat boots for the German Armed Forces, it was discovered that an
employee of the Armed Forces Procurement Agency passed on confidential information to
facilitate collusion among bidders in return for kickbacks. The German state prosecutor’s
office pursued corruption charges while the German Competition Authority
Bundeskartellamt issued fines after it found that six companies used the information
from the official to submit their bids. Notably, this behavior was investigated after an
internal procurement agency review found irregularities. Other enforcers are also
adopting a coordinated approach to detect collusion and corruption.28 It is in this context
25 DOJ, Press Release, Former Bechtel Executive Sentenced to 42 Months in Prison and Ordered to Forfeit
$5.2 Million in Connection with Kickback Scheme Mar. 23, 2015 , http://www.justice.gov/opa/pr/formerâ€
bechtelâ€executiveâ€sentencedâ€42â€monthsâ€prisonâ€andâ€orderedâ€forfeitâ€52â€millionâ€connection.
He
was
sentenced to 42 months in prison, and to forfeit the $5.2 million he received, after pleading guilty to mail
fraud, conspiracy to commit money laundering, obstruction, and tax offenses. Id.
26 DOJ, Press Release, Former Project Manager Sentenced to Serve Time in Prison for Role in Bid Rigging
and Other Fraudulent Schemes Involving Two EPA Superfund Sites in New Jersey Mar. 3, 2014 ,
http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/press_releases/2014/304133.htm.
27 TRACE International, Global Enforcement Report 2014, Fig. 3 June 2015 .
28 See MLex, Canada’s competition enforcers tapping police about links between bidâ€rigging, bribery
June 9, 2015 .
7
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
that screens are considered a means to uncover both forms of conduct. In fact, the Swedish
Competition Authority Konkurrensverket issued a statement last month that it has begun
employing a number of screens to analyze procurement data searching for tellâ€tales of
cartel behavior with the goal of increasing the likelihood of detection, and specifically noted
its collaboration with the Swedish National Antiâ€Corruption Unit by exchanging
anonymized information regarding suspected markets and preâ€studies. 29
Given the long list of competition and antiâ€corruption enforcement authorities
turning the microscope on procurement processes, the risk of detection for both collusion
and corruption has increased dramatically. A compliance audit that detects a bidâ€rigging
scheme therefore offers the potential of detecting related corruption conduct in time to
remediate or mitigate before being uncovered by others.30 Systems for review of public
procurement, however, are typically designed largely to make sure that the rules for
bidding processes are followed, and detecting bidâ€rigging is often not the primary
objective. The use of screens as part of a procurement review should be explored as a
means to detect patterns consistent with collusion and corruption rather than competition.
C. The Use of Structural Analysis and Empirical Screens to Detect Collusion
There are essentially two different types of economic analyses that flag the possible
existence of a conspiracy to rig bids.31 The first can be classified as a “structural approach,”
which looks at the structure of the industry at hand, “scoring” the likelihood of collusion
based on factors such as homogenous products, few competitors, stability of demand, and
other commonly acknowledged markers of environment conducive to collusion.32 The
second is empirical and adopts a “behavioral,” “outcomes,” or “empirical” approach. Here
economists look at markets’ and participants’ behaviors as translated into observable data
and then apply screens for conspiracies and manipulations to address whether the
observed behavior is more or less likely to have been produced under an explicit
agreement. It is in connection with this approach that “screens,” or sometimes “empirical
screens,” are used. These rely on timeâ€series, crossâ€sectional data, and/or panel data sets
with variables that measure market outcomes―including prices, volumes, and market
shares―to detect potential anticompetitive behavior.
In brief, “screening” refers to the method for flagging collusive behavior through
economic and statistical analyses. A screen uses statistical tests based on econometric
and
Screening for Cartels in Procurement Procedures
Cooperation May 7, 2015 , available online at
29 Konkurrensverket Swedish Competition Authority,
the
Importance
of
Interâ€agency
http://www.konkurrenverket.se/globalassets/press/talâ€artiklar/150507 danâ€sjoblomsâ€anforandeâ€ecd.pdf.
30 Gary R. Spratling, Deputy Assistant Attorney General, Antitrust Division, Remarks at the American
Conference Institute 7th National Conference on Foreign Corrupt Practices Act, International Cartels: the
Intersection Between FCPA Violations and Antitrust Violations Dec. 9, 1999 , available online at
http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/speeches/3981.htm.
31 Joseph Harrington, Detecting Cartels, HANDBOOK OF ANTITRUST ECONOMICS P. Buccirossi, ed. 2008 .
32 A general list of these factors is further detailed in Proof of Conspiracy under Antitrust Federal Law,
AMERICAN BAR ASSOCIATION EDS., Ch. VIII April 2010 . A nonâ€exhaustive “check list” of characteristics that
influence the susceptibility of a market to tacit or explicit collusion includes: number of firms and market
concentration, differences among competitors, product heterogeneity, demand volatility, barriers to entry,
benefits of cheating, transparency, and multiâ€market contact.
8
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
models and a theory of the alleged collusion designed to: 1 identify whether collusion,
manipulation, or any other type of cheating may exist in a particular market; 2 who may
be involved; and 3 how long it may have lasted. Screens typically use available data such
as prices, bids, quotes, spreads, market shares, volumes, and other data to identify patterns
that are anomalous or highly improbable other than as a product of collusion.
Over the last few years, economic analysis in general, and empirical screens in
particular, have been increasingly relied upon to detect behavior consistent with collusion
and manipulation.33 Competition authorities and other agencies worldwide have begun
using screens to detect possible market conspiracies and manipulation, and defendants and
plaintiffs have begun adopting them as well.34
Focus and interest in this area have increased dramatically in recent years. For
example, in October 2013 the OECD held a policy roundtable on “Ex Officio cartel
investigations and the use of screens to detect cartels.”35 In this discussion we see how the
adoption of screens has become increasingly popular with several countries but yet, at the
same time, we have learned that other jurisdictions have not yet adopted screens, alleging
these are “too resource” intensive, provide “too many false positions,” or simply that
“screens don’t work.” In a previous article summarizing her participation at the 2013 OECD
Policy Roundtable, Abrantesâ€Metz 2014 36 rebuts these and other arguments against
screens and makes the case for their effectiveness.
III. HOW STRUCTURAL AND EMPIRICAL ANALYSES CAN HELP DETECT COLLUSION IN
BIDDING
A. Applying Economic Analyses to Available Data—Using What You‘ve Got
A lack of robust data is the greatest challenge to detecting collusion in bidding
through economic analysis. This is particularly problematic for companies who are on the
Screens for Conspiracies and
their Multiple Applications, 24 1 ANTITRUST MAG. Fall, 2009 ; Rosa Abrantesâ€Metz & Patrick Bajari, Screens
for Conspiracies and their Multiple Applications, 6 2 COMPETITION POL’Y INT’L, 129â€144 2010 ; and Kai
Hüschelrath, Economist’s Note: How are Cartels Detected? The Increasing Use of Proactive Methods to
Establish Antitrust Infringements, J. EUR. COMPETITION L. & PRACTICE, 1â€7 September 2010 .
34 Surveys of screening methodologies and their multiple applications can be found in Harrington, supra
note 2; Joe Harrington & Joe Chen, Cartel Pricing Dynamics with Cost Variability and Endogenous Buyer
Detection, 24 INT’L J. INDUS. ORG. 1185â€1212 2006 ; and Abrantesâ€Metz & Bajari, Id. The use of these methods
in antitrust litigation is detailed in the American Bar Association’s Proof of Conspiracy under Antitrust
Federal Laws, which specifically describes in Chapter VIII the role of the economic expert in proving a
conspiracy and details the use of screens in this context. Rosa Abrantesâ€Metz & D. Daniel Sokol, Antitrust
Corporate Governance and Compliance, HANDBOOK OF ANTITRUST ECONOMICS forthcoming and Rosa Abrantesâ€
Metz, Patrick Bajari, & Joseph Murphy, Enhancing Compliance Programs through Antitrust Screening, 4 5
33 A trend detailed, for example, in Rosa Abrantesâ€Metz & Patrick Bajari,
ANTITRUST COUNSELOR September 2010 makes the case for the use of screens in corporate antitrust
compliance programs.
35 See generally OECD, Ex officio cartel investigations and the use of screens to detect cartels 2013 ,
available online at http://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/exofficioâ€cartelâ€investigationâ€2013.pdf. The panel
consisted of Rosa M. Abrantesâ€Metz, William E. Kovacic, and Maarten Pieter Schinkel.
36 R. Abrantesâ€Metz submission, OECD, Guidelines for Fighting Bid Rigging in Public Procurement 2â€3
2009 , available online at http://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/cartels/42851044.pdf.
9
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
sales side, but yet seek to ensure that their employees are not engaged in anticompetitive
conduct. Typically, their compliance programs canvas a company’s organizational structure
to identify which employees are likely to have contacts with competitors, and then train
them on the “do’s and don’ts.”
If audits are conducted, the focus is on available internal information, and such
audits frequently involve reviewing documentation from trade association meetings or
surrounding sales transactions with competitors, or even sampling emails for improper
contacts with competitors. Little focus is placed on reviewing externally available
information, which is often a fruitful avenue to assess risk.
Running background checks on individuals is one way to draw upon externally
available data to help assess risk, and these types of audit are now more routinely
conducted than previously in our current era of increased antiâ€corruption enforcement. But
now we are also seeing such audits in connection with public procurement. For example,
China’s NDRC and Supreme People’s Procuratorate announced this year that they would be
running criminal background checks on the winners in any project that requires a bidding
process.37
As noted earlier, there are numerous ways to assess the degree of risk of antiâ€
competitive conduct by looking at the structure of an industry and its participants.
Collusion among potential contracting firms can be facilitated where certain market
characteristics prevail, and these “industry, product, and service characteristics” include:
ï‚·
ï‚·
ï‚·
ï‚·
ï‚·
ï‚·
ï‚·
ï‚·
a small number of companies,
little or no entry,
market conditions,
industry associations,
repetitive bidding,
identical or simple products or services,
few if any substitutes, and
little or no technological change.38
For this reason, structural patterns should be examined. And, as noted earlier,
future enforcement efforts can sometimes be anticipated in jurisdictions that embrace
leniency programs and have experienced aggressive enforcement in an industry. By
analyzing these factors together, an entity is better equipped to assess its risk and what
further measures can and should be taken.
In addition to examining structural patterns and the enforcement environment,
entities procuring goods or services through bidding may have the requisite data readily
available to help make the use of behavioral screens effective. Other entities may be able
access that data externally, especially in connection with certain public procurements.
37 PaRR Alert,
China imposes criminal bribery background checks on bidding and tendering activities
June 9, 2015 .
38 OECD, supra note 35.
10
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
Bidâ€rigging in competitive tenders is a productive setting to apply screens for three
reasons:
1. Competitive tenders account for a large volume of economic output. Public sector
procurement, which often uses some form of competitive bidding, on average
accounts for about 10â€15 percent of an economy’s output.39 In addition, competitive
bidding is widely used in financial markets, privatization of public assets, real estate,
and many other transactions.
2. Bidâ€rigging is a common antitrust offense. As noted above, bidâ€rigging has been
alleged in nearly 60 percent of the criminal cases filed by the DOJ in the last year.
3. Markets that use competitive bidding are frequently rich in data, containing not just
the final price but also the individual bids and, in many cases, information related to
the components of the bids themselves. In many countries, statutes require the
public disclosure of bids.
There is a large body of empirical literature on collusion in auctions that discusses
the implementation of various types of screens.40 While these papers span a wide variety of
industries, researchers have identified common patterns that exist when collusion is
known or suspected. One common analysis involves identifying bidding patterns that are
very unlikely to be generated in a true competitive bidding process, and another compares
the market suspected of bidâ€rigging against a comparable unsuspected benchmark. As
discussed below, both methods should be considered.
B.
Screening for Bids That are Highly Correlated Even After Controlling for Legitimate Market
Conditions
This type of screening looks for specific improbable events that can be rationally
explained only by the existence of collusion. In sealedâ€bid settings, firms usually submit
their bids simultaneously to be later read at a fixed date. In the public sector, the contract is
typically then awarded to the lowest bidder. If there is no collusion between firms, then the
bidders have not formulated each of their bids in consideration of the others’ bids. As a
result, we should expect the bids to be independent across bidders after we control for
World Trade Organization, WTO and government procurement, https://www.wto.org/english/
tratop_e/gproc_e/gproc_e.htm.
40 P. Bajari & G. Summers, Detecting Collusion in Procurement Auctions, 70 ANTITRUST L. J. 143 2002 .
See Robert H. Porter & J. Douglas Zona, Detection of Bid Rigging in Procurement Auctions, 101 J. POL. ECON.
518 1993 examining auctions for highway construction projects in Long Island ; Laura H. Baldwin, et al.,
Bidder Collusion at Forest Service Timber Sales, 105 4 J. POL. ECON. 657â€699 1997 examining timber
auctions in the Pacific Northwest ; Robert H. Porter & J. Douglas Zona, Ohio School Milk Markets: An Analysis
of Bidding, 30 RAND J. ECON. 263 1999 examining the procurement of school milk in Ohio ; Martin
Pesendorfer, A Study of Collusion in Firstâ€Price Auctions, 67 REV. ECON. STUD. 1 2000 ; Peter Crampton &
Jesse Schwartz, Collusive Bidding: Lessons from the FCC Spectrum Auctions, 17 J. REG. ECON., 229â€252 2000 ;
Patrick Bajari & Jungwon Yeo, Auction Design and Tacit Collusion in FCC Spectrum Auctions, forthcoming in
INFORMATION ECON. & POL’Y; Patrick Bajari & Lixin Ye, Deciding Between Competition and Collusion, 85 4
REVIEW ECON. STAT., 971â€989 2003 ; John List, Daniel Millimet, & Michael Price, Inferring Treatment Status
39
when Treating Assignment is Unknown: with an Application to Collusive Bidding Behavior in Canadian
Softwood Timber Auctions, mimeo University of Chicago 2004 ; John Asker, A Study of the Internal
Organisation off a Bidding Cartel, 100 3 AMER. ECON. REV., 724â€762 2010 ; Robert Marshall & Leslie Marx,
The Vulnerability of Auctions to Bidder Collusion, forthcoming in Q. J. ECON 2007 .
11
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
information that is observed by all bidders, such as variables that influence cost or market
power.
On the other hand, if firms collude, they are coordinating their bids. This
coordination tends to destroy the independence of the bids and can be detected through
the use of statistical hypothesis testing. Collusion is suspected when bids are “too
correlated” with each other to be the result of independent actions by bidders.
Clearly identical bids would be flagged through this sort of screen as being “too
correlated.” But, absent identical bids, how high should the correlation be among bids to
raise suspicion? The answer is that “it depends” on typically several factors. But sometimes
the correlation is so high, even perfect, that the likelihood of the correlation occurring
without coordination is essentially zero. A famous example was seen in bids received by
the Tennessee Valley Authority to install conductor cables in the 1950s. Seven firms
submitted identical bids of $198,438.24. The chances of seven bidders, acting
independently, arriving at bids that agree to eight significant digits is statistically zero and
thus offered a very strong signal that firms had explicitly or implicitly arrived at a
mechanism for coordinating bids.
Porter & Zona 1993 41 utilized this type of screen in a case involving bids to supply
school milk in Ohio between 1980 and 1990, although producing a less striking pattern
than seen in the Tennessee Valley Authority case. In Ohio, firms submitted sealed bids for
contracts to supply schools with pintâ€size portions of milk. The bidders were typically
processors or distributors of milk with school milk typically representing less than 10
percent of their annual revenues. Based on evidence presented in court, Robert Porter and
Douglas Zona argued that a bidder’s costs are easily explained by only a small number of
variables, which are readily observed, and include the price of raw milk and transportation
costs, which represent 7 percent of total costs. Competition in the school milk market is
localized due to transportation costs, so firms that are close to a particular school have a
cost advantage because of shorter delivery routes.
Porter and Zona constructed econometric models of submitting a bid and bid levels.
Economic theory suggests that both decisions should depend on two factors. The first is
costs, which the authors measured using data on the distance between a public school, the
bidder’s location, and the number of deliveries made by the bidder. The second is local
market power, which the authors controlled for by variables measuring the locations of
competing firms. The first screen proposed by Porter and Zona examined the correlation in
bidders’ entry decisions. After controlling for information that was publicly observed at the
time of bidding, the authors found that the bidding decisions of some firms in the sample
was too high to be explained by pure randomness, which supported the hypothesis that
many accused colluders in fact coordinated their decisions to submit bids.
Next, Porter and Zona constructed econometric models that expressed bids as a
function of costs controlled for by the distance between a public school, the bidder’s
location, and the number of deliveries made by the bidder and local market power
41 Robert H. Porter & J. Douglas Zona, Ohio School Milk Markets: An Analysis of Bidding NBER Working
Paper No. 6037 1997 .
12
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
controlled for by variables measuring the locations of competing firms . Porter and Zona
found that bids for the nonâ€colluding firms were explained using these regression models
while, in comparison, the bids of the alleged cartel members were too highly and
persistently correlated to be explained by the data. The authors concluded that it was
difficult to reconcile this high and persistent correlation in bids with the hypothesis that
firms were bidding independently. This high degree of correlation is similar to a gambler in
a casino who has “correctly guessed” which bet to place in roulette twenty times in a row.
These events appear to be too improbable to have occurred at random.42
C. Screening for Bid Prices That Are Disconnected from Costs or Other Market Factors
A key prediction of economic theory is that bids should closely reflect costs in
reasonably competitive markets. The act of collusion, on the other hand, attenuates the
relationship between bids and costs so that conspirators can earn profits above a normal
competitive rate and prices do not tend to decrease when costs are reduced. Therefore, a
second screen proposed in the literature is to determine how well bids reflect costs.
One example of such an attenuation between costs and bid prices as a marker of
collusion was found in a concrete cartel operating under the direction of organized crime in
New York City in the 1980s that rigged bids on contracts of over $2 million. The distance
between prices and costs for concrete in New York City was over 70 percent. This was
compared to other large cities but the difference could not be explained by local market
conditions. This marker, taken together with other structural factors facilitating collusion
in this market, was highly suggestive that a cartel was in place.
In contrast with the example above, Bajari & Ye 2003 43 examined bids by highway
contractors in the upper Midwest during the 1990s and their findings indicated the data
was inconsistent with collusion. This finding supported the belief from market observers in
general that the industry was generally free of bidâ€rigging, despite that three firms had
been previously convicted of collusion.
Bajari & Ye used bids for a type of road repair known as seal coating where the
standard job in their data was fairly small—the winning bids were approximately
$175,000. State highway departments prepared cost estimates before bidding occurred and
these estimates were largely based on bids made in other geographic markets. The study
found that the ratio of the winning bid to cost estimate was almost equal to one with a
fairly small standard deviation. The authors found that this suggested that bids were
42 Other studies have performed similar tests with similar results in markets where collusion is strongly
suspected. This includes Porter & Zona’s 1993 analysis of paving contacts on Long Island in the 1980s, List
et. al.’s 2004 examination of bids for Canadian timber, and Marshall & Marx’s 2008 study of bidding
decisions for Russian Oil and Gas leases. Taken together, these papers demonstrate the usefulness of a screen
that tests for the independence of bid submissions and bid levels. In the introduction, we argued that a good
screen should have few false positives. Bajari & Ye infra demonstrate that this screen appears to have this
property in their study of bidding by contractors in Minnesota, North Dakota, and South Dakota during the
late 1990s.
43 Patrick Bajari & Lixin Ye, Deciding Between Competition and Collusion, 85 4 REV. ECON. STAT., 971â€
989 2003 .
13
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
comparable to properly deflated bids from other markets and took this as evidence that
most bids in the market were competitive.
In this market, distance and backlog were both important determinants of prices.
When studying their relationships with bids, the authors found that bids increased with
both these measures, which they considered to be consistent with competition. Next, the
authors modeled firms’ bids using regression analysis, using control variables such as the
engineer’s cost estimate, distance from the project, and backlog. The regression also
controlled for competitive factors, such as the distance of the closest rival to the project.
The models were separately estimated for each of the 11 largest firms in the market, which
allowed the analysis of whether bids were determined differently across the firms. The
authors then screened for collusion by comparing the regressions described above for pairs
of firms.
The intuition behind the screen was simple; if firms A and B were not colluding, then
their bids would only depend on cost and competitive factors; but, on the other hand, if
firms A and B colluded, these legitimate factors alone could not explain their bids to a
large extent. The authors found evidence consistent with collusion only for 2 out of the 11
firms studied; the same firms that were among the group previously sanctioned for bidâ€
rigging.
Thus, if market factors such as costs are capable of explaining the levels of the bids
for many of the bidders, but they seem to be unable to do so for a subgroup of the bidders,
then this empirical evidence is indicative of possible bidâ€rigging. But it is important to
control for other legitimate factors that may be common to that subgroup of firms and not
to the remaining bidders, and which could potentially justify the empirical finding.
More generally, when analyzing whether bidding patterns are likely to be due to
collusive behavior, one must realize that the failure to control for relevant components of
costs or competitive factors may provide misleading empirical evidence in support of
collusion.
D. Screening for Changes in Bidding Patterns That Are Unexplained by Market Conditions
When sudden changes in bidding patterns cannot be justified by legitimate changes
in market conditions this may be indicative of bid rigging. A recent case pursued by the
Mexican Competition Authority “Commission” is an example of the success of this type of
screening of bidding patterns. As discussed in Labarthe 2012 ,44 the Commission has seen
screens as an excellent tool to focus resources in particular investigations, but also to help
provide evidence in cases.
This bidâ€rigging investigation started from an informal 2006 complaint by the
Mexican Social Security Institute, which is Mexico’s largest public medicine procurer. The
screens employed by the Commission were based on improbable events as well as on
control groups among other interesting approaches that were consistent with theoretical
44 Carlos Menaâ€Labarthe, 2012, “Mexican Experience in Screens for Bidâ€Rigging,” Antitrust Chronicle
March 2 .
14
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
models of cartels. Data covered 2003 through 2007, and some of the patterns that emerged
were highly suggestive of a cartel, especially in two groups of medicines: insulin and serum.
It was determined that the structural design of the process through which the IMSS
acquired the medicines created incentives among pharmaceutical companies to collude in
the sale of such products. These design elements included:
1. product homogeneity;
2. contract allocations to diverse bidders, which permitted the cartel members to
divide the contract and designate certain cartel members as winners within a
specific bid, allowing for the distribution of collusive earnings;
3. information exchange among bidders, which led to the cartel’s ability to verify any
variations in the agreed bids so that the cartel could punish aberrant cartel
members in future bids;
4.
permanent bid rules maintained through time, which stabilized the cartel
agreements to set forth, agree, or coordinate tenders, so that the cartel members did
not have to periodically redesign their agreement conducts; and
5. entry barriers which inhibited new bidders from taking part in the auctions.
Jointly with these structural factors, the Commission identified certain behavioral
patterns through the time line directly related to the tenders of pharmaceutical companies.
These patterns were deemed as preliminary evidence of the existence of cartels in public
bids. The referred patterns included:
1. annual average of the winning and losing bids presented by the pharmaceutical
cartel members was extremely similar and only changed with the entrance of a new
winner or upon the consolidation of bids some years later;
2.
average price was much higher during the years identified as the collusion period,
sometimes 72 percent higher see figure 1 ;
3. the bids were too similar to each other during the collusive period, while presenting
significant variations during the nonâ€collusive period;
4. a clear structural break occurred in the bidding process which could not be justified
by legitimate conditions and which occurred at the end of the cartel figure 1 ;
5.
prices of winning and losing bids were always the same, with the only variations in
the identity of the winner—which, after winning, kept participating but with losing
bids, waiting for their turn to win again bid rotation ; and
6. the amount of the allocated contracts for each of the identified medicines was
concentrated in the pharmaceutical companies involved in the cartel and, in some
cases, the achieved portion for each was practically the same. Likewise, such
participation rapidly converged in time, at the same level.
15
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
Figure 1. Medicine 1 average price 145
Structural change:
*entry of competitors
*purchase consolidation
Non collusive period:
*different tenders
Collusive period:
*variance increases
*same tenders
*reduced variance
In a decision dated April 8, 2015,46 the Mexican Supreme Court of Justice confirmed
that Baxter, Fresenius, Eli Lilly, and Pisa laboratories engaged in monopolistic practices
between 2003 and 2006 with regard to the public procurement of human insulin and
intravenous solutions carried out by the Mexican Institute of Social Security “IMSS” .
Furthermore, the Supreme Court Ruling acknowledged the Commissions’ economic
analysis as valid indirect proof in detecting cases of collusion, which is an important
recognition of the value of screens in assisting in the proof of collusion. The screens were
considered powerful evidence in court when the Commission defended its case. As
Labarthe explains, “ w hen we showed some graphics to our judges they were amazed and
saw the whole picture clearly.”
Another example of a break of a bidâ€rigging cartel causing a drastic price drop that
was unexplainable by legitimate market conditions is discussed in Abrantesâ€Metz, Froeb,
Geweke and Taylor 2006 .47
Similarly, looking for bids that do not react in an expected way to changing market
conditions is another way of screening for bidâ€rigging.
45 Extracted from Labarthe
2012 .
46 COFECE 009â€2015, “The Supreme Court of Justice Decides on Bid Rigging in Social Security Public
Tenders Case,” April 2015.
47 Abrantesâ€Metz, R., Luke M. Froeb, John F. Geweke and Chris T. Taylor “A Variance Screen for
Collusion,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24, 467â€486, 2006,
16
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
IV. THE USE OF STRUCTURAL ANALYSIS AND EMPIRICAL SCREENS AS PART OF AN
“EFFECTIVE” COMPLIANCE PROGRAM
The Sentencing Guidelines state that an entity needs periodically evaluate the
effectiveness of its compliance and ethics program.48 There have been a number of
Antitrust Division speeches specifically referencing this requirement, noting that a
“company should regularly evaluate the compliance program itself to understand what it
can improve.”49 Deputy Assistant Attorney General Brent Snyder has elaborated that a
company “should ensure that it has a proactive compliance program,” meaning that “in
addition to providing training and a forum for feedback, a company should make sure that
at risk activities are regularly monitored and audited.”50 The United States Sentencing
Guidelines also call for companies to conduct risk assessments.51 The concept here is that
organizations have limited resources and need to focus those resources where the risk is
greatest. This means that companies are expected to be proactive, determining both which
risks are most likely to occur and which have the greatest potential impact and modify
their compliance programs accordingly on a periodic basis.
Though there are several possible avenues to address these risks, as discussed in
Abrantesâ€Metz, Bajari, & Murphy,52 screens are a key option to be considered. Screens
identify the areas of a business that are highâ€risk and therefore allow for efficient and
strategic targeting of those areas, allowing for a more efficient allocation of resources.
Specifically, screens employ techniques designed to highlight which parts of the company
merit closer scrutiny, where there should be intensive reviews, and which units may call
for intensive monitoring of internal communications and the like. Empirical screens fulfill
this role by looking at certain quantifiable red flags and applying statistical analysis to
determine the priority areas for further focus. While screens cost money, in the end they
can potentially save the corporation a whole lot more than their cost.
Going forward, the effectiveness of compliance programs will be judged according to
a higher standard than they have been previously. As companies become increasingly able
to amass and mine data, it soon could be expected that such capabilities are utilized to
monitor and test the effectiveness of compliance programs. Therefore, a failure to set up an
effective screen may be seen as falling below this standard, especially for sophisticated
corporate entities. In fact, the OECD has already noted the benefits of economic screening
as a means of strengthening a compliance program, particularly in highâ€risk industries.53
48 Federal Sentencing Guidelines Manual § 8B2.1 b 5 B 2014 “The organization shall take
reasonable steps . . . to evaluate periodically the effectiveness of the organization’s compliance and ethics
program.” .
49 Brent Snyder, Deputy Assistant Attorney General, Antitrust Division, Remarks as Prepared for the
International Chamber of Commerce/United States Council of International Business Joint Antitrust
Compliance Workshop, Compliance is a Culture, Not Just a Policy 6 Sept. 9, 2014 ,
http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/speeches/308494.pdf.
50 Id.
51 U.S. Sentencing Guidelines Section 8B2.1 c .
52 Abrantesâ€Metz, Bajari, & Murphy, supra note 33.
53 OECD, Background Note by the Secretariate, in Ex Officio Cartel Investigations and the Use of Screens
to Detect Cartels 19, DAF/COMP 2013 27 citations omitted citing various Abrantesâ€Mentz papers, among
17
. CPI Antitrust Chronicle
June 2015 (2)
There is another immediate and practical reason for adopting screens as part of a
compliance program. A compliance program, with the use of screening, helps position a
company to win a race for leniency. A leniency program offers tremendous benefits to
implicated companies, potentially permitting them to avoid liability altogether if certain
requirements are met. Even if a company fails to qualify for leniency because it is not the
first in the door, the DOJ considers “early acceptance of responsibility and meaningful
cooperation” in determining the appropriate consequences.54 Given the scores of
enforcement regimes that have similarly adopted leniency programs, or that otherwise
heavily credit early cooperation, such detection offers tremendous benefits. And, as noted
earlier, in the course of uncovering a bidâ€rigging scheme, a company may also be able to
uncover bribery conduct. Such early detection may allow them to remediate or seek
mitigation from the relevant antiâ€corruption enforcer s in a timely manner. The ability to
be the first to detect the conduct offers tremendous advantages to both companies and
enforcers.
Beyond their utility to detect antiâ€competitive or corrupt schemes, screens can serve
as a powerful tool for deterrence. Once knowledge of their implementation spreads, the
existence screens alone can have a chilling effect on wouldâ€be offenders. And, in the words
Benjamin Franklin, “an ounce of prevention is worth a pound of cure.”
others noting that the “implementation of screens as part of compliance programmes can be especially
effective because the screening exercise can rely on internal company data which is not necessarily always
available to competition agencies” , available online at http://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/exofficioâ€
cartelâ€investigationâ€2013.pdf.
54 Bill Baer, Assistant Attorney General, Antitrust Division, DOJ, Remarks as Prepared for the Georgetown
University Law Center Global Antitrust Enforcement Symposium 5â€6 Sept. 10, 2014 , available online at
http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/speeches/308499.pdf.
18
.