AND
88
8
SER
V
H
NC
THE BE
ING
1
BA
R SINCE
www. NYLJ.com
Wednesday, december 23, 2015
Volume 254—NO. 120
Expert Analysis
ANTITRUST
U.S. Brings Computerized Price-Fixing Charges
T
he U.S.
Department of Justice brought
criminal charges against online retailers for conspiring to fix prices by utilizing algorithm-based pricing software,
among other means. The U.S. Court of
Appeals for the Third Circuit ruled that a real
estate owner and developer had standing to
assert antitrust claims against a supermarket
chain even though the developer was neither
a competitor nor a customer of the defendant,
because its injury from alleged interference
with obtaining permits was inextricably intertwined with the harm to a rival supermarket.
A district court set aside a jury verdict finding that a cable provider unlawfully tied its
premium service to the rental of set-top boxes
because those boxes were not available from
any other source.
Other recent antitrust developments of note
include the U.S.
Court of Appeals for the Fifth
Circuit’s partial reversal of a jury verdict that
a steel distribution boycott violated antitrust
law and enforcement actions by U.S. antitrust
agencies for failure to comply with premerger
notification regulations.
Pricing Algorithm
A U.K.-based online retailer and an ownerdirector of the company were charged with
fixing prices of posters sold over the Internet
to U.S. customers, based on an alleged agreement to adopt specific computer pricing algorithms for the sale of certain posters, among
other allegations.
See DOJ Press Release,
Dec. 4, 2015. The Department of Justice filed
an indictment in the Northern District of California charging Trod Ltd (doing business as
Buy 4 Less, Buy For Less and Buy-For-LessOnline) and the owner-director with fixing the
prices of posters sold online through Amazon
Marketplace from September 2013 through
January 2014.
According to the indictment,
defendants and their co-conspirators used
commercially available algorithm-based pricing software to price their products sold on
Amazon. This software operates by collecting
competitor pricing information for a specific
By
Elai
Katz
product sold on Amazon and applies a pricing
rule set by the seller.
The DOJ alleged that defendants and their
co-conspirators agreed to adopt specific pricing rules for certain posters, with the goal of
offering consumers the same price for the same
poster. An alleged co-conspirator pleaded
guilty to similar charges in this case in April
2015.
The Assistant Attorney General in charge
of antitrust, Bill Baer, stated, “We will not toler-
The Department of Justice filed an
indictment charging Trod Ltd and
the owner-director with fixing the
prices of posters sold online.
ate anticompetitive conduct, whether it occurs
in a smoke-filled room or over the Internet using
complex pricing algorithms.”
Although the charges in the indictment
include traditional indicia of price-fixing agreements, including allegations of conversations
and communications to discuss and fix prices
of agreed-upon posters, this matter raises questions about the impact of sophisticated online
pricing software on competition. In the absence
of an agreement to fix prices, algorithms that
have the technological capacity to implement
parallel pricing strategies with great speed and
accuracy should fall outside the purview of §1 of
the Sherman Act, like other parallel but independent conduct engaged in by human beings and
addressed by the Supreme Court most recently
in Bell Atlantic v. Twombly, 550 U.S.
544 (2007).
Antitrust Standing
ELAI KATZ is a partner of Cahill Gordon & Reindel. KOMAL
PATEL, an associate at the firm, assisted in the preparation
of this article.
Plaintiff Hanover Realty, a landowner and
real estate developer, had contracted with
the Wegmans supermarket chain to build a
new full-service supermarket in Hanover, N.J.
The contract provided that Hanover Realty
would secure all of the necessary construction ermits, and gave Wegmans the right to
p
walk away from the deal should Hanover fail
to obtain the permits within two years.
Defendant ShopRite is another supermarket
chain with 26 locations in New Jersey, including
a full-service supermarket two miles away from
the proposed location of the new Wegmans.
Hanover Realty asserted that ShopRite was the
only full-service supermarket operating in the
relevant area and that, once it learned about the
proposal to open a Wegmans in town, ShopRite
and its subsidiary filed numerous challenges
to Hanover Realty’s permit applications for
the purpose of preventing the new Wegmans
from opening.
Hanover Realty brought suit against ShopRite
and its subsidiary, alleging that the defendants’
conduct constituted attempted monopolization
of the local “full-service supermarket” and the
“supermarket rental space” markets in violation
of §2 of the Sherman Act. The district court dismissed the claims on the grounds that Hanover
Realty could not demonstrate antitrust injury
and therefore did not have antitrust standing.
In most cases, those who are neither consumers nor competitors of the defendant in the
restrained market have difficulty demonstrating that they suffered antitrust injury.
Hanover
Realty conceded that it was neither a consumer
nor a competitor of ShopRite in the full-service
supermarket market, as it is a landowner and
lessor of property and not a food retailer.
Instead, Hanover Realty argued that its injuries
fell within the limited exception described by
the Supreme Court in Blue Shield of Virginia
v. McCready, 457 U.S. 465 (1982), for persons
whose injuries are “inextricably ntertwined”
i
with the harm caused by defendants.
The Third Circuit, reversing the district
court, determined that the “inextricably intertwined” exception applied to Hanover Realty’s injuries and reinstated one of its claims.
Hanover 3201 Realty v.
Village Supermarkets,
806 F.3d 162 (3d Cir. Nov. 12, 2015).
The appellate court reasoned that the end goal of the
alleged anticompetitive conduct was to injure
Wegmans, a prospective competitor. Injuring
Hanover Realty, through delay tactics and
inflicting high costs, “was the very means
by which Defendants could get to Wegmans;
. Wednesday, december 23, 2015
Hanover Realty’s injury was necessary to Defendants’ plan.” The Third Circuit explained that
had Wegmans applied for the permits itself, the
costs in question would have certainly qualified
as antitrust injuries; thus it “should make no
difference that the parties’ lease shifted these
costs to Hanover Realty.”
The appellate panel did, however, affirm
the dismissal of Hanover Realty’s claim that
defendants attempted to monopolize the market for supermarket rental space. Hanover
did not rely on the “inextricably intertwined”
theory for this claim and instead argued that
it was a direct competitor of ShopRite’s subsidiary, H&H. The panel affirmed the lower
court’s findings that H&H’s sole purpose was
to manage a single ShopRite store and it did
not own any other properties, such that it
could not conceivably compete with Hanover
Realty for more lessees.
Cable Box Tying
A district court in Oklahoma set aside a $6.3
million jury verdict awarded to cable services
subscribers alleging that Cox Communications
illegally tied its premium cable services to rentals of its set-top boxes. Healy v.
Cox Communications, No. 12-CV-0481 (W.D. Okla., Nov.
12, 2015).
Tying arrangements may be illegal where the
seller forecloses a substantial portion of the
market by exploiting its power in one market
to force buyers to accept another product that
they might otherwise buy from a competing
seller. In granting Cox’s judgement as a matter of
law, the court found that the subscribers failed
to offer evidence from which a jury could reasonably infer that any other supplier offered to
sell set-top boxes or that Cox had prevented
manufacturers from entering the market.
The court stated that the plaintiffs’ theories
as to how Cox prevented other manufacturers
from entering the market lacked evidentiary
support and required the jury to make impermissible leaps in logic. While the subscribers
demonstrated that at least one manufacturer
expressed a desire to enter the market, there
was no evidence that Cox prevented or blocked
that manufacturer from doing so.
Similarly, evidence that Best Buy declined to support a third
party set-top box due to its perception that cable
companies would not support the product did
not establish that Cox foreclosed competition.
The court noted that the subscribers’ other
theory, that Cox manufactured an indemnification issue to prevent Tivo from entering the
market, “invites unsupported speculation” and
was similarly insufficient to establish that Cox’s
tying arrangement foreclosed competition. For
similar reasons, the court also found insufficient evidence to establish the injury element
of the claim, which requires that plaintiffs suffer
harm from a competition-reducing aspect of
the tying arrangement.
Group Boycott
In another case involving the appeal of a
jury verdict, the Fifth Circuit ruled that there
was insufficient evidence of one steel manufacturer’s participation in a conspiracy by
steel distributors to boycott a new distributor formed by former employees. MM Steel v.
JSW Steel (USA) and Nucor Corp., No.
14-20267
(5th Cir. Nov. 25, 2015).
The former employees
alleged that as soon as they established their
new steel distribution business, the incumbent
distributors agreed to threaten steel manufacturers not to sell to the new firm.
The appellate court examined whether
there was substantial evidence for the jury
to conclude that two manufacturers joined
the distributors’ conspiracy to refuse to deal
with the new firm. Noting that only a concerted
refusal to deal is illegal, the Fifth Circuit ruled
that one manufacturer decided independently
not to deal with the new firm out of loyalty
to its longstanding distributor, not because
of the group boycott, without knowledge of
any threats and before the distributors allegedly agreed to form a boycott. As to the other
manufacturer, the appellate court stated that
a reasonable juror could have concluded that
its refusal to deal was a response to threats
from distributors.
A district court in Oklahoma set aside
a $6.3 million jury verdict awarded to
cable services subscribers alleging
that Cox Communications illegally
tied its premium cable services to
rentals of its set-top boxes.
Premerger Notification
The Federal Trade Commission (FTC)
announced two enforcement actions involving
interpretation of investment-related exemptions to premerger notification requirements.
The Hart-Scott-Rodino Act (HSR Act) requires
those contemplating mergers or acquisitions of
voting securities or assets that meet statutory
thresholds to notify the antitrust agencies and
observe a waiting period before completing
those transactions.
The HSR rules apply not only to mergers
and acquisitions of control but also to acquisitions of minority positions valued at or above
$76.3 million (the current threshold, adjusted
annually).
The rules exempt minority acquisitions resulting in the buyer holding not more
than 10 percent of outstanding voting securities if they are made “solely for the purpose
of investment.”
In one matter, a complaint filed by the FTC
and the Department of Justice alleged that
Third Point LLC and affiliated hedge funds
failed to make an HSR filing and observe the
waiting period before acquiring voting securities in Yahoo! Inc. in 2011. The FTC asserted that
Third Point engaged in activities that reflected
an intent to acquire stock not solely for the
purpose of passive investment but rather to
participate in the formulation, determination
or direction of the basic business decisions of
Yahoo!, including communicating with potential
candidates for Yahoo!’s board of directors and
taking steps to assemble an alternate slate of
directors.
See United States v. Third Point Offshore Fund, 15-cv-1366 (D.D.C. Aug.
24, 2015).
In another HSR enforcement action, the FTC
and DOJ asserted that Jeffries, LLC, and its parent Leucadia National Corporation, improperly
relied on the institutional investor exemption
when they failed to make an HSR filing before
acquiring approximately 13.5 percent of the
outstanding voting securities of KCG Holdings.
The institutional investor exemption provides
that certain institutional investors, including
broker-dealers, may acquire up to 15 percent
of an issuer without making a filing as long
as the acquisition is solely for the purpose of
investment. However, the exemption does not
apply when an institutional investor acquires
shares of another institutional investor of the
same type. The antitrust agencies alleged that
the institutional investor exemption did not
apply to the acquisition because both Jeffries and KCG were broker-dealers within
the meaning of the HSR rules.
United States
v. Leucadia National Corp., 15-cv-1547 (D.D.C.
Sept. 22, 2015).
The FTC majority statement in the Third Point
matter emphasized that HSR violations do not
depend on the likelihood of competitive harms
resulting from the acquisition, noting that the
HSR Act is procedural and that the investmentonly exemption is narrow.
In a lengthy dissent,
Commissioners Joshua D. Wright (who has since
left the commission) and Maureen K. Ohlhausen
suggested that the antitrust agencies revisit the
parameters of the investment-only exemption,
including the possibility of exempting all acquisition of less than 10 percent, because those
transactions are unlikely to raise competitive
concerns and the agencies should avoid chilling
valuable shareholder advocacy.
As Commissioners Wright and Ohlhausen
noted, one of the principal concerns motivating
the passage of the HSR Act (and other premerger notification laws)—providing the antitrust
agencies an opportunity to review a transaction before it is too late to “unscramble the
eggs”—is absent in acquisitions of 10 percent or
less.
Post-closing remedies should be effective
in virtually any case where antitrust agencies
might determine that a minority acquisition of
up to 10 percent (or even 15 percent) raises
substantial competitive concerns. At the same
time, a clear bright-line rule would substantially
reduce costs associated with evaluating and
complying with HSR obligations.
Reprinted with permission from the December 23, 2015 edition of the NEW YORK
LA JOURNAL © 2015 ALM Media Properties, LLC. All rights reserved.
Further
W
duplication without permission is prohibited. For information, contact 877-257-3382
or reprints@alm.com. # 070-12-15-32
.